POLICY BRIEF. Tax legislation enacted in 2001 increased the value of the Child Tax

Similar documents
The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson. December 2006

One of the closest and most

THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE MINIMUM TAX: HISTORICAL DATA

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

Senator Kerry s Tax Proposals. Leonard E. Burman and Jeffrey Rohaly 1 Revised July 23, 2004

An Analysis of the 2004 House Tax Cuts. Leonard E. Burman 1 The Urban Institute and The Tax Policy Center. June 2004

Tax Policy Issues and Options

New Analysis Finds GOP Tax Plan would Give Richest One Percent of CT Residents $125,380 More Per Year on Average than Obama s Approach

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF THE FAMILY FAIRNESS AND OPPORTUNITY TAX REFORM ACT

HOW DO PHASEOUTS WORK?

Options to Fix the AMT

UPDATED OPTIONS TO REFORM THE DEDUCTION FOR HOME MORTGAGE INTEREST. Amanda Eng Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center May 7, 2014

July 17, Summary

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

In a typical month in 2001, 17.3 million. Welfare Reform & Beyond. Food Stamps and Welfare Reform. Michael Wiseman. Policy Brief No.

Federal Tax Policy and the States

Hundreds of millions at stake for New York s working families: Current tax debate to determine future of key work-supporting tax credits

Middle Class Tax Relief Act of 2012

The Effect of the 2001 Tax Cut on. Low- and Middle-Income Families and Children

Investing in Children

Understanding the Effects of the 2001, 2003, and 2004 Income Tax Cuts

WINNERS AND LOSERS AFTER PAYING FOR THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

The Child Tax Credit: Current Law and Legislative History

Using Refundable Tax Credits to Help Lowincome

Suppose they took the AM out of the AMT?

Federal Tax Cuts in the Bush, Obama, and Trump Years

The Bush Tax Cut: One Year Later

The Child Tax Credit: Current Law and Legislative History

GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH CENTER May 14, 1999

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): Legislation in the 113 th Congress

REFORMING CHARITABLE TAX INCENTIVES: ASSESSING EVIDENCE AND POLICY OPTIONS

FASB Looks to. Leslie F. Seidman, FASB Chair. Annual Tax Update Marriage and Taxes Estate Tax Portability Tax Preferences for Education

Thomas Gais and R. Kent Weaver

Strengthening the EITC for Childless Workers Would Promote Work and Reduce Poverty

F I S C A L P O L I C Y I N S T I T U T E 1 LEAR JET LANE / LATHAM, NEW YORK / (518)

The Effects of the Candidates Tax Plans on Households at Different Income Levels: Examples

The federal tax code. The Brookings Institution POLICY BRIEF

The Bush Tax Cuts and the Economy

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Alan Berube, Fellow

AN OPTION TO REFORM THE INCOME TAX TREATMENT OF FAMILIES AND WORK

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

The Minnesota and Federal Dependent Care Tax Credits

The 1990s produced a host of unexpected

Extension of Saving and Investment Incentives

OVERVIEW OF TAX CHANGES IN THE JOBS AND GROWTH TAX RELIEF RECONCILIATION ACT OF 2003

Revised January 6, 2006

EFFECTS OF THE TAX REFORM PANEL S PROPOSALS ON LOW- AND MODERATE-INCOME HOUSEHOLDS By Aviva Aron-Dine and Joel Friedman 1

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty

ALLOWING STATES TO PAY FOR STATE CHARITABLE CONTRIBUTION TAX CREDITS OUT OF TANF BLOCK GRANTS WOULD NOT BE AN EFFECTIVE USE OF FEDERAL WELFARE FUNDS

SPECIAL REPORT. IMPACT. At this time, the framework is just a proposal. No legislative. IMPACT. If a tax reform package moves in Congress under the

Introduction. Many of the papers included are preliminary and subject to revision - please contact the author before quoting or citing.

