Nicholas Mathers Why a universal Child Grant makes sense in Nepal: a four-step analysis

Similar documents
The contribution of Nepal s Child Grant to social inclusion in the Karnali region

Results from a social protection technical assistance program. July 2011

Myths, misnomers, misrepresentations: Unpicking the targeting versus universal debate

by Dilli Raj Khanal, PhD Presented to the Seminar on Income Security to Old Persons in South Asia Organized by ESCAP 27 Feb 2017, New Delhi

POVERTY, GROWTH, AND PUBLIC TRANSFERS IN TANZANIA PROGRESS REPORT ON THE NATIONAL SAFETY NET STUDY

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries

Social Protection Toolsheet Targeting Social Transfers

FINAL REPORT DISCUSSION PAPER ON TRANSFER VALUES IN KENYA S NATIONAL SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEM

Who Benefits from Water Utility Subsidies?

Economic standard of living

Increasing efficiency and effectiveness of Cash Transfer Schemes for improving school attendance

Assessing Targeting and Poverty Performance

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

THE QUEST FOR ACHIEVING SOCIAL PROTECTION FOR ALL IN NEPAL: CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES

Fighting Hunger Worldwide. Emergency Social Safety Net. Post-Distribution Monitoring Report Round 1. ESSN Post-Distribution Monitoring Round 1 ( )

Fiscal Space for Social Protection: Harmonization of Contributory and Non-Contributory programmes

REDUCING CHILD POVERTY IN GEORGIA:

CASH TRANSFERS, IMPACT EVALUATION & SOCIAL POLICY: THE CASE OF EL SALVADOR

Improving targeting in Rwanda in the context of broader Social Protection

Wits School of Governance

Just Give Money to the Poor

World Social Security Report 2010/11 Providing coverage in times of crisis and beyond

Do Conditional Cash Transfers (CCT) Really Improve Education and Health and Fight Poverty? The Evidence

THE NATIONAL SOCIAL PROTECTION STRATEGY (NSPS): INVESTING IN PEOPLE GOVERNMENT OF GHANA. Ministry of Manpower, Youth and Employment (MMYE) 2008

Francesco Caselli and Guy Michaels A resource curse? The impact of oil windfalls on living standards in Brazil

The Role of Conditional Cash Transfers in the Process of Equitable Economic Development

National budget brief Review of 2016 social sector budget allocations

MONEY SUPPLY ROLE IN ECONOMIC AND INDUSTRIAL GROWTH: THE CASE OF JORDAN ( )

Education and Employment Status of Dalit women

Poverty and Inequality in the Countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States

Ethiopia Productive Safety Net Programme (PSNP): Prospects for graduation and sustainability beyond 2014

GLA 2014 round of trend-based population projections - Methodology

THE RICH AND THE POOR: CHANGES IN INCOMES OF DEVELOPING COUNTRIES SINCE 1960

John Hills The distribution of welfare. Book section (Accepted version)

Universal Social Protection

Financial Sector Reform and Economic Growth in Zambia- An Overview

SUMMARY POVERTY IMPACT ASSESSMENT

Cash Research and Development Pilots Emergency Response Pakistan

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries

Basic Income as a policy option: Can it add up?

Tracking Government Investments for Nutrition at Country Level Patrizia Fracassi, Clara Picanyol, 03 rd July 2014

Q&A THE MALAWI SOCIAL CASH TRANSFER PILOT

PROGRAM EXPENDITURE AND FINANCING ASSESSMENT

KENYA CT-OVC PROGRAM DATA USE INSTRUCTIONS

Final Evaluation & Outcome Assessment of Promotion of Sustainable Agriculture for Nutrition and Food Security (POSAN FS) Project

THE IMPACT OF REFORMING ENERGY SUBSIDIES, CASH TRANSFERS, AND TAXES ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN GHANA AND TANZANIA

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS. A. Short-Term Effects on Income Poverty and Vulnerability

PROXY MEANS TESTING: AN ALTERNATIVE METHOD FOR POVERTY ASSESSMENT

Financing Social Security

Economic Life Cycle Deficit and Intergenerational Transfers in Italy: An Analysis Using National Transfer Accounts Methodology

