Menu Choices in Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Similar documents
Defined Contribution Pension Plans: Sticky or Discerning Money?

It Pays to Set the Menu: Mutual Fund Investment Options in 401(k) Plans

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DEFINED CONTRIBUTION PENSION PLANS: STICKY OR DISCERNING MONEY? Clemens Sialm Laura Starks Hanjiang Zhang

It Pays to Set the Menu: Mutual Fund Investment Options in 401(k) Plans

WikiLeaks Document Release

CRS Report for Congress

The Labor Market Effects of the VA s Disability Compensation Program

WRITTEN TESTIMONY SUBMITTED BY LORI LUCAS EXECUTIVE VICE PRESIDENT CALLAN ASSOCIATES

What Causes World Monetary Instability?

SIEPR policy brief. Fiscal Stimulus in the Form of Lower Payroll Taxes. By Mark Bils and Pete Klenow. About The Author

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

The Impact of the Fed s Mortgage-Backed Securities Purchase Program By Johannes C. Stroebel and John B. Taylor

HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN

RESEARCH DIALOGUE IT PAYS TO SET THE MENU: MUTUAL FUND INVESTMENT OPTIONS IN 401(K) PLANS * Issue no. 121 DECEMBER 2015

Foreclosure and Bankruptcy Policy Conclusions From the Current Crisis

Written. Before the. Regarding. September 2009

Potential vs. realized savings under automatic enrollment

ICI RESEARCH PERSPECTIVE

Health Insurance Coverage and Employee Contributions

The Limitations of Defaults

SPRING Behavioral Finance Research Digest for plan sponsors and their advisors

Do Defaults Have Spillover Effects? The Effect of the Default Asset on Retirement Plan Contributions

Are Wellness Programs Any Good? 1

Advancements in target date fund delivery. Weighing the pros and cons of collective investment trusts and customization in target date design

Chairmen and Members of the Joint Committee on Alabama Public Pensions The Pew Charitable Trusts

Mechanisms Behind Retirement Saving Behavior: Evidence From Administrative and Survey Data

Susan S Bies: Retirement savings, equity ownership, and challenges to investors

Some Considerations for Empirical Research on Tax-Preferred Savings Accounts.

Investing for a Lifetime. Guaranteed. Providing guaranteed lifetime-income options can improve participants retirement readiness.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCHANGE TRADED FUNDS: A NEW INVESTMENT OPTION FOR TAXABLE INVESTORS. James M. Poterba John B. Shoven

CEM Benchmarking DEFINED BENEFIT THE WEEN. did not have.

CAN THE ENROLLMENT EXPERIENCE IMPROVE PARTICIPANT OUTCOMES?

Assessing the Efficiency of Asset Markets through Analysis of the Currency Carry Trade

IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING?

This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH. SIEPR Discussion Paper No.

A NUDGE ISN T ALWAYS ENOUGH

SIEPR policy brief. Why Exchange Rate Changes Will Not Correct Global Trade Imbalances. About The Author. By Ronald I. McKinnon

SIEPR policy brief. Is Policy Uncertainty Delaying the Recovery? About the Authors. By Scott R. Baker, Nicholas Bloom and Steven J.

Household finance and libertarian paternalism

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

219B Exercise on Present Bias and Retirement Savings

center for retirement research

MMI LINCOLN LINCOLN MIDDLE MARKET INDEX INSIDE THIS ISSUE

The Benefits of. Presented By:

Offering vs. Choice in Retirement Plans: A Cross Sectional Analysis of Investment Menus with Traditional and Life-Cycle Mutual Funds

RiXtrema Quantitative Research. Retirement Plans Are Wasting $12.32B in Fees: How Are Your Clients & Prospects Doing?

