Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

Similar documents
Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Supplementary Appendix to Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times. and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

Are Government Spending Multipliers State Dependent? Evidence from Canadian Historical Data

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What Have We Learned from. the Renaissance in Fiscal Research?

Government Spending Multipliers under Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

Government Spending Multipliers under Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

Government Spending Multipliers under the Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

Private Debt Overhang and the Government Spending Multiplier: Evidence for the United States

Government Spending Multipliers under the Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

Private Debt Overhang and the Government Spending Multiplier: Evidence for the United States

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Not-for-Publication Appendix to:

Discussion of Corsetti, Meyer and Muller, What Determines Government Spending Multipliers?

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Discussant comments on Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy by J. Bradford DeLong and Lawrence H. Summers

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

The Economic Effects of Government Spending * (Preliminary Draft)

Is Fiscal Policy More Effective in Uncertain Times or During Recessions?

Is it the "How" or the "When" that Matters in Fiscal Adjustments?

The Economic Effects of Government Spending * (First Draft)

FISCAL MULTIPLIERS IN JAPAN

Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in Structural VAR models

Pushing on a string: US monetary policy is less powerful in recessions

What drives the short-run costs of fiscal consolidation? Evidence from OECD countries

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

What determines government spending multipliers?

D6.3 Policy Brief: The role of debt for fiscal effectiveness during crisis and normal times

FISCAL MULTIPLIERS IN JAPAN

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Vector Autoregressions. September 7, 2016

Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes. Robert J. Barro and Charles J. Redlick Harvard University

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FISCAL MULTIPLIERS IN RECESSION AND EXPANSION. Alan J. Auerbach Yuriy Gorodnichenko

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

BIS Working Papers. What drives the short-run costs of fiscal consolidation? Evidence from OECD countries. No 553. Monetary and Economic Department

On the Measurement of the Government Spending Multiplier in the United States An ARDL Cointegration Approach

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. The Government Spending Multiplier at the Zero Lower Bound: International Evidence from Historical Data

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

Empirical Effects of Monetary Policy and Shocks. Valerie A. Ramey

How Large is the Government Spending Multiplier? Evidence from World Bank Lending

Workshop on resilience

The Dynamic Effects of Personal and Corporate Income Tax Changes in the United States

Interest Rate Peg. Rong Li and Xiaohui Tian. January Abstract. This paper revisits the sizes of fiscal multipliers under a pegged nominal

Fiscal Multipliers in Good Times and Bad Times

Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth & Employment

A Review on the Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

What does the empirical evidence suggest about the eectiveness of discretionary scal actions?

Fiscal policy and collateral constraints in an estimated DSGE model:

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence.

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Can tax cuts restore economic growth in bad times?

State-Dependent Effects of Fiscal Policy

What drives the short-run costs of fiscal consolidation? Evidence from OECD countries

Estimating the Economic Impacts of Highway Infrastructure

Non-Linearities and Fiscal Policy

Taxes and the Fed: Theory and Evidence from Equities

Tax multipliers: Pitfalls in measurement and identi cation

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

Asymmetric Effects of Tax Changes

Bonn Summer School Advances in Empirical Macroeconomics

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

What Are The Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks in India?*

How Big (Small) Are Fiscal Multipliers?

The Government Spending Multiplier at. the Zero Lower Bound

Austerity, Inequality, and Private Debt Overhang

It s in the Sign. Regis Barnichon Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, CREI, CEPR. Christian Matthes Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

Ination Expectations and Consumption Expenditure

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

The Output and Welfare Effects of Government Spending Shocks over the Business Cycle *

Assessing the Effects of Government Spending Shocks: Evidence from OECD and Non-OECD Countries

Austerity and Private Debt

The Effects of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from Italy

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IS IT THE "HOW" OR THE "WHEN" THAT MATTERS IN FISCAL ADJUSTMENTS?

