The Future of EMU and the Netherlands' place in Europe

Similar documents
Klaas Knot: The future of EMU and the Netherlands place in Europe

The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for

II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits

A Two-Handed Economist s Presentation on The Treaty. Professor Karl Whelan University College Dublin Presentation for Labour Party April 28, 2012

Fund Management Diary

Check against delivery.

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT

A European Unemployment Insurance Scheme? An Interview with Sebastian Dullien

The Outlook for the European and the German Economy

ECFIN/C-1 Fourth quarter 2000

Greece and the euro area adjustment programmes Speech Hellenic Bank Association Klaus Regling, Managing Director ESM Athens, 12 June 2018

Peter Praet: The role of the central bank and euro area governments in times of crisis

Discussion of Marcel Fratzscher s book Die Deutschland-Illusion

Macro Focus. From austerity to growth? 30 May Group Economics Macro Research

Spring Forecast: slowly recovering from a protracted recession

International Environment Economics for Business (IEEB)

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Slovakia. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty

Implications of the European financial crisis for fiscal policy and public financing of the health and social sectors

What Governance for the Eurozone? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Irish Economy and Growth Legal Framework for Growth and Jobs High Level Workshop, Sofia

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN PROPERTY YIELDS AND INTEREST RATES: SOME THOUGHTS. BNP Paribas REIM. June Real Estate for a changing world

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOUNDATION IKV BRIEF 2010 THE DEBT CRISIS IN GREECE AND THE EURO ZONE

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

Can the euro still be saved? Morning session: the threats

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

FINANCIAL STABILITY SOVEREIGN DEBT ECONOMIC GROWTH

The future of the euro zone

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Winter edition December 2012

How to avoid a double-dip recession in the eurozone

For the Eurozone, much hinges on self-discipline and self-interest

Crisis and cooperative solutions: the euro area since 2008

Budgetary challenges posed by ageing populations:

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA

1. Sustainable public finances and structural reforms for growth

11244/12 RD/NC/kp DG G1A

Fiscal Federalism - some thoughts

The outlook for the global economy in 2012

7569/18 DA/NT/fh DGG 1A

1.1. Low yield environment

Ranking Country Page. Category 1: Countries with positive CEP Default Index and positive NTE. 1 Estonia 1. 2 Luxembourg 2.

Recovery in Europe The outcome of successful crisis policies?

Design Failures in the Eurozone. Can they be fixed? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Transcript of interview with ESM Managing Director Klaus Regling. The interview was conducted by Tomoko Hatakeyama in Tokyo on 26 January 2016

Mario Draghi: Introductory remarks at the French Assemblée Nationale

Eurozone crisis and its impact on Ukraine

Kristina Budimir 1 Debt Crisis in the EU Member States and Fiscal Rules

Nicolaie Alexandru-Chidesciuc, CFA, PhD

Monetary Integration

Eurozone crisis and its impact on Belarus

EUROPEAN SOVEREIGN DEBT MARKETS

A Fiscal Union in Europe: why is it possible/impossible?

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION 2014 DRAFT BUDGETARY PLANS OF THE EURO AREA: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE BUDGETARY SITUATION AND PROSPECTS

Ways out of the crisis

OECD III: EMU. Gavin Cameron Lady Margaret Hall. Michaelmas Term 2004

Does the South of Europe have a competitiveness problem?

CRISIS MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE EUROZONE. Paul De Grauwe (LSE) Yuemei Ji (Brunel University)

JANUARY 2012 THE BEST AND WORST OF TIMES

1. IMF Article IV interim mission to the euro area. Eurogroup The President. Brussels, 13 December To the members of the Eurogroup

Erkki Liikanen: Reforming the structure of the EU banking sector

ECB LTRO Dec Greece program

European Public Debt: A Solution to Fragility

Key Features of the Flexible Protection Plan

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

STABILITY PROGRAMME:

Economic Reform in Uganda: Lessons for Africa 3 December Prof. E. Tumusiime-Mutebile, Governor

Regling: Greece has to repay that loan in full. That is our expectation, nothing has changed in that regard.

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2015

Divergence and Adjustment in the Euro Area

The European Social Model and the Greek Economy

Managing the Fragility of the Eurozone. Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Denmark. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty

Europe in crisis. George Gelauff. ECU 92 Lustrum Conference Utrecht. 23 February 2012

DYNAMICS OF BUDGETARY REVENUE IN THE CONDITIONS OF ROMANIAN INTEGRATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION - A CONSEQUENTLY OF THE TAX AND HARMONIZATION POLICY

Recent developments and challenges for the Portuguese economy

Why ESBies won t solve the euro area s problems

Modelling the sovereign debt crisis in Europe

Fiscal Policy, Budget Deficits and the Economic Crisis. Lars Calmfors Intermediate macroeconomics Stockholm, 30 March 2010

What is the global economic outlook?