Oren M. Levin-Waldman and George W. McCarthy

PUBLIC WORKS AS A SAFETY NET: DESIGN, EVIDENCE AND IMPLEMENTATION KALANIDHI SUBBARAO DOHA, MARCH 8, 2014

The Effects of the Ecological Tax Reform in Germany

UPDATED FINANCIAL ANALYSIS

HEALTH COVERAGE AMONG YEAR-OLDS in 2003

The Economic Effects of Canceling Scheduled Changes to Overtime Regulations

Benazir Income Support Programme (BISP)

All social security systems are income transfer

ECON 450 Development Economics

Open Working Group on Sustainable Development Goals. Statistical Note on Poverty Eradication 1. (Updated draft, as of 12 February 2014)

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan

Universal Social Protection

Estimating Rates of Return of Social Protection

Poverty and Social Transfers in Hungary

Divya Parmar, Manuela de Allegri, Aurélia Souares, Germain Savadogo and Rainer Sauerborn Equity impact of community-based health insurance ( )

THE IMPACT OF CASH AND BENEFITS IN-KIND ON INCOME DISTRIBUTION IN INDONESIA

The Food Stamp Program A Secret History of the First Targeted Benefit in Mongolia. W. Walker SP Training - Pattaya

A New Construction Price Comparison Methodology for. The International Comparison Program: Concept Note

Assessing payment mechanisms for Myanmar

Online Appendix for Constrained Concessions: Dictatorial Responses to the Domestic Opposition

Universal Social Protection

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

Does health capital have differential effects on economic growth?

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

How Much? Spending on SSN Programs

Prepared By. Roger Colton Fisher, Sheehan & Colton Belmont, Massachusetts. Interim Report on Xcel Energy s Pilot Energy Assistance Program (PEAP):

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

SOCIAL PROTECTION BUDGET SWAZILAND 2017/2018 HEADLINE MESSAGES. Swaziland

THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE

Although a larger percentage of the world s population

Measuring coverage of social protection programmes: Lessons from Kenya, Zimbabwe, Belize and Vietnam

Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World

POVERTY IN AUSTRALIA: NEW ESTIMATES AND RECENT TRENDS RESEARCH METHODOLOGY FOR THE 2016 REPORT

Combating Child Poverty and Deprivation: The Promise of a Universal Child Grant

THE ECONOMICS OF CHILD LABOR: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION. Eric Edmonds Dartmouth, IZA, NBER Norbert Schady The World Bank

Welcome to the presentation on

Workshop on Policy Options for Effective and Sustainable Social Protection Floors. United Nations Mozambique Delivering as One

Social Protection and Jobs in Nepal. Jasmine Rajbhandary Senior Social Protection Specialist World Bank September 5, 2018

Social protection consist of policies and programs designed to reduce poverty and vulnerability.

The Economic Impact of International Education in Manawatu-Whanganui 2015/16. for Education New Zealand

Oxford Energy Comment March 2007

Social Protection Floor Costing Tool. User Manual

Analogue Entitlements in a Digital Age

Wits School of Governance

Potential impacts of climate change on $2-a-day poverty and child mortality in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia

The Impact of the Public Distribution System on Living Standards Some Microsimulations 5

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors

WJEC (Eduqas) Economics A-level Trade Development

Policy Brief May 2016

TERMS OF REFERENCE EXTERNAL EVALUATION OF UNICEF S CASH TRANSFER PROJECT IN NIGER SEPTEMBER 2010

Transcription:

Nicholas Mathers Why a universal Child Grant makes sense in Nepal: a four-step analysis Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Mathers, Nicholas (2017) Why a universal Child Grant makes sense in Nepal: a four-step analysis. Global Social Policy. ISSN 1468-0181 DOI: 10.1177/1468018117729913 2017 The Author This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/85320/ Available in LSE Research Online: November 2017 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher s version if you wish to cite from it.