The Analytics of SVARs: A Unified Framework to Measure Fiscal Multipliers

Chapter 4. Fiscal Multipliers: How Will Consolidation Affect Latin America and the Caribbean? Regional Economic Outlook: Western Hemisphere May 2018

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Discussion of Fiscal Policy and the Inflation Target

Effects of Fiscal Shocks in a Globalized World

When Is Discretionary Fiscal Policy Effective?

FISCAL POLICY AFTER THE GREAT RECESSION

spillover NOTES The Importance of Macroeconomic and Policy Conditions in Transmission

The Distributional Effects of Government Spending Shocks on Inequality

The link between labor costs and price inflation in the euro area

Discussion of Exits from Recessions by Bordo and Landon-Lane

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Government Sector and the Government Spending Multipliers

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

Austerity in the Aftermath of the Great Recession

Assessing Expectations as a Joint Monetary-Fiscal and State-Dependent Phenomenon

FISCAL STIMULUS AND CONSUMER DEBT

Transcription:

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER and Sarah Zubairy Texas A&M April 2015

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy?

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy? Traditional Keynesian idea: Multipliers are high when there are many idle resources.

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy? Traditional Keynesian idea: Multipliers are high when there are many idle resources. New Keynesian models: Effects of government spending do not depend on the current utilization of resources.

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy? Traditional Keynesian idea: Multipliers are high when there are many idle resources. New Keynesian models: Effects of government spending do not depend on the current utilization of resources. Recent Theories: Only a few papers have tried to link the size of the multiplier to slack in a theoretical model (e.g. Michaillat (2014), Michaillat and Saez (2013), Roulleau-Paseloup (2014))

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy? Traditional Keynesian idea: Multipliers are high when there are many idle resources. New Keynesian models: Effects of government spending do not depend on the current utilization of resources. Recent Theories: Only a few papers have tried to link the size of the multiplier to slack in a theoretical model (e.g. Michaillat (2014), Michaillat and Saez (2013), Roulleau-Paseloup (2014)) Other State Dependent Models

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy? Traditional Keynesian idea: Multipliers are high when there are many idle resources. New Keynesian models: Effects of government spending do not depend on the current utilization of resources. Recent Theories: Only a few papers have tried to link the size of the multiplier to slack in a theoretical model (e.g. Michaillat (2014), Michaillat and Saez (2013), Roulleau-Paseloup (2014)) Other State Dependent Models ZLB or state-dependent monetary policy responses (Eggertson and Woodford (2003), Christiano, Eichenbaum, Rebelo (2011))

Do Multipliers Depend on the State of Economy? Traditional Keynesian idea: Multipliers are high when there are many idle resources. New Keynesian models: Effects of government spending do not depend on the current utilization of resources. Recent Theories: Only a few papers have tried to link the size of the multiplier to slack in a theoretical model (e.g. Michaillat (2014), Michaillat and Saez (2013), Roulleau-Paseloup (2014)) Other State Dependent Models ZLB or state-dependent monetary policy responses (Eggertson and Woodford (2003), Christiano, Eichenbaum, Rebelo (2011)) Countercyclical spreads (Canzoneri et al (2013))

Empirical Literature on Effects of Recessions or Slack

Empirical Literature on Effects of Recessions or Slack Gordon and Krenn (2010) Multipliers are larger if they stop the sample in mid-1941.

Empirical Literature on Effects of Recessions or Slack Gordon and Krenn (2010) Multipliers are larger if they stop the sample in mid-1941. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Use STVAR model on quarterly post-wwii data Find significantly higher multipliers during recessions.

Empirical Literature on Effects of Recessions or Slack Gordon and Krenn (2010) Multipliers are larger if they stop the sample in mid-1941. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Use STVAR model on quarterly post-wwii data Find significantly higher multipliers during recessions. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013, NBER Fiscal Volume) Use Jorda local projection method on panel of OECD countries, semiannual data from 1985 on Find higher multipliers during recessions.