OPENING STATEMENT BY MARIO DRAGHI CANDIDATE FOR PRESIDENT OF THE ECB TO THE ECONOMIC AND MONETARY AFFAIRS COMMITTEE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT

A Dose of Structural Reform for the Stability Pact. Barry Eichengreen May 2, 2003

Policy Reforms after the Crisis

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro area s economic outlook

How Europe is Overcoming the Euro Crisis?

CHALLENGES FOR THE EURO AREA AND IMPLICATIONS FOR LATVIA

The Swiss Franc within an Euro Environment. Address given by. Jean-Pierre Roth Vice-Chairman of the Governing Board Swiss National Bank

DEFICITS AND DEBT Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Interview with Klaus Regling, Managing Director, ESM. Published in Hospodárske noviny (Slovakia) on 16 September Interviewer: Tomáš Púchly

Wage Setting and Price Stability Gustav A. Horn

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast June 2014

Greece and the Euro. Harris Dellas, University of Bern. Abstract

Previsions Macroeconòmiques. Macroeconomic scenario for the Catalan economy 2017 and June 2017

Reviving Growth in Europe

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Insolvency forecasts. Economic Research August 2017

Global Financial Crisis and China s Countermeasures

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast June 2014

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast June 2013

Transcription:

The Future of EMU and the Netherlands' place in Europe Thank you for this opportunity to exchange views with you on this topical issue. Thank you also for arranging for me to do so amid the splendour of this magnificent hall. I feel quite safe standing here, for I understand the Armourers Hall was among the few buildings that escaped destruction in the Great Fire of 1666, and, in 1940, also survived a major blitz on London, while the surrounding area was devastated. So one might say that this venue symbolically suits my subject of today, for I am confident that in the distant future we will be able to say that EMU still survives. Speaking of which, I couldn t help but notice that the title of my talk as announced in the flyer is The Future of European Monetary Union, instead of Economic and Monetary Union which the term EMU stands for. Don t worry, you find yourselves in good company; many European governments are only now starting to realize that they haven t paid enough attention to the E in EMU. My talk today consists of two parts. In the first part, I ll focus on why it is that, for the Netherlands in particular, it is so important that the European project will be successful. In the second part, I'll discuss the implications of the European sovereign debt crisis for the future design of EMU. I will argue that at the root of the crisis we find some individual euro area countries pursuing wrong policies and a failing system of mutual surveillance in the euro area. These deficiencies pose a number of challenges for the future of EMU. While the introduction of the euro has increased macroeconomic stability and furthered trade and financial integration, the sovereign debt crisis clearly demonstrates that the job is not done yet. The alliance of the Netherlands with Europe has always been strong and will remain so in the future, if only because of its small size and geographical location. The same holds true for the other low country, Belgium. By nature, Dutch people have always had a strong focus on Europe. Just to illustrate this point, every pupil in high school has to learn at least two foreign European languages. Foreign residents in the Netherlands even complain that it is hard to learn Dutch in Holland, because everybody they speak to in Dutch replies in English, French or German. Another way to illustrate the Netherlands focus on the outside world is to look at the openness of its economy. If you take a look at Chart 2, you find openness defined as exports plus imports as a percentage of GDP. As you can see, in the US, exports plus imports are less than 30% of GDP. 1

In France, Italy, Spain and the UK, this indicator is between 53 and 63%. In the Netherlands, exports plus imports are nearly 150% of GDP, and in Belgium and Ireland even more. As a consequence of this openness, the realization of the single market and the introduction of the euro later on did have a substantial positive impact on the Dutch economy. After all, one of the most significant yields was the boost that EMU provided to trade. Driven by lower transaction cost, lower exchange rate risks and more market transparency, trade within the euro area developed more strongly than outside the euro area. Being a country of trade and distribution by tradition, the Netherlands has taken advantage of these circumstances. For sure, it is one of the reasons why the Dutch economy outperformed the euro area in terms of GDP growth in 14 out of the last 20 years. The strong alliance of the Dutch economy with Europe in general and the euro area in particular also shows up if we look at its exports orientation. In Chart 3 you see this defined as exports to the euro area expressed as a percentage of total exports. It follows that the orientation on the euro area is the largest in the Netherlands. More than 60% of our exports goes to euro area countries. Given its close ties with the euro area, it is obvious that for the Dutch economy a solution of the European sovereign debt crisis is of vital importance. If EMU were to fall apart, the consequences for the open Dutch trading nation would be severe. Therefore, Dutch policymakers and central bankers should do their utmost to solve this crisis. In what follows, I will first focus on the causes of the sovereign debt crisis. Finally, I will present my views on the implications for a stable design of EMU. Over the last couple of months, European policy makers have done a lot to restore confidence. As a consequence, most stressed sovereign debt markets have calmed down substantially (left-hand side of the graph). The most important development was the announcement and finalisation of the Fiscal Compact, in which the political leaders of the euro area countries (and most other EU countries) further strengthened the rules governing budgetary discipline in Europe. Furthermore, in March the capacity of the EFSF/ESM will be evaluated. We have to conclude that the EFSF in its current form (based on guarantees) and size unfortunately has failed to convince markets that all countries will get through this crisis unharmed. This is why we as central bankers call upon the European governments to increase the emergency facility as soon as possible. 2

