Robert Kollmann ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Université Paris-Est and CEPR Frédéric Malherbe London Business School.

Similar documents
Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 55

Introduction: macroeconomic implications of capital flows in a global economy

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 52

Review of. Financial Crises, Liquidity, and the International Monetary System by Jean Tirole. Published by Princeton University Press in 2002

Business cycle fluctuations Part II

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 74

Government Guarantees and the Two-way Feedback between Banking and Sovereign Debt Crises

Issues in Too Big to Fail

International Transmission, and international financial. Michael B. Devereux UBC James Yetman BIS

The Financial System: Opportunities and Dangers

Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria

Lessons from the Subprime Crisis

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?

Banking Crises and Real Activity: Identifying the Linkages

Liquidity and Solvency Risks

Financial Institutions, Markets and Regulation: A Survey

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

Discussant remarks: monetary policy and exchange rate issues in Asia and the Pacific

L-3: BALANCE OF PAYMENT CRISES IRINA BUNDA MACROECONOMIC POLICIES IN TIMES OF HIGH CAPITAL MOBILITY VIENNA, MARCH 21 25, 2016

Expectations vs. Fundamentals-based Bank Runs: When should bailouts be permitted?

Preview PP542. International Capital Markets. Gains from Trade. International Capital Markets. The Three Types of International Transaction Trade

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Stern School of Business. Corporate Finance and Financial Crises B Franklin Allen Spring Semester 2002

A.1. Verifying that the period-by-period household budget constraint (12) is satis ed and that the current account is zero, to rst order

Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler

Empirical research, considers 20 countries with fixed exchange rate, crawling peg or floating within a band.

COMPARING FINANCIAL SYSTEMS. Lesson 23 Financial Crises

Enrique Martínez-García. University of Texas at Austin and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse

Rollover Crisis in DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano Northwestern University

Should Financial Institutions Mark to Market? * Franklin Allen. University of Pennsylvania. and.

Some Parallels Between Currency and Banking Crises: A Comment

SOURCES OF INSTABILITY IN FINANCIAL SYSTEMS

ECS 3701 Monetary Economics

Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Macroeconomics IV (14.454)

Global Games and Financial Fragility:

Chapter 2 Theoretical Views on Money Creation and Credit Rationing

Financial Crises and Asset Prices. Tyler Muir June 2017, MFM

International Finance and Macroeconomics (Econ 422)

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Macro-Financial Linkages: Issues and Challenges

Macroprudential Policies and the Lucas Critique 1

The Federal Reserve in the 21st Century Financial Stability Policies

Bubbles, Liquidity and the Macroeconomy

Bank Instability and Contagion

Currency Crises: Theory and Evidence

CAPITAL FLOWS: EMERGING ISSUES Guillermo A. Calvo University of Maryland Bogota, October 1, 1997

Why are Banks Highly Interconnected?

Topic 8: Financial Frictions and Shocks Part1: Asset holding developments

Foreign Currency Debt, Financial Crises and Economic Growth : A Long-Run Exploration

Developing Countries Chapter 22

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

the Federal Reserve to carry out exceptional policies for over seven year in order to alleviate its effects.

Financial Frictions in Macroeconomics. Lawrence J. Christiano Northwestern University

Credit Market Competition and Liquidity Crises

BALANCE SHEET CONTAGION AND THE TRANSMISSION OF RISK IN THE EURO AREA FINANCIAL SYSTEM

Discussion by J.C.Rochet (SFI,UZH and TSE) Prepared for the Swissquote Conference 2012 on Liquidity and Systemic Risk

Financial Risk and Network Analysis

What Governance for the Eurozone? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Economic Dynamics and Integration in Eastern Europe and Asia Lecture Winter semester 2017/18

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

Economic Theory and Lender of Last Resort Policy

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

Shadow Banking and Financial Stability

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 22 FINANCIAL MARKETS AND MONETARY POLICY April 12, 2018

The main lessons to be drawn from the European financial crisis

Macro-Insurance. How can emerging markets be aided in responding to shocks as smoothly as Australia does?