FEDERAL INCOME TAX IMPLICATONS OF THE ACA MANDATE FOR INDIVIDUAL TAXPAYERS

Options to Limit the Benefit of Tax Expenditures for High-Income Households

Georgetown Center on Poverty, Inequality and Public Policy

Revised November 21, 2008

Rural America Benefits From Expanded Use of the Federal Tax Code for Income Support

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding membership eligibility for North Carolina s

THE STATUTORY PAY-AS-YOU-GO ACT OF 2010: A DESCRIPTION

The Minnesota and Federal Dependent Care Tax Credits

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina s Earned Income

There are several types of tax-favored retirement

From Welfare to Work: What the Evidence Shows

Lots of plans to boost tax credits: Which is best?

Expiring Tax Provisions

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

The Minnesota Income Tax Marriage Credit

Tax Policy for Low-Income Families: The Earned Income Tax Credit

The Minnesota and Federal Dependent Care Tax Credits

Tax Subsidies to Help Low-Income Families Pay for Child Care

The Child and Dependent Care Credit: Impact of Selected Policy Options

The Federal Earned Income Tax Credit and The Minnesota Working Family Credit

Governor s tax cut plan sets stage for service cuts Reforms for fairness and simplicity could be achieved without losing revenue

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

Overview of the Federal Tax System

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

Summary of the Latest Federal Income Tax Data, 2018 Update

BTC Reports. Executive Summary. NC Justice Center. North Carolina Budget & Tax Center. P.O. Box Raleigh, NC

2019 Tax Brackets. FISCAL FACT No. 624 Nov Amir El-Sibaie

What we know and are learning about the EITC Kartik Athreya March 31, 2015

SPECIAL REPORT. IMPACT. Many of the changes to the Internal Revenue Code in the INDIVIDUALS

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

Changes in Refundable Tax Credits

The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): An Overview

on-line Reports Low-Income Tax Policy: Increases in Tax Credits for Tax Year 2003 are Good News for Working Families

Tax Transfer Policy and Labor Market Outcomes

Dan Bloom and Don Winstead

Who Pays? The Unfairness of Connecticut s State and Local Tax System

THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON FISCAL RESPONSIBILITY AND REFORM. The Moment of Truth

Desperately Seeking Revenue

Credit Where Credit is (Over) Due

DISTRIBUTIONAL ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT AS PASSED BY THE HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS COMMITTEE

D A T A D I G E S T PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI. Extending Preferences for Dividends and Capital Gains: Who Gains the Most?

Executive Summary. Effects of the Federal Tax Law on the State of Maryland Page 1 of 41

Make Tax Time Pay! New Developments 2009

Federal Tax Reform and State and Local Governments

Income Tax Changes, Estate Tax Changes And Implications for Charitable Giving Of the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001

SPECIAL REPORT. IMPACT. Many of the changes to the Internal Revenue Code in the INDIVIDUALS

Revised Senate Plan Would Raise Taxes on at Least 29% of Americans and Cause 19 States to Pay More Overall (State-by-State Figures in Appendix)

Transcription:

The Brookings Institution POLICY BRIEF July 2003 Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 Related Brookings Resources One Percent for the Kids Isabel V. Sawhill, ed. Brookings Institution Press (2003) Welfare Reform and Beyond: The Future of the Safety Net Isabel V. Sawhill, R. Kent Weaver, Ron Haskins, and Andrea Kane, eds. Brookings Institution Press (2002) The New World of Welfare Rebecca Blank and Ron Haskins, eds. Brookings Institution Press (2001) Ending Welfare as We Know It R. Kent Weaver Brookings Institution Press (2000) The Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center www.taxpolicycenter.org For more information on the Brookings Welfare Reform & Beyond Initiative and a full archive of the WR&B Policy Brief series, go to www.brookings.edu/wrb Tax Reform for Families: An Earned Income Child Credit BY ADAM CARASSO, JEFFREY ROHALY, AND C. EUGENE STEUERLE Tax legislation enacted in 2001 increased the value of the Child Tax Credit (CTC) and made it refundable, meaning that cash payments would be sent by the IRS to those without sufficient tax liability to take advantage of the credit. These provisions were to be fully phased in by 2010. In May 2003, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (JGTRRA) accelerated the phase-in of the value of the credit (but not the refundability provisions), thereby increasing the CTC from $600 to $1,000 but for 2003 and 2004 only; the credit reverts back to its prior law value of $700 in 2005. More legislation is likely on this front. This brief argues that the time is ripe for an integrated credit that combines the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) and the CTC into an Earned Income Child Credit (EICC). The proposed EICC simplifies and standardizes the definition of qualifying children and those who may claim them, and indexes the new credit for inflation so that it retains its purchasing power over time. The EICC also provides enhanced benefits to low-income working families and reduces marginal tax rates. One version would cost $6 billion relative to current law (JGTRRA) in calendar year 2003. The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave., N.W. Washington, DC 20036 In recent years, the expansion of family tax credits has provided substantial new, work-dependent benefits for low- and middle-income families. In 2002, the U.S. government spent about $32 billion on families via the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), and $26 billion via the Child Tax Credit (CTC), compared to $21 billion on cash welfare. Although this expansion has been valuable to families, the proliferation of credits has created a bewildering array of provisions including the following: Earned Income Tax Credit The EITC is a refundable credit intended to reward work among low-income families, especially those with children. Families receive the credit as a cash benefit when there is no tax liability to offset. The value of the credit increases with earnings up to a maximum of about All Policy Briefs are available on the Brookings website at www.brookings.edu.

Adam Carasso is a research associate at the Urban Institute in Washington, D.C. Jeffrey Rohaly is a research associate at the Urban Institute in Washington, D.C. C. Eugene Steuerle is a senior fellow at the Urban Institute in Washington, D.C. $4,000 for a family with two children and then begins to phase out at incomes above approximately $14,000. To encourage marriage, the 2001 tax law allows married parents to qualify at a somewhat higher level of income than single parents. The EITC can be claimed for children under age nineteen, or under age twenty-four if they are still in college. Child Tax Credit The 2001 tax law called for a gradual doubling of this credit, which can only be claimed for children under age seventeen, from $500 to $1,000 by 2010. The 2001 legislation also made the credit partly refundable, like the EITC, for families earning over $10,500 in 2003. JGTRRA accelerated this increase in the CTC, providing the $1,000 credit in 2003 rather than 2010, but with a catch: the child credit increase, as written, sunsets after 2004, so at that point the CTC reverts back to levels of less than $1,000 for all years leading up to 2010. Furthermore, JGTRRA does not accelerate the refundable portion of the credit although Congress is currently debating on the subject and does not index the $1,000 credit for inflation. Dependent Exemption The personal exemption, applied to dependents, is $3,050 per child in 2003 and is indexed to inflation. At a 15 percent tax rate, the dependent exemption is worth $458 per child in reduced taxes, but is phased out for families above a certain income level. However, current law calls for the gradual elimination of this phase-out after 2005. The definition of an eligible child is the same as for the EITC. Single Head of Household (HOH) Status Single filers with children enjoy brackets and standard deductions that are more beneficial than single filers without children. This benefit for having children is not available on joint returns, although joint returns (with and without children) do have a lower rate schedule. WHY AN INTEGRATED CHILD CREDIT? Because the rules governing the four tax measures described above are so confusing, errors are common. Some families entitled to benefits do not file for them; others that are not entitled receive benefits anyway. The costs of compliance are a burden on families and also on the Treasury Department, which must administer, award, and audit these benefits. Moreover, the public is hard-pressed to understand fully who gets which benefits under what circumstances. The complexity, time and compliance issues associated with this patchwork of children s tax benefits have been documented by the IRS Taxpayer Advocate; both the Treasury Department and the Joint Committee on Taxation have suggested ways to harmonize definitions of qualifying children (and pending child credit legislation contains Treasury s definition). Further evidence of complexity is revealed by the reliance of many families on paid tax preparers. Low-income households that file for the EITC are about 9 to 17 percent more likely to use a preparer than those who do not file for this credit. Furthermore, the IRS is about to require many families filing for the EITC to pre- 2 Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 July 2003