MUTUAL FUND PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS PRE AND POST FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008

Annuity and Lump-Sum Decisions in Defined Benefit Plans: The Role of Plan Rules

When and How to Delegate? A Life Cycle Analysis of Financial Advice

STRATEGY OVERVIEW. Opportunistic Growth. Related Funds: 361 U.S. Small Cap Equity Fund (ASFZX)

People avoid actions that create regret and seek actions that cause

MUTUAL FUND: BEHAVIORAL FINANCE S PERSPECTIVE

PPI Briefing Note Number 99 (PhD Series No 2) Page 1

Brand Name Recognition and Participant-Friendly Provisions

Regulation of the Mortgage Market Must Consider Shadow Banks

Target Date Glide Paths: BALANCING PLAN SPONSOR GOALS 1

New Evidence on the Demand for Advice within Retirement Plans

Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds

The BrightScope/ICI Defined Contribution Plan Profile: A Close Look at 401(k) Plans, 2014

Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment. Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A.

New ICI Research on Mutual Fund Ownership and on the U.S. Retirement Market

W H I T E P A P E R. Sabrient Multi-cap Insider/Analyst Quant-Weighted Index DAVID BROWN CHIEF MARKET STRATEGIST

The benefits of core-satellite investing

SUMMARY PROSPECTUS May 1, 2018

Yale ICF Working Paper No February 2002 DO WINNERS REPEAT WITH STYLE?

Research Report. The Population of Workers Covered by the Auto IRA: Trends and Characteristics. AARP Public Policy Institute.

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016

Meeder Asset Management, Inc.

QDIA POLICIES: A Guide for Plan Sponsors

Tax Uncertainty and Retirement Savings Diversification

Target-Date Funds: Not as Simple as Set It and Forget It

401(k) Plan Asset Allocation, Account Balances, and Loan Activity in 1998

One COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Performance PART

Behavioral characteristics affecting household portfolio selection in Japan

Building Efficient Hedge Fund Portfolios August 2017

The Hidden Advantage of Long/Short Portfolios

Target-Date Funds, Annuitization and Retirement Investing

Managed Futures as a Crisis Risk Offset Strategy

Vanguard Research February 2016

Who Uses the Roth 401(k), and How Do They Use It?

Treasuries for the Long Run

Behavioral Finance and Its Effect on Pension Portfolios

How 403(b) Plans are Wasting Nearly $10 Billion Annually, and What Can Be Done to Fix It

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework

Presentation to August 14,

Senate Committee on Finance

Prospectus August 1, 2017 as amended November 1, 2017

Rational Defensive Growth Fund Class A Shares: HSUAX Class C Shares: HSUCX Institutional Shares: HSUTX

Target-Date Glide Paths: Balancing Plan Sponsor Goals 1

International and Global Equity Funds

401(k) PLANS ARE STILL COMING UP SHORT

Fuller & Thaler Behavioral Unconstrained Equity Fund Summary Prospectus December 19, 2018

Pioneer Fund VCT Portfolio. Prospectus, May 1, A portfolio of Pioneer Variable Contracts Trust. Class I Shares. Contents

Behavioral Economics and Behavior Change

Quantifying the impact of chasing fund performance

The Balance-Matching Heuristic *

Asset Location for Retirement Savers

Transcription:

SIEPR policy brief Stanford University August 2014 Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research on the web: http://siepr.stanford.edu Menu Choices in Defined Contribution Pension Plans By Clemens Sialm Over the last three decades there have been significant changes in the structure of retirement savings in the United States and across the world. Defined Contribution (DC) pension plans, such as 401(k) and 403(b) plans, have become a more important source of retirement funding for many households while the relative importance of government-provided social security has declined and while firms have switched from Defined Benefit (DB) to DC plans. Thus, more savings and investment decisions need to be taken by households, who might not have the time and knowledge to make these important investment decisions. In addition, there are potential conflicts of interest between DC pension plan service providers and retirement savers. The investment choices that maximize the profitability of the service providers do not necessarily correspond to the optimal choices for retirement savers. It is therefore crucial to scrutinize the impact of the DC plan design on savings and investment decisions. I discuss in this policy brief some key findings from two recent research projects that analyze the mutual fund investment options offered in DC pension plans. The structure of the retirement savings system affects the investment strategies, money flows, and performance of retirement savers. An optimal DC plan design needs to take into account behavioral biases and bounded rationality by retirement savers as well as conflicts of interests by service providers. Mutual Fund Menu Options Mutual fund holdings in employer-sponsored DC plans are an important and growing segment of today s financial markets. Figure continued on inside... About The Author Clemens Sialm is the Mark and Sheila Wolfson Distinguished Visiting Associate Professor at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research and an Associate Professor of Finance at the University of Texas in Austin. He is also a Research Associate in the Asset Pricing and the Public Economics Programs of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). Sialm received a Ph.D. in Economics from Stanford University. He has taught at Stanford University, the University of Michigan, and the University of Texas at Austin. Sialm s research interests are in the areas of investments, asset pricing, and taxation. His research projects analyze the structure of Defined Contribution pension plans. In addition, he studies the investment strategies and the performance of mutual funds and hedge funds. His research has been published in the American Economic Review, the Journal of Finance, the Review of Financial Studies, the Journal of Public Economics, and the Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, among others. Sialm s research has been frequently quoted in the Wall Street Journal, the New York Times, and the Economist.

SIEPR policy brief 1 depicts the total value of mutual fund assets in the United States. Between 1992 and 2013, total mutual funds assets grew from $1.6 trillion to $15 trillion. Mutual funds can be held in DC pension plans, in Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs), and in non-retirement environments. The growth of mutual fund assets has been particularly strong in DC plans. Currently, approximately 23% of mutual fund assets are held in DC plans, 20% in IRAs, and the remaining 57% in nonretirement accounts. 1 Thus, mutual funds have mixed clienteles that differ according to their distribution channels, their time horizons, and their tax implications, as discussed in more detail in Sialm and Starks (2012). 1 2014 Investment Company Handbook and ICI Report on the U.S. Retirement Market, First Quarter 2014. Figure 1 Total Asset Value Held in U.S. Mutual Funds Total Value (in Billions, US$) 16,000 14,000 12,000 10,000 8,000 6,000 4,000 2,000 Total Assets Retirement Assets DC Assets Whereas investors who own mutual funds in IRAs or in nonretirement accounts can choose among the universe of mutual funds, participants in employersponsored DC plans typically have limited choices. These choices arise through a two-stage process. In the first stage, plan sponsors (i.e., the employers) select the DC plan menus and adjust the investment options over time by removing or adding options. In the second stage, plan participants (i.e., the employees) allocate their individual DC account balances among the choices made available to them by the plan sponsors. Thus, the final allocations in DC plans reflect the decisions of both the sponsor and the participants. Sticky vs. Discerning Money Despite the importance of DC mutual fund holdings, little is 0 1992 1997 2002 2007 2012 Non- Retirement IRA DC known about the properties of money flows in DC pension plans. Conventional wisdom suggests that the DC plan assets in mutual funds are sticky and not discerning, as many plan participants exhibit significant inertia in their investment decisions, follow default options, and are reluctant to rebalance and readjust their portfolios. 2 In addition, DC plan participants make periodic retirement account contributions or withdrawals, which lead to persistence in money flows. To test whether DC money flows are sticky and not discerning, Laura Starks, Hanjiang Zhang, and I compare the flows of DC and non-dc mutual fund investors from 1997 to 2010 (Sialm, Starks, and Zhang, 2014). In contrast to the conventional wisdom, we find that money flows into mutual funds by DC plan participants are more volatile and exhibit a lower serial correlation than the flows into mutual funds by other investors. Furthermore, we show that DC flows are more sensitive to prior fund performance than non-dc flows. In fact, the flow-performance sensitivity of DC flows is particularly pronounced for the lowest and highest performance funds. Figure 2 depicts the sensitivity of money flows to prior performance for DC and non-dc assets. We group all U.S. domestic equity funds into percentiles according 2 See, for example, Benartzi and Thaler (2001), Madrian and Shea (2001), and Choi, et al. (2002).