WP/16/180. Market Frictions, Interbank Linkages and Excessive Interconnections. by Pragyan Deb

Financial Regulation, Banking Integration, and Business Cycle Synchronization

Financial Fragilities in Developing Countries

M. R. Grasselli. February, McMaster University. ABM and banking networks. Lecture 3: Some motivating economics models. M. R.

Global Business Cycles

What do new forms of finance mean for EM central banks?

Commentary: Housing is the Business Cycle

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a, Fall 2009 Yale University. Syllabus

Economics 435 The Financial System (10/28/2015) Instructor: Prof. Menzie Chinn UW Madison Fall 2015

Monetary and Financial Macroeconomics

Banking, Liquidity Transformation, and Bank Runs

Discussion of Confidence Cycles and Liquidity Hoarding by Volha Audzei (2016)

The Federal Reserve in the 21st Century Financial Stability Policies

Regulatory Arbitrage and Systemic Liquidity Crises

14. What Use Can Be Made of the Specific FSIs?

The banking crisis with interbank market freeze

Design Failures in the Eurozone. Can they be fixed? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Review of Understanding Global Crises Author: Assaf Razin

Insights on the Greek economy from the 3D macro model

Managing the Fragility of the Eurozone. Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Orthodox vs. Minskyan Perspectives of Financial Crises Jesús Muñoz

The Monetary and Financial Sector

ECON 5058 W - Advanced Topics in Financial Economics Financial Crises and Stability

The Common Lender Effect : Are Banking Centers Crisis Carriers?

The global economic landscape has

José Darío Uribe E. Governor central bank of colombia October 13, 2011

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES REVIEW OF THEORIES OF FINANCIAL CRISES. Itay Goldstein Assaf Razin. Working Paper

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

Answers to Questions: Chapter 5

Transcription:

Theoretical Perspectives on Financial Globalization: Financial Contagion Chapter 287 of the Encyclopedia of Financial Globalization (Elsevier), Jerry Caprio (ed.) Section Editors: Philippe Bacchetta and Philip Lane Robert Kollmann ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Université Paris-Est and CEPR Frédéric Malherbe London Business School December 30, 2010 Author contact information: R. Kollmann ECARES, CP 114, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 50 Av. F. Roosevelt, B-1050 Brussels, Belgium robert_kollmann@yahoo.com F. Malherbe Department of Economics, London Business School Regent's Park, London NW1 4SA, United Kingdom; fmalherbe@london.edu Table of contents 1. Introduction 2. The international financial multiplier 3. Financial contagion through interbank linkages 4. Bank runs and self-fulfilling international financial crises. Key words: global financial crisis, international financial contagion, international financial multiplier, global banks, bank balance sheets, capital ratio, leverage ratio, international interbank market, asset prices, credit losses, bank runs Glossary: Financial contagion: the strong and rapid spread of a financial crisis across markets, sectors, or countries. International financial multiplier: mechanism by which a fall in asset values in one country triggers a global asset sell-off, due to balance sheets adjustments by global banks. Global bank: bank that holds domestic and foreign assets, and borrows from domestic and foreign residents. Bank capital requirement: requirement that banks have to fund at least a specified fraction of their assets using bank capital (own funds). 1