Empirical Literature on Effects of Recessions or Slack Gordon and Krenn (2010) Multipliers are larger if they stop the sample in mid-1941. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Use STVAR model on quarterly post-wwii data Find significantly higher multipliers during recessions. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013, NBER Fiscal Volume) Use Jorda local projection method on panel of OECD countries, semiannual data from 1985 on Find higher multipliers during recessions. Other aggregate analyses e.g. Bachmann and Sims (2012), Fazzari, Morley and Panovska (2012)

Empirical Literature on Effects of Recessions or Slack Gordon and Krenn (2010) Multipliers are larger if they stop the sample in mid-1941. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Use STVAR model on quarterly post-wwii data Find significantly higher multipliers during recessions. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013, NBER Fiscal Volume) Use Jorda local projection method on panel of OECD countries, semiannual data from 1985 on Find higher multipliers during recessions. Other aggregate analyses e.g. Bachmann and Sims (2012), Fazzari, Morley and Panovska (2012) Cross-sectional analyses Most find higher multipliers during periods of slack, but not always statistically different

Literature on the Size of the Multiplier at the ZLB

Literature on the Size of the Multiplier at the ZLB Theoretical DSGE Literature Eggertsson, Woodford, Christiano, Eichenbaum, Rebelo; Fernandez Villaverde et al. Multipliers can be 3X larger at the zero lower bound. Mertens and Ravn (2014), Kiley (2014) present models with multipliers that are smaller at the ZLB.

Literature on the Size of the Multiplier at the ZLB Theoretical DSGE Literature Eggertsson, Woodford, Christiano, Eichenbaum, Rebelo; Fernandez Villaverde et al. Multipliers can be 3X larger at the zero lower bound. Mertens and Ravn (2014), Kiley (2014) present models with multipliers that are smaller at the ZLB. Ramey (2011, QJE) Estimated the model from 1939 through 1949. Estimates a lower multiplier for this period: 0.7.

Literature on the Size of the Multiplier at the ZLB Theoretical DSGE Literature Eggertsson, Woodford, Christiano, Eichenbaum, Rebelo; Fernandez Villaverde et al. Multipliers can be 3X larger at the zero lower bound. Mertens and Ravn (2014), Kiley (2014) present models with multipliers that are smaller at the ZLB. Ramey (2011, QJE) Estimated the model from 1939 through 1949. Estimates a lower multiplier for this period: 0.7. Crafts and Mills (2012) Constructed defense news series for Britain. Estimate multiplier from 1922 through 1938. Estimate multipliers below unity even when interest rates near the ZLB.

Econometric Issues Non-linear VARs. Information in the data. Ex post computation of multipliers.

Goal of this paper To investigate whether multipliers are higher when unemployment is higher or when the economy is near the zero lower bound.

Specific contributions of this paper New historical data for the U.S. encompassing periods with dramatic fluctuations in unemployment and government spending and interest rates near the zero lower bound. Alternative estimation method that avoids nonlinear problems. Alternative method of calculating multipliers. Result: Different conclusions about state dependence.

Roadmap 1. Motivation and Introduction 2. Data 3. Econometric Framework and Issues 4. State Dependence on Slack 5. State Dependence on ZLB 6. Conclusion

Should we worry about including data with major wars?

Should we worry about including data with major wars? The widespread tendency in empirical studies of economic behavior to discard war years as abnormal, while doubtless often justified, is, on the whole, unfortunate. The major defect of the data on which economists must rely - data generated by experience rather than deliberately contrived experiment - is the small range of variation they encompass. Experience in general proceeds smoothly and continuously. In consequence, it is difficult to disentangle systematic effects from random variation since both are of much the same order of magnitude. From this point of view, data for wartime periods are peculiarly valuable. At such times, violent changes in major economic magnitudes occur over relatively brief periods, thereby providing precisely the kind of evidence that we would like (to) get by critical experiments if we could conduct them. Of course, the source of the changes means that the effects in which we are interested are necessarily intertwined with others that we would eliminate from a contrived experiment. But this difficulty applies to all our data, not to data for wartime periods alone. Milton Friedman (1951)

Data Events happen quickly around wars and agents react quickly so we want to use quarterly data. Quarterly historical data for early 20th century not readily available. General strategy: use various higher frequency series to interpolate existing annual series.