to the fund performance over the prior year. Funds in the lowest percentile correspond to the 1% of mutual funds that exhibit the worst performance over the previous year, whereas funds in the highest percentile correspond to the 1% of funds that exhibit the best performance. The dots in the figure show the average money flows for the performance percentiles after controlling for other fund characteristics. The red diamonds correspond to DC flows and the grey circles correspond to non-dc flows. The solid curves show the least-squares cubic relation for DC and non-dc flows. DC assets on average experience larger fund flows than non-dc assets due to the significant growth of tax-qualified retirement accounts over our sample period. Whereas the flow-performance relation is close to linear for non-dc assets, the relation is clearly nonlinear for DC assets. The flow-performance relation is particularly steep for DC assets corresponding to funds in the top and bottom performance groups. For example, funds in the bottom decile of performance experience an average outflow of 8.3% of their DC assets, and funds in the top decile experience an average inflow of 53.6% of their DC assets. On the other hand, funds in the bottom decile experience an average outflow of 11.8% of their non-dc assets and funds in the top decile experience an average inflow of 17.9% of their non-dc assets. DC retirement flows react more sensitively to performance than non-dc flows. This surprising result could either be driven by the actions of the plan participants or by the actions of the plan sponsors. SEC data allow us to decompose aggregate flows into flows resulting primarily from plan sponsor actions and flows resulting primarily from participant actions. The flow results are predominantly driven by the actions of the plan sponsors, and, consistent with previous research, we confirm that the plan participants themselves exhibit inertia and do not react sensitively to prior fund performance. These results indicate that the actions of plan sponsors in changing their menus counteract the inertia of plan participants. Fund Flow 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 Favoritism in DC Plans Whereas DC plans provide valuable services to retirement savers by adjusting the menu options offered, DC plan service providers often face conflicting incentives concerning the plan s design. Veronika Pool, Irina Stefanescu, and I examine whether mutual fund families acting as service providers (i.e., trustees, record keepers) of 401(k) plans display favoritism toward their own funds (Pool, Sialm, and Stefanescu, 2014). We study whether poorly performing funds are less likely to be removed from and more likely to be added to a 401(k) menu if they are affiliated with the plan service provider. Focusing on fund additions and deletions, we hypothesize that if the trustees Figure 2 Sensitivity of Mutual Fund Money Flows to Prior Performance for DC and Non-DC Assets DC Flow Non-DC Flow 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Performance Percentile

Stanford University August 2014 decisions are driven by their own financial interests, mutual fund service providers may be more inclined to include funds from their own fund lineup even when more suitable options are available from other fund families and more reluctant to remove them. Additionally, mutual fund service providers may also be less sensitive to the performance of affiliated funds in menu-altering decisions as they have an incentive to support their own poorly-performing funds. To investigate this favoritism hypothesis, we hand collect information on the menus of mutual fund options offered in a large sample of DC pension plans for the period 1998 to 2009 from annual filings of Form 11-K with the SEC. Most 401(k) plans in our sample adopt an open architecture 30.0 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 whereby investment options include funds not only from the family of the service provider but from other mutual fund families as well. We find that service providers display significant favoritism toward their own funds. Affiliated funds are more likely to be included and less likely to be removed from 401(k) plans. The biggest difference between affiliated and unaffiliated funds occurs for the worst performing funds, which exhibit significant performance persistence. Figure 3 reports the mean annual deletion frequencies by trustee affiliation for funds grouped into deciles according to their prior percentile performance. Funds are less likely to be deleted from affiliated plans regardless of past performance. For example, the average affiliated fund has a Figure 3 Annual Mutual Fund Deletion Rates from 401(k) Menus by Fund Affiliation Deletion Rates Affiliated Funds Unaffiliated Funds 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Performance Deciles deletion rate over the subsequent year of 14% across all performance deciles, whereas an unaffiliated fund has an average deletion rate of 19%. Furthermore, we find that the difference in deletion rates widens significantly if we focus on poorly performing funds. For example, the probability of deletion for funds in the lowest performance decile equals 26% for unaffiliated funds and just 14% for affiliated funds. Indeed, the deletion rates of affiliated funds in the lowest performance decile are actually lower than the deletion rates of trustee funds in deciles two through four. On the other hand, the probability of deletion for funds in the highest performance decile equals around 15% for both unaffiliated and affiliated funds. While our evidence on favoritism is consistent with adverse trustee incentives, 401(k) service providers may also have superior information about their own proprietary funds. Therefore, it is possible that they show a preference for these funds not because they are necessarily biased toward them, but rather due to positive information they possess about these funds. To investigate this possibility, we examine future fund performance. For instance, if despite lackluster past performance the decision to keep poorly performing trustee funds on the menu is information driven, then they should perform continued on flap