1. Introduction During the recent (2007-2009) financial crisis, GDP growth and stock markets collapsed simultaneously in most countries around the globe. Yet, the crisis was triggered by a financial shock in the US, namely an unanticipated fall in US house prices that led to massive mortgage loan defaults by US households, and thus impaired the health of US and foreign banks that had invested in the US mortgage market. Earlier episodes of financial contagion included the 1997-1998 crises, during which financial troubles that originated in Asia and Russia rapidly spread to other Emerging Market economies. The 1997-1998 crises spawned a sizable empirical and theoretical literature on mechanisms by which a financial crisis is strongly and rapidly transmitted across countries. That literature highlights that contagion may occur through a variety of channels (trade linkages, credit flows, changes in investor sentiment etc.). It points out that financial frictions are needed for financial strains to disrupt real activity. For in the theoretical world of frictionless financial markets, the financial side of the economy is a veil only, and risks are hedged efficiently. Hence, a shock to any individual may be transmitted to all others, but there is nothing wrong with this. But with financial frictions, risk sharing is incomplete, and financial shocks spill over to real activity. This chapter discusses recent theories of financial contagion in which balance sheets of global banks (and other financial institutions) are the key channel of international transmission. This is motivated by the fact that the 2007-2009 crisis in the US mortgage market was transmitted to the rest of the world through cross-country banking linkages. By contrast to earlier contagion episodes, linkages due to international goods trade were of secondary importance in the global spread of the 2007-2009 crisis (countries with close trade links with the US did not suffer more than countries with weaker trade links to the US). Empirically, the bulk of bank assets is financed by short-term debt; banks own funds (bank capital) only account for a small fraction of total assets. Furthermore, bank assets generally have a longer maturity and are less liquid than bank liabilities. This is a source of fragility that magnifies the effect of crises. In a globalized financial system, banks hold domestic and foreign securities (stocks, bonds), and they lend to domestic and foreign households and firms; banks in different countries also lend to each other. An adverse macroeconomic or financial shock in one country that lowers the capital of global banks may thus trigger a global asset sell-off and a global decrease in bank lending (credit crunch), provoking a global recession. These channels of contagion are further explained below. Section 2 discusses international contagion due to portfolio adjustments of global banks, in response to an asset price shock in one country. Section 3 considers the role of the interbank linkage for international contagion. Section 4 discusses bank runs and self-fulfilling international financial crises. 2. Bank balance sheet adjustments as a channel of contagion: the international financial multiplier Financial intermediaries, henceforth referred to as banks, make loans and invest in securities and other assets (e.g., real estate). They fund their asset holdings by taking deposits and issuing other forms of debt (mostly short-term), and using the bank s own funds (bank capital): Assets = Debt + Capital. A key constraint on bank activities is that 2

banks have to back at least a fraction of their assets by bank capital: Capital/Assets k, for some coefficient 0<k<1. Hence, only a maximum fraction 1-k of bank asset holdings can be funded by debt. A constraint of this type is known as a bank capital requirement. It can reflect a regulatory (legal) requirement, or market pressures. Bank capital requirements protect the interests of bank creditors. For bank capital is a buffer against a fall in the value of bank assets, and thus lowers the risk of insolvency. Also capital requirements help to limit moral hazard by bankers. A simple story is that bankers can walk away with a fraction k of bank assets without prosecution (and start a new life next period). Banks will then only be able to borrow if bank capital does not fall below a fraction k of assets. The ratio of a bank s capital to her assets is called the capital ratio ; the inverse of the capital ratio is the leverage ratio. If the expected return on bank assets exceeds the interest rate on bank debt, then banks have an incentive to borrow the maximum amount, and thus the capital ratio will stay close to the required capital ratio k. Empirically, the capital ratios of the major European banks and of major US investment banks have typically ranged between 3% and 5% in the period 1995-2010, while the capital ratios of US commercial banks have generally been in the range of 7%-8%. As shown below, low capital ratios imply that asset price changes may trigger sizable adjustments of banks asset holdings and debt positions. When banks are globally active, then local (country-specific) shocks can hence induce sharp and synchronized world-wide asset price changes. Those asset price movements can feed into real activity, and thus induce global booms and recessions. In an influential 2008 paper, Paul Krugman refers to this mechanism as the international financial multiplier. This mechanism has become more and more powerful in recent decades, as the banking industry has become globalized. For example, external assets and liabilities of US banks (each) represented about 30% of US GDP in 2009; for Germany, France and the UK, external bank assets and liabilities represent more than 100% of domestic GDP. Consider the following numerical example of a world with two countries of equal size, called Home and Foreign (the countries can be viewed as the European Union and the US, respectively). There is a (representative) global bank that holds both Home and Foreign assets (loans, stocks, bonds), and takes deposits from Home and Foreign households. The bank wishes to allocate 50% of her total assets to Home (Foreign) assets. Let k=0.05, i.e. the bank has to fund at least 5% of her assets using capital. Assume that, initially, the bank holds Home and Foreign assets both worth 50, that her debt is 95, and her capital 5. The initial balance sheet of the global bank is thus: Assets Liabilities Home: 50 Debt: 95 Foreign: 50 Capital: 5 Consider now what happens when the value of the bank s Home assets drops by 0.5 (i.e. by 1%). This might be due to bad news about the future profits (dividends) of Home firms, which lowers the Home stock price; it could also be due to Home credit losses, i.e. defaults by Home households or firms on loans received from the global bank. As a result of this shock, the bank s capital drops to 4.5, i.e. the bank s new balance sheet becomes: 3