certify by presenting tax authorities with marriage and birth certificates and affidavits from landlords and doctors to prove eligibility. These requirements could add huge delays to credit receipt and further discourage many families from applying for the credit. HOW THE EARNED INCOME CHILD CREDIT WOULD WORK An ideal reform would integrate all four of the tax provisions discussed above. Although this does not seem feasible in the short run, since the focus now is mainly on accelerating the phase-in of the 2001 legislation, an initial set of steps could be taken toward making these credits simpler, more generous, and less discouraging of work. Our proposed Earned Income Child Credit (EICC) would impose a single definition for qualifying children, those who may claim the credit, and the income used to determine the amount of the credit. This proposal would not change the basic structure of the EITC and CTC only blend the two into a seamless, more generous credit from the tax filer s standpoint. The specific parameters we suggest for the EICC appear in table 1, alongside pre- JGTRRA law and the child credit provisions of JGTRRA. The EICC has an EITC TABLE 1. PARAMETERS OF PROPOSED EARNED INCOME CHILD CREDIT COMPARED TO PRIOR LAW AND CURRENT LAW (JGTRRA) Parameter Prior Law (EITC & CTC) JGTRRA (Current Law) Earned Income Child Credit EITC Phase-in rates 34% for 1 child; 40% for 2 or more 38% for 1 child; 50% for 2 or more EITC Phase-in range of income to $7,500 for 1 child; to $10,540 for 2 or more to $6,750 for 1 child; to $8,470 for 2 or more EITC Phase-out rates 15.98% for 1 child; 21.06% for 2 or more 14% for 1 child; 19% for 2 or more EITC Phase-out range of income $13,760 to $33,780 (HOH); $14,760 to $34,780 (MFJ) $13,760 to $36,050 (HOH); $14,760 to $37,050 (MFJ) Child credit refundability rate 10% in 2003-4; 15% thereafter 15% in all years Child credit refundability threshold $10,500; indexed for inflation Child credit value (2003 dollars) $600 in 2003; $841 in 2010 $1,000 in 2003; $666 in 2005; $841 in 2010 $1,000 in 2003, 2005, and 2010 Child credit indexation Credit not indexed for inflation Credit indexed for inflation Child credit phase-out threshold $75,000 for singles; $110,000 for joint; not indexed for inflation $60,000 for singles; $90,000 for joint; not indexed for inflation Method of child credit phase-out $50 reduction for every $1,000 of added AGI.05 reduction for every $1.00 of added AGI Cost in 2003 $6.3 billion (one version) Cost in 2010 No additional cost $9.3 billion Note: Costs are in 2003 dollars and measured relative to JGTRRA HOH = Head of Household; MFJ = Married Filing Jointly; EITC = Earned Income Tax Credit; CTC = Child Tax Credit. Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 July 2003 3

Note that because JGTRRA only increases the child tax credit from $600 to $1,000, it only benefits those families that currently receive the maximum $600 child tax credit. portion and a child credit portion. The EITC portion would phase in at more generous rates than prior law and JGTRRA, providing a larger refund to those on the bottom rung of the income ladder. It would also phase out more slowly, leaving families with slightly lower marginal tax rates. Beginning in 2003, the EICC would raise the child credit from $600 to $1,000, increase the refundability rate from 10 to 15 percent, and index the credit for inflation after 2003. JGTRRA, by contrast, increases the CTC to $1,000 in 2003, but would not increase the refundability rate from 10 percent and would not index the child credit for inflation. For most families, the total EICC would be at least as high as the combined EITC and CTC they receive under current law. The EICC would give families with qualifying seventeen- and eighteen-year-olds a $1,000 child tax credit they do not receive under current law. The EICC would exclude families with children aged nineteen through twenty-three (and in college) that receive the EITC under current law. Lastly, the child credit would phase out starting at $90,000 for joint returns and $60,000 for other returns, as opposed to $110,000 and $75,000 respectively under both prior law and JGTRRA. The EICC differs from JGTRRA in 2003 as a result of its higher EITC phase-in rates, its more immediate application of a 15 percent child credit refundability rate, and its lower EITC phase-out rates. In 2010, the key differences are again the higher phase-in rates and lower phase-out rates and the indexation of the EICC s minimum child credit to inflation. JGTRRA spends $16.8 billion in calendar year 2003 on the CTC. This version of the EICC would spend $6.3 billion more. In 2010, the EICC would cost $9.3 billion more (in real 2003 dollars); JGTRRA has no additional cost in 2010 since it merely accelerates the child tax credit provisions already in current law without indexing them for inflation. Out of the EICC s $9.3 billion price tag in 2010, $7.5 billion would go to indexing for inflation, while the remaining $1.8 billion is the cost of its increased generosity. Other versions of the EICC, some with lower costs, have been designed and analyzed using the Urban Institute- Brookings Institution Tax Policy Center Tax Model, which is similar to those used by the Treasury and the Congressional Budget Office. More information about these other versions, along with their costs and benefits, can be obtained from the authors upon request. WINNERS AND LOSERS Winners under the EICC would be families with children under age nineteen who reside with the taxpayer, particularly those families with children aged seventeen and eighteen, and those families that earn under $90,000 per year if married and $60,000 per year if single. Table 2 compares the potential impacts of the EICC and the child credit provisions in JGTRRA by income group in 2003. As shown by the figures at the top of the first column, the EICC would provide 4 Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 July 2003