The ECB also took further measures to avoid the sovereign debt crisis from severely dragging down the real economy. It did so by introducing a refinancing operation with a maturity of three years. As Chart 4 shows, this operation attracted a lot of interest, with a total volume of EUR 490 billion (right-hand side of the graph). This is not all new liquidity by the way, since banks also rolled over operations with shorter maturities into this new facility. This provides them with the liquidity security they need in light of the market tensions and, thus, helps prevent a sharp reduction in credit supply to the economy. At the end of this month, a second three-year operation will be carried out. In analysing and solving the sovereign debt crisis, the focus was on fiscal and monetary factors rather than on the macroeconomic causes of the crisis. However, as I ll briefly demonstrate by means of Charts 5, 6 and 7, these causes are at least as important as the fiscal slippages some countries allowed themselves. At the start of EMU, per capita income levels between countries differed significantly. It was assumed that catching-up countries would experience faster economic growth. This is what did happen, but not quite to the extent expected. Prior to the crisis, mainly Ireland, and to a lesser extent also Greece and Spain, showed signs of real convergence. Their cumulative growth differentials compared to Germany reached 20 to 45% in 2007. Note that Italy and Portugal hardly experienced any real convergence towards the German welfare level, even before to the crisis. Even the Netherlands converged more than these countries. Unfortunately, the catching-up process largely took place through debt, either public or private. As Chart 6 shows, in some countries credit to the private sector grew by more than 10% a year for over a decade. As a result, their debt with the rest of the world ran up tremendously. This was most dramatically the case in Ireland, which moved from a net creditor position of 52% of GDP in 1999 to a net debtor position of 71% of GDP in 2008. Note that the Netherlands is not doing particularly well with regard to this measure either. This is mainly the result of the growth in mortgage loans. In my view the high stock of mortgage debt is among today s biggest vulnerabilities of the Dutch economy. Besides being largely based on credit, real convergence was accompanied by high inflation, as you find visualised on Chart 7. 3

Whereas Germany experienced lower inflation compared to the euro area average, the inflation rates in Greece, Ireland, Spain and Portugal were much higher than the EMU average. This substantial deterioration of competitiveness mainly reflects the development of unit labour costs. The economic developments in Germany in the last decade have been phenomenal. The time that Germany was called the sick man of Europe is not so far way. Partly due to the supply of many low-paid workers from East Germany, the labour market institutions in Germany were no longer sustainable. This has led to the so-called Harz reforms, which made the German labour market more flexible and tempered unit labour costs and inflation. Before EMU, the current euro area countries followed different economic strategies. Between 1970 and 1999, unit labour costs in Germany, the Netherlands en Austria grew by a factor of 2.5 to 3. During these 28 years prior to EMU, unit labour costs grew by a factor of 12 in Italy, 14 in Spain, 35 in Portugal and 55 in Greece. By regularly devaluing their currencies, these countries were able to restore competitiveness. But after the launch of EMU, this policy option was no longer available, of course. The hope was that these countries would adapt to this new reality and unit labour costs growth would slow down. But has this happened? Chart 8 shows the cumulative growth of unit labour costs relative to the euro area average from the start of EMU. While countries like Germany, Austria and Finland continued their modest wage policies, unit labour costs in Southern European countries went up at a much higher pace, undermining their competitiveness. This proved unsustainable. The countries that found themselves in the top of the chart when the sovereign debt tensions started in 2009 that is Greece, Spain, Ireland, Portugal and Italy all ran into trouble one after the other. This is no coincidence. Currently, adjustments are hard-handedly being enforced by the markets. In the said countries, Ireland excepted, product and labour markets didn t function properly and they still don t. Markets are overregulated and labour markets are highly inflexible. By addressing these problems, labour productivity can increase, thereby lowering unit labour costs. I am not saying this will be easy, but I m convinced that such steps are absolutely necessary for EMU to function properly. 4