Assets Liabilities Home: 49.5 Debt: 95 Foreign: 50 Capital: 4.5 Note that Bank capital falls by a much larger percentage (-10%) than the fall in total assets (-0.5%). The bank s capital ratio is now 4.5/99.5=4.52%, which is smaller than the target ratio (5%). Unless the bank s shareholders provide new capital to the bank, the bank has to reduce her debt and her total assets by 9.5, i.e. total assets and debt have to fall to 90 and 85.5, respectively--as then the capital ratio is again 5%. Assuming that the bank continues to allocate 50% of her total assets to Home assets, the adjusted balance sheet is: Assets Liabilities Home: 45 Debt: 85.5 Foreign: 45 Capital: 4.5 Thus, the initial 1% fall in the value of Home assets has triggered a much bigger simultaneous reduction of the bank s Home and Foreign asset holdings and of her debt (-10%, relative to the initial balance sheet). The sale of Home and Foreign assets by the global bank is likely to lead to a (further) fall in Home and Foreign asset prices, which then can lead to an additional round of Home and Foreign asset sales etc. This is likely to reduce Home and Foreign real activity. The spill over into the real economy may be due to the fact that the asset sell-off makes it harder for firms to fund physical investment projects and to obtain working capital; it also limits the supply of consumption and mortgage loans to households. Investment and consumption will fall thus, which lowers output. A general equilibrium model is needed for a rigorous analysis of these feedback effects (see below). 1 An equivalent vicious circle of global asset sales and falling asset prices can also be triggered by an adverse shock that induces depositors (or other bank creditors) in one country to withdraw their funds from the global bank. Of course, a similar powerful effect also operates when asset values rise. In our numerical example, an initial 1% rise in the value of Home assets will, on impact, raise the bank s capital to 5.5, and her capital ratio to 5.47%. In order to again reach a 5% capital ratio, the bank then has to increase her holdings of Home and Foreign assets and her debt by 10% (compared to the initial situation). Much recent research has been devoted to building quantitative dynamic general equilibrium models with the mechanisms that were just described. Devereux and Yetman (2011) present a model of a two-country world with cross-country trade in equity (claims to physical capital), and in one-period bonds. Within each country there are patient households who save, and impatient households who invest. Investors (who resemble banks) hold domestic and foreign equity, and they face a capital requirement (i.e. maximum debt depends on investor net worth). When the capital requirement does not 1 A general equilibrium set-up is also required for an account of who buys the assets sold by banks. The buyers are likely to be less productive at managing those assets, which too contributes to the drop in aggregate output. 4