TABLE 2. DISTRIBUTIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF THE EICC AND THE CHILD CREDIT PROVISIONS IN JGTRRA RELATIVE TO PRIOR LAW IN CALENDAR YEAR 2003, BY INCOME FIFTHS 1 Bottom Second Middle Fourth Top Fifth All Fifth Fifth Fifth Fifth 80%-90% 90%-100% Fifths Total Decrease in Income Tax Liability (Millions) All Filers JGTRRA 2003 2 $58 $3,709 $5,732 $5,407 $1,746 $129 $16,817 EICC 3 $1,321 $7,152 $7,673 $6,526 $374 $8 $23,158 Average Decrease in Income Tax Liability per Filer 4 Filers with Children JGTRRA 2003 $7 $289 $502 $460 $346 $28 $303 EICC $155 $550 $672 $552 $74 $2 $418 All Filers JGTRRA 2003 $2 $114 $176 $166 $107 $8 $103 EICC $42 $219 $235 $200 $23 $142 Percent Increase in After-Tax Income Filers with Children JGTRRA 2003 0.1% 1.3% 1.4% 0.8% 0.4% 0.0% 0.6% EICC 2.7% 2.6% 1.9% 1.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.8% All Filers JGTRRA 2003 0.0% 0.7% 0.7% 0.4% 0.2% 0.0% 0.3% EICC 1.1% 1.4% 0.9% 0.5% 0.0% 0.0% 0.4% Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model. 1 Income is equivalent to adjusted gross income plus nontaxable social security benefits, nontaxable pension income, and tax-exempt interest income. Income has been adjusted for family size using the implicit adjustment factors in the federal poverty thresholds. Returns with negative income have been excluded from the lowest fifth but are included in the totals. Baseline is pre-jgtrra law. 2 JGTRRA accelerates the increases in the child tax credit scheduled in the 2001 tax cut (EGTRRA), from $600 to $1,000, but these increases are only temporary. The child credit reverts back to the amounts set forth in EGTRRA after 2004. 3 The Earned Income Child Credit combines the Earned Income Tax Credit and the Child Tax Credit into a single credit, working off 2001 tax law (EGTRRA) parameters for the most part. Qualifying children must be under age 19. 4 Or increase in refunded amount. $1.3 billion more than prior law to the poorest fifth of all families, whereas JGTRRA s child credit provisions would allocate $58 million to the same group. At the other end of the income spectrum, the EICC would provide $380 million more than current law to the richest fifth compared to JGTRRA s $1.9 billion. This result is mirrored in the average tax refund families would receive, also shown in Table 2. The EICC would provide the bottom-fifth of families an average additional tax refund of $155 compared to JGTRRA s $7. By contrast, it would provide the top fifth of families an average additional tax refund of $38 compared to JGTRRA s $187 (not shown in table). Note that because JGTRRA only increases the child tax credit from $600 to $1,000, it only benefits those families that currently receive the maximum $600 child tax credit. Those families that currently receive a CTC under $600 such as a head of household with one child earning below $14,800 or a married couple with two children earning below $19,300 will not benefit. This has to do with the CTC s Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 July 2003 5