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS.

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with:

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939 CPI data back to 1939

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939 CPI data back to 1939 Balke-Gordon quarterly data for 1890-1938

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939 CPI data back to 1939 Balke-Gordon quarterly data for 1890-1938 NBER MacroHistory database monthly federal expenditures and receipts.

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939 CPI data back to 1939 Balke-Gordon quarterly data for 1890-1938 NBER MacroHistory database monthly federal expenditures and receipts. Unemployment rate

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939 CPI data back to 1939 Balke-Gordon quarterly data for 1890-1938 NBER MacroHistory database monthly federal expenditures and receipts. Unemployment rate Use Conference Board, etc. unemployment rates from 1930-1947 to interpolate Weir (1992) annual unemployment rates.

US Historical Data: 1889-2013 1947-2013 - available quarterly from NIPA and CPS. 1890-1946 - interpolate annual Y,G,T, P from NIPA and Historical Stats with: BEA quarterly data on nominal Y and G going back to 1939 CPI data back to 1939 Balke-Gordon quarterly data for 1890-1938 NBER MacroHistory database monthly federal expenditures and receipts. Unemployment rate Use Conference Board, etc. unemployment rates from 1930-1947 to interpolate Weir (1992) annual unemployment rates. Use NBER recession dates for 1890-1929 to interpolate Weir annual series.

Identifying government spending shocks Exogenous. Unanticipated. Narrative method.

Government Spending and GDP Data 5 Log of real per capita government spending 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Log of real per capita GDP 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

Roadmap 1. Motivation and Introduction 2. Data 3. Econometric Framework and Issues 4. State Dependence on Slack 5. State Dependence on ZLB 6. Conclusion

Econometric Framework We use Jorda (2005) local projection method to estimate the impulse response of variable z at horizon t + h. This involves running h sets of regressions. Allows us to easily accommodate state dependence. We allow all coefficients to vary according to whether unemployment is high or low.

Linear model z t+h = α h + ψ h (L)y t 1 + β h shock t + ε t+h, for h = 0, 1, 2,... where y t 1 is a vector of control variables ψ h (L) is a polynomial in the lag operator Coefficient β h gives the response of z t+h to the shock at horizon h.

State dependent model z t+h = I t 1 [α A,h + ψ A,h (L)y t 1 + β A,h shock t ] +(1 I t 1 ) [α B,h + ψ B,h (L)y t 1 + β B,h shock t ] + ε t+h. where The dummy variable, I t = 1 if unemp t > 6.5%. Coefficient β A,h gives the high unemployment state response of z t+h to the shock at horizon h. Coefficient β B,h gives the low unemployment state response of z t+h to the shock at horizon h.

Advantages of the Jorda method Does not impose restrictions on the dynamic pattern of responses like VARs do. The same variables do not have to be used in each equation. Estimates embed the average transitions of the economy from state to state and the tendency of the shock to cause it to leave the state.

Disadvantages of the Jorda method Responses are often less precise and more erratic. Standard errors need to be corrected for serial correlation. Account for this serial correlation induced in regressions when horizon h > 0 by using Newey-West standard errors. Long-run responses tend to oscillate. Cannot conduct experiments that are counter-factual to the data.

Calculating Impulse Responses (IRs) IRs of G and Y are the building blocks for multipliers in a dynamic model. In a linear VAR, IRs are invariant to history, proportional to the size of the shock, and symmetric in the sign of the shock. In a nonlinear VAR, the IRs depend on the history of shocks, are not proportional to the size, and are not symmetric in the sign.