Why a universal Child Grant makes sense in Nepal: A four-step analysis Nicholas Mathers London School of Economics (LSE), UK Abstract Whether cash transfers should be poverty targeted or universal within certain social categories remains a hotly debated topic. Recent plans to expand Nepal s Child Grant programme brought this question sharply into focus. Using available secondary data, this article presents a four-step analysis that examines the costs and benefits of different approaches. Given the country s poverty profile, the theoretical results of different targeting models, government capacity and overall costs, a universal (age-cohort targeted) approach achieves the best outcomes for children. Keywords Cash transfers, Nepal, social protection, targeting Whether cash transfers should be poverty targeted or universal within certain social categories remains a hotly debated topic. 1 Recent plans to expand Nepal s child grant programme brought this question sharply into focus. The Child Grant an unconditional cash transfer was introduced in Nepal in 2009 to support better nutrition for children under 5 years of age. During its first 6 years, the Child Grant was limited to all households in the geographically remote Karnali region and to poor Dalit households in the rest of the country. In 2016, the Government took the decision to initiate expansion of the programme nationwide. Targeting was one of the central questions to be addressed. Here, I make the argument that a universal rather than a poverty-targeted approach will achieve better outcomes for children and is affordable. 2 The rationale put forward for poverty targeting is that it is more efficient, allowing sometimes scarce resources to be concentrated on those who need them most. This argument is appealing, but there are potentially significant costs associated with targeting. These include the misidentification of those who are poor; complex and expensive implementation; reduced incentives to work; and the creation of social and political tensions between those who qualify and those who do not (Devereux, 2016; Slater and Farrington, 2009). Universal approaches, on the contrary, are by definition more inclusive and are less demanding to implement an important consideration in countries with widespread poverty and limited administrative capacity. In reality, most social protection systems and many individual programmes including Nepal s Child Grant utilise a combination of targeting approaches.

Which targeting approach(es) to use should primarily be an empirical question about which is the most effective (in terms of outcomes) and feasible (in terms of implementation and cost) to achieve the programme objectives. When data are limited, assessing the benefits and costs of different approaches can be done in four steps: first, understand the country poverty profile; second, using available datasets, model the theoretical targeting outcomes; third, review any existing empirical evidence; and fourth, calculate the total cost. Poverty and targeting In Nepal, around 25% of the population live under the official poverty line with an even greater number of near poor. Under-fives experience an even higher level and greater depth of poverty. Moreover, nearly 80% of under-fives live in a household with per capita consumption of less than NRs 40,000 (US$374) (Mathers, 2016). Although double the official per capita poverty line of NRs 19,261, this is far from being economically secure. 3 In this context, the leakage of benefits to well-off households one of the problems that targeting aims to address is of less concern. What do different targeting approaches achieve in theory? Table 1 shows the exclusion and inclusion errors, benchmarked against the national poverty line, under universal, caste- and poverty-based targeting designs and assuming perfect implementation. Logically, a universal Child Grant results in zero exclusion of poor underfives, compared with an exclusion error of more than seven in every 10 poor children for both the Dalit option (72%) and the simple proxy means test (PMT) (71%). 4 Thus, both castebased targeting and the simple PMT both of which are currently applied to the Child Grant result in the exclusion of more than two-thirds of poor children. Inclusion errors (grant recipients who are non-poor ) are more comparable across the different approaches. All three targeting options are slightly regressive with more than 50% of grant recipients being non-poor. However, it is worth noting that the universal approach (64%) performs slightly better than the simple PMT approach (67%). Moreover, it has been shown that the majority of these non-poor under-fives are in fact near-poor and economically insecure. Table 1. Exclusion and inclusion errors for under-fives under different targeting designs. Child Grant targeting design Percentage of poor underfives excluded Percentage of under-fives included who are non-poor Universal 0 64 Dalit 72 52 Simple PMT 71 67 Data source: Nepal Living Standards Survey (NLSS), 2010. PMT: proxy means test.