FIGURE 1. TAX BENEFITS AND MARGINAL RATES FOR A HEAD OF HOUSEHOLD WITH TWO CHILDREN Real 2003 Value of Tax Benefits Graph 1. Children s Tax Benefits Under Pre-JGTRRA Law, 2003 $6,000 $5,500 EITC Child Tax Credit Dependent Exemption $5,000 $4,500 $4,000 $3,500 $3,000 $2,500 $2,000 $1,500 $1,000 $500 $20,000 $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000 $120,000 $140,000 Real Adjusted Gross Income In revising and combining the EITC and CTC, it is possible to improve: (1) simplicity; (2) work incentives and net income from work at the bottom of the income distribution; and (3) benefits for most families with children. Real 2003 Value of Tax Benefits $6,000 $5,500 $5,000 $4,500 $4,000 $3,500 $3,000 $2,500 $2,000 $1,500 $1,000 $500 Real 2003 Value of Tax Benefits Graph 2. Children s Tax Benefits: Pre-JGTRRA Law, the EICC, and the Child Credit Provisions in JGTRRA in 2003 $6,000 $5,500 $5,000 $4,500 $4,000 $3,500 $3,000 $2,500 $2,000 $1,500 $1,000 $500 $20,000 $20,000 Pre-JGTRRA EICC JGTRRA $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000 $120,000 $140,000 Real Adjusted Gross Income Graph 3. Children s Tax Benefits: EICC vs. the Child Credit Provisions in JGTRRA, 2010 JGTRRA/Prior Law EICC $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000 $120,000 $140,000 Real Adjusted Gross Income Marginal Tax Rates Graph 4. Marginal Tax Rates: EICC Vs. Pre-JGTRRA Law in 2003 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 0-10% -20% -30% -40% -50% -60% 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 Real Adjusted Gross Income Source: Carasso, Rohaly, and Steuerle, 2003 100,000 120,000 140,000 Current Law EICC 6 Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 July 2003

TABLE 3. TAX BENEFITS AT SELECT INCOME LEVELS BY OPTION Family Income Level (in 2003 Dollars) Option $9,000 $21,000 $33,000 In 2003 EICC $4,062 $5,517 $3,494 JGTRRA $3,427 $4,884 $3,079 Difference $635 $633 $415 In 2010 EICC $4,062 $5,568 $3,485 JGTRRA $3,427 $5,078 $2,748 Difference $635 $490 $737 Note: Data points are taken from Graphs 2 and 3 of Figure 1 and apply to a head of household with two children. Baseline is pre-jgtrra law. refundability and has been a subject of recent intense debate in Congress. In addition, under JGTRRA, all families are scheduled for an effective tax increase, because first, the legislation does not extend past 2004, and second, JGTRRA fails to index the CTC for inflation. Although there are few losers under the EICC, these losers are worth noting. Taxpayers who currently claim the EITC for college-age children are one group. We believe that college financing for lowincome individuals is better directed through other federal education programs such as Pell Grants. Other losers would include some taxpayers earning over $90,000 per year if married and $60,000 per year if single, corresponding to the start of the phase-out of the EICC s child credit; taxpayers with children living away from home; and taxpayers who are married but who file separately. Another way to see who would win and who would lose is to look at the four graphs in figure 1. Graph 1 shows the value of the major children s tax benefits under current law for a typical family in 2003. Graph 2 compares the tax benefits offered under the EICC to the child credit provisions in JGTRRA in 2003. Winners include those earning less than about $25,000 who benefit because of the credit s more generous phase-in rate and its use of a 15 percent refundability rate in the child credit portion, compared to JGTRRA s (and prior law s) 10 percent rate. The EICC continues to provide significantly higher tax benefits than JGTRRA even though each has a $1,000 per child credit up through $36,000 of family income, because of the EICC s lower phase-out rate. Graph 3 compares the EICC option and JGTRRA in 2010. Compared to current law and the Bush administration s proposal, the family would be significantly better off in 2010 than in 2003 with the EICC since the child credit portion is indexed to inflation. Finally, graph 4 shows the EICC s impact on marginal tax rates in ADDITIONAL READING Ellwood, David T., and Jeffrey B. Liebman. 2000. The Middle Class Parent Penalty: Child Benefits in the U.S. Tax Code (NBER Working Paper No. 8031). Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research. Gale, William G., and Jeffrey Rohaly. 2002, November. Effects of Tax Simplification Options on Equity, Efficiency, and Simplicity: A Quantitative Analysis. Paper prepared for the Crisis in Tax Administration Conference, Washington, D.C. Joint Committee on Taxation. 2001. Study of the Overall State of the Federal Tax System and Recommendations for Simplification. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Congress. Olson, Nina. 2002. FY 2002 National Taxpayer Advocate s Annual Report to Congress. Washington, D.C.: Internal Revenue Service. Sawhill, Isabel, and Adam Thomas. 2001. A Tax Proposal for Working Families with Children (Welfare Reform and Beyond Policy Brief No. 3). Washington, D.C.: Brookings. Sawicky, Max B., Robert Cherry, and Robert Denk. 2002. The Next Tax Reform: Advancing Benefits for Children (Economic Policy Institute Technical Paper). Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy Institute. Steuerle, C. Eugene. 2000, 24 April. Combining Child Credits, the EITC, and the Dependent Exemption: First of Two Parts: Is a New Momentum Being Created? Tax Notes Magazine. Washington, D.C.: Tax Analysts. Welfare Reform & Beyond #26 July 2003 7