Stanford University August 2014 better in the future. This is not the case: Trustee funds that rank poorly based on past performance but are not delisted from the menu do not perform well in the subsequent year. On average, they underperform by approximately 4% annually on a risk-adjusted basis. This figure is large in and of itself, but its economic significance is magnified in the retirement context by compounding. Our results suggest that the favoritism we document has important implications for the employees income in retirement. Conclusions As households are allocated more responsibility to manage their own retirement savings it becomes important to consider the optimal institutional structure of retirement savings. The two-stage process of asset allocation where the sponsor selects the menu and the participants decide how much to invest in the separate options has the advantage of mitigating the inertia of plan participants. Sponsors, together with service providers, can monitor the available investment choices and decide whether to make adjustments to the lineup. On the other hand, the twostage process can also create agency conflicts, as service providers have an incentive to attract and retain retirement contributions in their own proprietary funds. A systematic analysis of the advantages and disadvantages of different structures of retirement savings is crucial in an environment where retirement savers are subject to behavioral biases and bounded rationality and where financial intermediaries are subject to agency conflicts. References Benartzi, Shlomo, and Richard Thaler, 2001, Naïve diversification strategies in defined contribution savings plans, American Economic Review 91, 79-98. Choi, James J., David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick, 2002, Defined contribution pensions: Plan rules, participant decisions, and the path of least resistance, Tax Policy and the Economy 16, 67-113. Investment Company Institute, 2014, The Investment Company Fact Book. Madrian, Brigitte, and Dennis F. Shea, 2001, The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) participation and savings behavior, Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 1149-1187. Pool, Veronika, Clemens Sialm, and Irina Stefanescu, 2013, It pays to set the menu: 401(k) investment options in mutual funds, Working paper, Indiana University and University of Texas at Austin (http:// ssrn.com/abstract=2112263). Sialm, Clemens, and Laura Starks, 2012, Mutual fund tax clienteles, Journal of Finance 67, 1397-1422. Sialm, Clemens, Laura Starks, and Hanjiang Zhang, 2014, Defined contribution pension plans: Sticky or discerning money? Forthcoming: Journal of Finance (http://ssrn.com/ abstract=2090096).

SIEPR policy brief Stanford University 366 Galvez Street Stanford, CA 94305 MC 6015 A publication of the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Non-Profit Org. U.S. Postage PAID Palo Alto, CA Permit No. 28 SIEPR About SIEPR The Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research (SIEPR) conducts research on important economic policy issues facing the United States and other countries. SIEPR s goal is to inform policymakers and to influence their decisions with long-term policy solutions. Policy Briefs SIEPR policy briefs are meant to inform and summarize important research by SIEPR faculty. Selecting a different economic topic each month, SIEPR will bring you up-to-date information and analysis on the issues involved. SIEPR policy briefs reflect the views of the author. SIEPR is a nonpartisan institute and does not take a stand on any issue. For Additional Copies Please see SIEPR website at http://siepr.stanford.edu.