Pitfalls in Calculating Multipliers from IRs

Pitfalls in Calculating Multipliers from IRs Standard SVARs would use ln(g) and ln(y) and then multiply by sample average Y /G to get multiplier: Y G = ln (Y ) ln (G ) Y G

Pitfalls in Calculating Multipliers from IRs Standard SVARs would use ln(g) and ln(y) and then multiply by sample average Y /G to get multiplier: Y G = ln (Y ) ln (G ) Y G In our historical sample, Y/G varies between 2 and 24. ratio

Definition of left hand side variables: z We use the Hall-Barro-Redlick transformation. Y t+h Y t 1 Y t 1 lny t+h lny t 1 G t+h G t 1 Y t 1 (lng t+h lng t 1 ). G t 1 Y t 1

Baseline control variables 2 lags of log real per capita GDP. 2 lags of log real per capita government purchases. 2 lags of news. Quartic trend.

Roadmap 1. Motivation and Introduction 2. Data 3. Econometric Framework and Issues 4. State Dependence on Slack 5. State Dependence on ZLB 6. Conclusion

State Dependence on Slack Definition of Slack Baseline Results Robustness Comparison to the Literature Behavior of Taxes

US Data: 1890-2013 Military news (% of GDP) 60 40 20 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Unemployment rate 20 15 10 5 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Shaded areas indicate time periods when the unemployment rate is above 6.5 %

Is Military News a Relevant Instrument? 20 Full Sample 20 Full Sample with no WWII 15 15 10 10 5 5 0 20 0 5 10 15 h Post WWII Sample 0 0 5 10 15 h 15 10 Linear High unemployment Low unemployment 5 0 0 5 10 15 h The lines show the F-statistic on news for each horizon in the baseline model. Statistics are capped at 20.

State Dependence on Slack Definition of Slack Baseline Results Robustness Comparison to the Literature Behavior of Taxes

Linear Model Government spending GDP 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0 5 10 15 20 quarter 0 5 10 15 20 quarter Grey areas are 95% confidence intervals.

State Dependent Model Government Spending GDP 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.2 0 0 5 10 15 20 quarter 5 10 15 20 quarter Blue lines are high unemployment state, red lines are low unemployment state.

Multipliers Multipliers account for dynamics of G, and defined as: H i=1 Y i H i=1 G i Linear High Low P-value for Model Unemp Unemp difference across states 2 year integral 0.76 0.69 0.78 (0.102) (0.094) (0.187) 0.631 4 year integral 0.84 0.76 0.96 (0.092) (0.060) (0.218) 0.331

Cumulative Multipliers by Horizon Linear: cumulative spending multiplier 2.2 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 2 State dependent: cumulative spending multiplier 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 quarter Blue lines are high unemployment state, red lines are low unemployment state.

Summary of Baseline Results Both GDP and government spending have more robust responses during high unemployment states. The multipliers are usually less than 1. No evidence of larger multipliers during periods of slack in the economy.

State Dependence on Slack Definition of Slack Baseline Results Robustness Comparison to the Literature Behavior of Taxes

Using time-varying unemployment rate threshold: US News (% of GDP) 60 40 20 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Unemployment rate 20 15 10 5 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 year Time varying threshold of HP filtered unemployment with λ = 1, 000, 000 Linear High Unemp Low Unemp 2 year integral 0.76 0.73 0.78 4 year integral 0.84 0.82 0.92

Other Robustness Checks Using linearly interpolated data - slightly lower multipliers than baseline. Using AG function of 7 quarter moving average of output growth - similar to baseline. Excluding WWII Rationing - multipliers are 1-1.26, but they are lower when unemployment is high. Post WWII Data Estimated multipliers across states vary wildly, from -5 to 25. F-statistics for news during slack states are low.

State Dependence on Slack Definition of Slack Baseline Results Robustness Comparison to the Literature Behavior of Taxes

Comparison to Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Multipliers of 2.2 in recessions and -0.3 in expansions in the U.S.