Recent Welfare Reform & Beyond Policy Briefs Achieving Compromise on Welfare Reform Reauthorization WR&B Brief #25 Ron Haskins and Paul Offner (May 2003) Can Work Experience Programs Work for Welfare Recipients? WR&B Brief #24 Harry J. Holzer (November 2002) Another State Fiscal Crisis: Is There a Better Way? WR&B Brief #23 Alice M. Rivlin (December 2002) The Structure of the TANF Block Grant WR&B Brief #22 R. Kent Weaver (April 2002) 2003. The EICC lowers the highest marginal rates for families in the $20,000 to $35,000 income range from 31 and 36 percent to 29 and 34 percent. Table 3 summarizes the differences in the tax benefits received at three income levels in both 2003 and 2010. The EICC s impact on marriage penalties is mainly positive, although some couples experience tax increases (really, decreases in the amount of tax subsidies they receive from marriage). JGTRRA reduces marriage penalties for all families earning above $17,000. CONCLUSION In revising and combining the EITC and CTC, it is possible to improve: (1) simplicity; (2) work incentives and net income from work at the bottom of the income distribution; and (3) benefits for most families with children. At an additional $6 billion in 2003, the EICC option we describe is more costly than JGTRRA, but unlike JGTRRA it would provide a greater share of benefits to lowincome families and index the value of the credit to inflation so that those gains are locked in over time. It would be possible to reduce the cost of this option for example, by deferred indexing and still improve simplicity, work incentives, and benefits. Ideally, we believe that Congress should push further along the simplification path by considering the looming alternative minimum tax problem, which will affect about 33 million families by 2010. Although a potential crisis, it is also an opportunity. Congress could create an integrated credit that, in addition to the EITC and CTC, incorporates the dependent exemption and does away with the head of household rate schedule. However, such an option does not seem feasible in the short-run. Editor Elana Mintz Tell us what you think of this Policy Brief. E-mail your comments to yourview@brookings.edu. Production/Layout Mary Techau Vice President of Communications Stephen G. Smith The Brookings Office of Communications 202/797-6105 communications@brookings.edu The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave., N.W. Washington, D.C. 20036 NONPROFIT ORG. U.S. POSTAGE PAID FREDERICK, MD PERMIT NO. 225 The views expressed in this Policy Brief are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the trustees, officers, or other staff members of the Brookings Institution. Copyright 2003 The Brookings Institution