Table 2 shows the percentage point (pp) change for different poverty measures (headcount, poverty gap and severity index) achieved by different targeting designs, given a fixed budget. 5 The best outcomes are achieved by the universal and Dalit designs, with 7.3 and 8.4 pp reductions in the poverty rate, respectively. The simple PMT performs worst, with a 4.9 pp reduction. Notably, however, both the Dalit and PMT designs achieve these outcomes by transferring the same sizable budget to a much smaller population a scenario that results in unreasonably high benefit levels for a small number of recipients and is unlikely to occur in practice. The universal option also achieves the best outcomes in terms of reducing the poverty gap (by 2.8 pp) and severity (by 1.3 units). In other words, a universal Child Grant is better at reaching the poorest of the poor. Table 2. Poverty reduction impacts under-fives under different targeting designs. Child Grant targeting design Percentage point (pp) reduction in national under-five poverty measures Head count Poverty gap Severity Under-five poverty rate 35.8 % 8.6 % 3.1 Universal 7.3 pp 2.8 pp 1.3 Dalit 8.4 pp 2.3 pp 0.9 Simple PMT 4.9 pp 1.8 pp 0.8 Data source: Nepal Living Standards Survey (NLSS), 2010. PMT: proxy means test. Significance of text in Italics is to distinguish the poverty rates from the pp change in poverty rates. How does targeting work in practice in Nepal? The previous analysis assumed that no additional exclusion and inclusion errors result from poor implementation and that the targeting approach incurs no additional administrative costs. Given that this is unlikely, even under the best conditions, what do we know about how these targeting approaches work in practice? Experience from Nepal shows that the simple PMT associated with the Child Grant is, for several reasons, not actually implemented. First, official procedures are often not well understood by local-level implementers. Second, despite being relatively simple, measuring and verifying even just three indicators is administratively challenging. Third, while local communities accept, to some extent, a Child Grant for Dalit children, when poverty criteria are applied there is demand from other non-dalit but poor households. We are all poor here is a common refrain (Hagen-Zanker and Mallett, 2016).

Implementing a more complex PMT is even more challenging in Nepal. Data collected for this purpose in 25 districts remained contested and unused for programming several years later. 6 Moreover, in a pilot cash transfer project in two districts that employed a PMT, the financial cost of targeting was estimated at 22% of total project costs (Acharya et al., 2010), considerably more than the average of 4% estimated for programmes in middle-income countries (Slater and Farrington, 2009). While a PMT approach may have useful applications in certain circumstances, the current level of government capacity means that implementing at scale and at reasonable cost is still some years away. Insufficient human resources, paper-based record keeping and poor infrastructure limit the ability of local government to undertake regular and accurate measurement, recording and analysis of socioeconomic data. In such a context, a PMT would result in substantially higher exclusion and inclusion errors than predicted and would be more prone to manipulation by both beneficiaries and officials (Kidd and Wylde, 2011). International experience supports this analysis. In low-income countries, means-tested and PMT-targeted programmes have been shown to perform no better than universal child grants in transferring resources to poor households, despite being specifically designed to do so (Coady et al., 2004). 7 Geographic targeting can provide a useful option when there are specific problems to be addressed, such as food insecurity, within certain well-defined geographic areas. The choice of Karnali region for the initial roll-out of the Child Grant is a case in point. However, from a national perspective, it is a crude mechanism for reaching poor households, leading to high levels of exclusion and inclusion error. Nonetheless, when budgets are limited, geographic targeting can be a practical approach to achieve incremental expansion in programme coverage, prioritising areas with the largest proportion of or absolute number of poor or vulnerable households. What is the financial cost of a universal Child Grant? Assuming an incremental expansion to reach national coverage within 10 years, the cost of a universal Child Grant for under-fives at current benefit levels is estimated to be NRs 14.2 billion (US$117 million) in 2025 (Mathers and Mshvidobadze, 2016). 8 Accounting for an inflation-indexed increase in benefit levels after 5 years will result in a total budget of NRs 21.2 billion (US$175 million). Once national coverage has been reached, the overall cost is projected to decline due to falling fertility rates. While these sums are certainly not small, they are affordable, representing between 0.25% and 0.38% of gross domestic product (GDP), depending on the scenario. Within the context of the 2016 national budget, an immediate nationwide expansion would see the Child Grant s share of the budget grow from 0.2% to 1.3%. Social security as a whole would grow to 10.2% still well within the Government s own target under the Sustainable Development Goals to achieve 15% of total expenditure on social protection by 2030. Conclusion