Comparison to Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Multipliers of 2.2 in recessions and -0.3 in expansions in the U.S. Details of their specification: X t = [1 F (z t 1 )] Π E (L) X t 1 +F (z t 1 ) Π R (L) X t 1 + Π Z (L) z t 1 + u t,

Comparison to Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Multipliers of 2.2 in recessions and -0.3 in expansions in the U.S. Details of their specification: X t = [1 F (z t 1 )] Π E (L) X t 1 +F (z t 1 ) Π R (L) X t 1 + Π Z (L) z t 1 + u t, Blanchard-Perotti identification.

Comparison to Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, AEJ) Multipliers of 2.2 in recessions and -0.3 in expansions in the U.S. Details of their specification: X t = [1 F (z t 1 )] Π E (L) X t 1 +F (z t 1 ) Π R (L) X t 1 + Π Z (L) z t 1 + u t, Blanchard-Perotti identification. Impulse responses assume that the economy does not leave its current state for at least 20 quarters.

AG-12 Impulse Responses Black line - linear; Blue - recession; Red - expansion.

Using Jorda method on AG (2012, AEJ) post-wwii data and threshold Linear: Government spending Linear: GDP 1.5 2 1 1 0.5 0 0 1 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 State dependent: Government Spending State dependent: GDP 2 6 4 1 2 0 1 5 10 15 20 quarter 0 2 5 10 15 20 quarter Blue lines are high unemployment state, red lines are low unemployment state.

Comparison of Multipliers AG-12 s Estimates Extreme Extreme Recession Expansion Difference 5 year integral 2.24-0.33 2.57 (0.24) (0.20) 2 year integral 1.65 0.10 1.55 Jordà Method Applied to AG Specification 5 year integral 0.84-0.59 1.43 2 year integral 0.24 0.36-0.12

Why is the Jorda Method Producing Different Results? Auerbach-Gorodnichenko method for calculating impulse responses. Compute the impulse responses for each state assuming the economy stays in that state. Their baseline results assume the government spending shock can t change the state. They compute alternative multipliers allowing partial feedback of government spending on the state. Jorda Method Embeds the historical state transition tendencies into the h-period ahead forecast. Embeds the historical effect of government spending shocks into the h-period ahead forecast.

Isolating the Differences We use AG-12 s STVAR parameter estimates. We compute alternative impulse response functions allowing historical state transitions and/or effects of government spending on the state of the economy.

Alternative Multipliers using AG s STVAR Estimates Severe Severe Specification Recession Expansion Difference Constant State, 2.16-0.31 2.47 No Feedback Actual State Dynamics, 1.41 0.19 1.22 No Feedback AG Partial Feedback 1.36-0.04 1.40 Actual State Dynamics, 1.07 0.14 0.93 Partial Feedback The multipliers shown are 5 year integral multipliers.

Comparison to Second AG Paper: AG-13 Despite using the Jorda method, AG-13 report finding higher multipliers in recessions. They calculate multipliers in a non-standard way - relative to initial shock, not cumulative change in government spending. Their estimates are also affected by using the ex post conversion factor. We show that applying their method to our estimates also results in higher multipliers during recessions.

State Dependence on Slack Definition of Slack Baseline Results Robustness Comparison to the Literature Behavior of Taxes

Taxes Most increases in government spending are financed partly with deficits and partly with distortionary taxes. Romer-Romer find large, negative tax multipliers. Thus, it is important to consider how the government spending is financed.

Taxes Most increases in government spending are financed partly with deficits and partly with distortionary taxes. Romer-Romer find large, negative tax multipliers. Thus, it is important to consider how the government spending is financed. We will modify our baseline model to include tax rates and deficits.

Taxes Most increases in government spending are financed partly with deficits and partly with distortionary taxes. Romer-Romer find large, negative tax multipliers. Thus, it is important to consider how the government spending is financed. We will modify our baseline model to include tax rates and deficits. Tax rates are defined as nominal federal receipts divided by nominal GDP.

Responses of taxes and deficits Government spending 0.6 GDP 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 Tax rate Deficit 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.05 0.2 0.1 0 0 5 10 15 20 0.1 5 10 15 20 Ratio of cumulative deficit to cumulative spending 0.5 0 0.5 5 10 15 20 Note: These are responses for taxes and deficits in the linear model. The shaded areas indicate 95% confidence bands.