As the chart also shows, in the Netherlands unit labour cost growth was also relatively high during the first years of EMU. This, however, wasn't caused by the high inflation rates and low flexibility of the labour market, but reflected the low unemployment rate in the Netherlands in that period. For many years, the unemployment rate in the Netherlands was the lowest in the euro area. The divergences in unit labour cost developments and price competitiveness within the euro area are reflected in the current account balances of the individual countries. As you can tell from Chart 9, before the crisis, most southern European countries and, to a lesser extent, Ireland experienced high and steadily increasing current account deficits, while the current account surpluses of Germany and the Netherlands improved further. For many years it was thought that in a monetary union, the current account balances of individual countries were no longer relevant. It was only the balance of payment of the euro area as a whole that mattered. We know better now. Of course, besides competitiveness problems, the crisis also had fiscal causes. As can be told from Chart 10, the stability and growth pact didn t prevent some governments from taking up old habits once they had fulfilled the convergence criteria that enabled them to join EMU. We shouldn t forget, however, that this was facilitated by some of the core countries of EMU. When it became clear that fiscal policies in these countries wouldn t be able to meet the rules of the Stability and Growth Pact, it was not the policies that were changed but the Pact. This was clearly a mistake. Besides, the gradual worsening of the budget balance in countries like Italy and Portugal was partly due to their competitiveness problems. Since devaluing out of these problems was no longer an option, the declined competitiveness slowed down economic and employment growth. This dampened tax revenues while stimulating social security expenditures. Looking at it this way, the lack of fiscal discipline partly reflected the lack of macroeconomic discipline. More in general, budgetary policy was supposed to absorb temporary cyclical differences, by allowing the automatic stabilisers to do their work. For example, during a downturn, public spending automatically goes up as more people receive unemployment benefits, while tax revenues decrease. Such automatic response to cyclical developments stabilises the economy. 5

But in most member states, the automatic stabilisers have failed to operate properly since 1999. Instead, a number of governments followed pro-cyclical budgetary policies, by loosening the budgetary reins during the economic booms, and tightening them during the busts. In other words, budgetary policies have hampered the functioning of EMU. Budgetary discipline in EMU was supposed to be exacted not only by the stability and growth pact, but also by market discipline. Markets were expected to restrain profligate governments by charging them higher interest rates and, thus, forcing them to change their ways. As is evident from Chart 11, market discipline was largely absent during the first ten years of EMU, allowing governments to pursue unsustainable policies. And when markets finally started to differentiate between governments, they did so with a vengeance. Although market discipline is now imposing necessary corrections, a stable monetary union cannot be based on this mechanism. So what would a stable monetary union look like in my view? As I argued earlier, some euro area countries have not fully adapted to the fact that they lost the option of devaluation in order to restore competitiveness. If they had, they would have increased their flexibility and growth potential by reforming their labour and product markets. Given the spillover effects of postponed structural reforms on the functioning of EMU, these reforms cannot be the sole responsibility of the governments concerned, but should also have a European dimension. This can take different forms. One way could be to strengthen the macroeconomic imbalances procedure, by increasing its focus and enforceability. This could be done, for instance, by introducing more reversed Qualitative Majority Voting in these areas. Another way would be to introduce minimum standards or best practices in policy areas where spillovers have turned out to be especially high, such as labour market policies. Importantly, what should be avoided is harmonisation towards some kind of EMU average, as this would force strong countries to reduce their competitiveness. Secondly, debt ratios should gradually be brought well below the ceiling of 60%. This lower debt ratio can only be realised and maintained through independent enforcement of the European fiscal rules and by anchoring these rules in national legislation. A politically independent European authority 6

that can increasingly intervene in the fiscal policy of countries breaking the agreements is essential here. If and only if these conditions have been met, eurobonds could be a serious option. Eurobonds could enhance the stability of EMU in several ways. They would prevent a liquidity problem in one euro area country from needlessly transforming into a solvency problem. Moreover, they could provide a fire wall against the danger of contagion. Although eurobonds are not suitable as a crisis instrument, they could be the light at the end of the tunnel for the people of vulnerable euro area countries. For the people in those countries need to feel that their sacrifices will contribute to a permanent solution; one that will safeguard them from the short-sightedness of both politicians and markets. As I said at the beginning of my presentation, it is obvious that for the Dutch economy a solution of the sovereign debt crisis is very important, given its strong connections to the euro area. And therefore, Dutch politicians and central bankers should do their utmost to solve this crisis. But what is it we can offer? In my opinion a lot. Pragmatism, common sense and a focus on problemsolving are crucial now and the Dutch happen to be famous not to say notorious for these characteristics. Although we can be very principled on some issues and in many cases see eye to eye with the Germans, these typically Dutch characteristics could help divided euro area countries to stick together and solve this crisis. Pointing at the long-term perspective of eurobonds once the necessary conditions have been met, is an example of this pragmatism and focus on problem solving. Let me finish this presentation by saying that finding a structural way out of the crisis will not only be beneficial for the Netherlands, but also for the euro area, the rest of Europe, and, yes, even for the world economy. Thank you for your attention. 7