bind, then the international transmission of macroeconomics shocks is very limited. By contrast, with binding capital requirements, balance sheet linkages across banks generate a powerful mechanism for the international transmission of shocks. Kollmann et al. (2010) model the international transmission of defaults on bank loans. A two-country world is considered, in which global banks collect deposits from households, and lend to entrepreneurs, in both countries. An unanticipated loan default in one country brings about a wealth transfer from banks to entrepreneurs; hence bank capital falls, which impairs the bank s ability to channel funds from savers to borrowers. The deposit rate falls while the loan rate rises, in both countries, thus lowering lending, investment and output in both countries. The important insight is that a credit loss (default) in one country triggers an immediate and identical fall in both domestic and foreign output. 3. Financial contagion through interbank linkages The recent financial crisis has revealed that interbank borrowing and lending is a key channel of international contagion. Because depositors have a preference for liquidity, deposits are generally available on demand (demand deposits). But most bank loans have a longer maturity (mortgage loans for instance). The reason why banks can engage in such a maturity transformation is that normally not all depositors withdraw their funds at the same time (one may think that, on average, withdrawals are compensated by new deposits). Still, banks must be able to cope with unexpected large withdrawals. For this reason, banks hold a fraction of their assets in cash or other liquid assets (i.e. in assets that can easily and rapidly be turned into cash). When choosing her holdings of liquid reserves, a bank faces the following trade-off: on the one hand, any Euro held in reserves earns the bank less interest than loans; on the other hand, if the bank does not hold enough reserves to face unexpected high withdrawals, it will have to sell less liquid assets on short notice, often at fire sale prices. Banks may respond to this uncertainty by holding demand deposits in other banks. Such cross-holdings of deposits allow banks to re-allocate cash among themselves, according to their respective liquidity needs. That mechanism improves the efficiency of the banking system: for a given total liquid assets held by the banking system, each bank will be able to cope with larger idiosyncratic deposit withdrawals. Banks thus need lower total reserves to hedge against a given amount of withdrawal risk by households. Hence, they can issue more loans, which raises real activity. This logic holds for banks within a country, but also across banks in different countries, as deposit withdrawals are likely to be imperfectly correlated across countries. Imagine, for example, that there is a natural disaster in one country and that its residents draw on their deposits at the local banks to fund unanticipated spending. This is likely to be independent of deposit withdrawals by households in other countries. Banks in the country in which the disaster occurs can more easily meet deposit withdrawals if they hold deposits in foreign banks. International cross-holdings of deposit thus facilitate international risk sharing, but they also imply that an unexpected withdrawal in one country may impact on real activity in other countries. For instance, a bank could be forced to cut its lending in order to fulfill its obligations towards her foreign counterparts. Also, for the reasons explained above, banks may end up holding less total liquid assets when there is risk-sharing via interbank linkages. This implies that a system of global interbank linkages is more resistant to a local increase in withdrawals, but that it may be 5

less able to resist infrequent global shocks. Global crises might hence be magnified by cross-country interbank linkages. In this respect, the precise structure of the interbank linkages is crucial. A network in which all banks are directly linked to each other is most resilient. If setting up such a network is too costly, then it is preferable to have a series of smaller networks, rather than a chain that indirectly connects all banks. The intuition for this is that, in a chain, if a bank faces a negative shock, it might force the next bank in the chain to liquidate assets at fire-sale values; this, in turn, can trigger fire-sales by another bank, and so on and so forth; hence, a smaller initial shock suffices to bring about the collapse of the entire system (than in a complete network ). The notion of balance sheet contagion has several other applications that are explored in the next section. 4. Bank-runs and self-fulfilling international crises The maturity mismatch of bank balance sheets exposes banks to the risk of bank-runs, which can lead to self-fulfilling international financial crises. As explained above, banks are able to borrow short-term and lend long-term because, in normal times, not all deposits are withdrawn at the same time. A run occurs when depositors panic and try to withdraw their money simultaneously. Imagine you are a depositor, and that you do not need your money now, and thus have no fundamental reason to withdraw. However, you know that if all depositors demand their money back at the same time, then the bank will be in trouble: it will have to sell its assets at fire-sale price, which might imply that the bank would fail. Whether you should withdraw depends thus on your expectations about the behavior of other depositors. This can lead to two possible outcomes. A no-bank-run equilibrium: expecting that no-one will withdraw, you are better-off not withdrawing; this is true also for others depositors; hence, no-one withdraws. There is also a bank-run equilibrium: expecting others to run, you are better-off running as well--if you wait, the bank will deplete her assets, and fail, before you show up; this is of course true for other depositors too, and a bank run can thus become a self-fulfilling prophecy. This simple story applies too to emerging market countries. Note that these countries usually borrow short-term to finance longer term projects. They hence face the risk of a run. A run on a country is usually called a sudden-stop (of capital inflows). The basic story can also be enriched to study the cross-country contagion of self-fulfilling crisis. Consider for instance two countries, each with a bank, and imagine that all depositors decide to run in the first country. If depositors in the other country believe that this will lead to a run in their country too, there will be a run. However, if depositors think the opposite, there will be no run. Note that this is the case even if the two countries are autarkic. This purely self-fulfilling equilibrium is therefore consistent with both international contagion and the absence of contagion. In reality, though, bank runs (or sudden-stops) usually follow the disclosure of some unfavorable news about economic fundamentals. Formal models of runs show that there is generally a threshold for the liquid reserves of the bank (or the economy) below which a run can occur. The bank run threshold theory is useful for thinking about contagion because, when the same investors lend to banks in different countries, then a run in one country can affect the likelihood of a bank run in other countries. Assume for instance that there is a run in the first country, 6