Responses of taxes and deficits 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Government Spending 5 10 15 20 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 GDP 5 10 15 20 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 Tax rate 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Deficit 5 10 15 20 Ratio of cumulative deficit to cumulative spending 5 10 15 20 quarter 0.5 0 0.5 5 10 15 20 quarter Blue lines are high unemployment state, red lines are low unemployment state.

Observations on the Behavior of Tax Rates and Deficits If anything, a higher fraction of expenditures are financed with deficits during slack periods. Thus, the behavior of taxes can t seem to explain why multipliers aren t higher during times of slack. Tax rates lag the increase in spending. If this is anticipated, then intertemporal substitution effects mean that multipliers are larger than for the lump-sum case.

Roadmap 1. Motivation and Introduction 2. Data 3. Econometric Framework and Issues 4. State Dependence on Slack 5. State Dependence on ZLB 6. Conclusion

Behavior of Interest Rates Military news (% of GDP) 60 40 20 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 15 Tbill rate 10 5 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Shaded areas indicate time periods which we classify as the zero lower bound period.

Taylor Rule vs. Actual Interest Rates 30 20 10 0 10 20 30 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 nominal interest rate = 1 + 1.5 year-over-year inflation rate + 0.5 output gap

Is Military News a Relevant Instrument? Full Sample Full Sample with no WWII 20 20 15 15 10 10 5 5 0 0 5 10 15 h 0 0 5 10 15 h The lines show the F-statistic on news for each horizon in the baseline model. Statistics are capped at 20.

State Dependent Model - ZLB Government Spending GDP 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 5 10 15 20 quarter 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 5 10 15 20 quarter Blue lines are ZLB state, red lines are normal state.

Multipliers Across Monetary Policy Regimes Multipliers account for dynamics of G, and defined as: M i=1 Y i M i=1 G i Linear Near Zero Normal P-value for difference Model Lower Bound in multipliers across states 2 year integral 0.76 0.81 0.57 (0.102) (0.139) (0.191) 0.356 4 year integral 0.84 0.76 0.85 (0.092) (0.073) (0.501) 0.860

Robustness Checks on Full Sample Define ZLB as Treasury Bill < 0.5 - similar to baseline. Blanchard-Perotti identification - similar to baseline. Including taxes - similar to baseline. Including inflation - similar to baseline.

Robustness Checks on Sample Excluding WWII Linear Near Zero Normal P-value for difference Model Lower Bound in multipliers across states 2 year integral 1.01 1.59 0.57 (0.376) (0.532) (0.192) 0.126 4 year integral 1.26 1.06 0.85 (0365) (0.364) (0.501) 0.790 Differences are larger if use Blanchard-Perotti (1.88 vs. 0.47 for 2-year). Differences are smaller if include taxes as controls (1.19 vs. 0.71 for 2-year). Differences are similar if include inflation.

Roadmap 1. Motivation and Introduction 2. Data 3. Econometric Framework and Issues 4. State Dependence on Slack 5. State Dependence on ZLB 6. Conclusion

Conclusion In the full historical sample, we observe that both GDP and government spending respond more to a news shock during slack times. However, there is no difference in multipliers - all multipliers in the linear and state dependent models are estimated to be between 0.8 and 1.1. Our results differ from Auerbach-Gorodnichenko because our estimates incorporate the natural propensity of the economy to transition between states. We find weak evidence of higher multipliers when interest rates are at the ZLB only if we exclude WWII.

Ratio of Y/G in US 25 Y/G 20 15 10 5 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Back

Extra Response of Private Activity (Y-G) 2 1.5 Government spending 0.4 0.3 0.2 Private activity 1 0.1 0.5 0 0 0.1 0.5 0.2 10 20 30 40 quarter 10 20 30 40 quarter Suggests output multiplier of less than 1. Back

Extra Ratio of G/Y in US 0.5 G/Y 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000