When deciding the most appropriate targeting approach for a particular policy, it is important to use all available evidence to assess the costs and benefits in the specific context. The four-step approach presented here provides a rounded and logical analysis for policy makers and is feasible in most developing countries considering data availability. In the case of Nepal s Child Grant, the evidence suggests that a poverty-targeted approach will be practically very difficult and costly, as a share of programme resources, to implement and will result in an unacceptably high level of exclusion of the poor, including the poorest. On the other hand, a universal approach is inclusive, locally acceptable and affordable. Funding The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship and/or publication of this article. Notes 1. Universal is sometimes used to refer to blanket coverage of the entire population (a universal benefit or basic income). Here, as commonly understood, it refers to benefits that are available to all within a defined social category regardless of income status. 2. This article presents analysis that was produced as part of UNICEF s technical support to the Government of Nepal for the Child Grant expansion strategy in 2016. 3. The poverty line is based on the cost of basic needs (CBN) approach and constitutes (a) a food basket adequate to meet minimum dietary requirements and (b) a non-food item basket based on the actual average non-food item consumption of borderline food insecure households. As such it represents the bare minimum for survival rather than the resources required for an acceptable standard of living. 4. Caste-based targeting refers to the selection of Dalit households, an historically oppressed group at the bottom of the Hindu caste system. The simple proxy means test (PMT) that is applicable to the Dalit Child Grant requires that households do not own their own house, or have less than a certain area of farmable land, or can only produce adequate food for less than 3 months of the year. 5. Each targeting design receives the same fixed budget, which allows for a transfer of NRs 500 (US$4.70) per month per child under the universal design. 6. VDC officials challenge data on poverty in Bajura (Republica, 7 June, 2016). 7. World Bank analysis from low- and middle-income countries shows that, on average, child grants transfer 53% more resources to poor households than purely random targeting, on a par with means test (53%) and PMT (50%) approaches. 8. International Labour Organization (ILO) undertook a costing exercise when the Child Grant was first under consideration, coming to similar results regarding its cost and affordability (see ILO, 2008).

References Acharya A, Chirchir R, Hobley M et al. (2010) Options for the Social Security Pilot Project. Paper prepared for LGCDP, Ministry of Local Development, July 2010. Kathmandu, Nepal: UNCDF. Coady D, Grosh M and Hoddinott J (2004) Targeting of Cash Transfers in Developing Countries. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Devereux S (2016) Is targeting ethical? Global Social Policy. Available at: http://journals.sagepub. com/doi/pdf/10.1177/1468018116643849 Hagen-Zanker J and Mallett R (2016) Nepal s child grant: A mixed-methods assessment of implementation bottlenecks. International Social Security Review 69: 47 65. ILO (2008) Affordable and not an illusion. Costing of basic social protection benefits for Nepal 2007-2034. Nepal Technical Note. Available at: http://www.socialprotection.org/gimi/gess/showressource.action?ressource.ressourceid=10174 Kidd S and Wylde E (2011) Targeting the Poorest: An Assessment of the PMT Methodology. Canberra, ACT, Australia: AusAID. Mathers N (2016) Achieving the Best Outcomes for Children: Why a Universal Child Grant Makes Sense for Nepal. Kathmandu, Nepal: Policy Brief UNICEF. Mathers N and Mshvidobadze A (2016) Costing the Child Grant Expansion in Nepal. Kathmandu, Nepal: UNICEF. Slater R and Farrington J (2009) Targeting of Social Transfers: A Review for DFID. London: ODI. Author biography Nicholas Mathers is a PhD candidate in the Department of Social Policy at the London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE). His research focuses on poverty and social protection in developing countries. He was the Cash Transfers Specialist for UNICEF Nepal between 2015 and 2017 and previously Social Protection Programme Manager at the Overseas Development Institute (ODI).