and that investors loose a substantial amount of money. Then, they might be more concerned about facing the risk of a run in the second one, and as a result a run in the second country becomes more likely. This can, for instance, happen when investors have decreasing absolute risk aversion, which implies that losses make them more risk averse. This story applies also to speculative attacks on an exchange rate peg. Imagine that speculators successfully attack the peg of a first country and thereby make sizable profits. Then they will be more eager to attack the currency peg of another country. Note that this mechanism also works the other way around: a failed attack decreases the probability of a successful attack on another currency peg. Further Reading Adrian, T. and Shin, H.S. (2008). Liquidity and financial contagion. Banque de France Stability Review 11, 1-7 Allen, F. and Gale, D. (2001). Financial contagion. Journal of Political Economy 108, 1 33. Bacchetta, P. and van Wincoop, E. (2010). Explaining sudden spikes in global risk, Working Paper, University of Lausanne. Bacchetta, P., Tille, C. and van Wincoop, E. (2010). On the Dynamics of Leverage, Liquidity, and Risk, Working Paper, University of Lausanne. Cetorelli, N. and Goldberg, L. S. (2010). Global banks and international shock transmission: Evidence from the crisis. Working Paper 15974, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge (MA), USA, www.nber.org Castiglionesi, F., Feriozzi, F. and Lorenzoni, G. (2010). Financial Integration and Liquidity Crises. Mimeo. Claessens, S. and Forbes, K. (eds.) (2001). International financial contagion. Boston, Dordrecht and London: Kluwer Academic. Dedola, L. and Lombardo, G. (2010). Financial frictions, financial integration and the international propagation of shocks. Working Paper, European Central Bank. Devereux, M. B. and Yetman, J. (2010). Leverage constraints and the international transmission of shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42: 71-105. Diamond, D. and Dybvig, P. (183). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91, 401 419. Dornbusch, P., Park, Y. and Claessens, S. (2000). Contagion: understanding how it spreads. The World Bank Research Observer 15, 177-97. Goldstein, I, and Pauzner, A. (2004). Contagion of self-fulfilling financial crises due to diversification of investment portfolios. Journal of Economic Theory 119, 151 183. Kaminsky, G., Reinhart, C. and Vegh, C. (2003). The unholy trinity of financial contagion. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17, 51 74. Kollmann, R., Enders, Z. and Müller, G. (2010). Global banking and international business cycles. Discussion Paper 7972, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London, UK, www.cepr.org Krugman, Paul, 2008, The international finance multiplier. Working Paper, Princeton University. Malherbe, F. (2010). Self-fulfilling liquidity dry-ups. National Bank of Belgium, Research series. 7

Relevant Websites: International Monetary Fund http://www.imf.org http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/ (IMF Global Financial Stability Report) Bank for International Settlements http://www.bis.org http://www.bis.org/cgfs/index.htm (BIS Committee on the Global Financial System) European Central Bank http://www.ecb.int Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System http://www.federalreserve.gov/ 8