Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Similar documents
ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Chapter 10: Price Competition Learning Objectives Suggested Lecture Outline: Lecture 1: Lecture 2: Suggestions for the Instructor:

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

I. Introduction and definitions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

MICROECONOMICS II. Author: Gergely K hegyi. Supervised by Gergely K hegyi. February 2011

Horizontal Mergers. Chapter 11: Horizontal Mergers 1

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

Chapter 7: Product Differentiation

Strategy -1- Strategy

Economics 335 Problem Set 6 Spring 1998

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Challenge to Hotelling s Principle of Minimum

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Chapter 9. Noncompetitive Markets and Inefficiency. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

Exercise Chapter 10

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

HW Consider the following game:

Model Question Paper Economics - I (MSF1A3)

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

Strategic Pre-Commitment

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

ECON 102 Boyle Final Exam New Material Practice Exam Solutions

Basic Game-Theoretic Concepts. Game in strategic form has following elements. Player set N. (Pure) strategy set for player i, S i.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

HE+ Economics Nash Equilibrium

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

Chapter 17: Vertical and Conglomerate Mergers

Solutions to Homework 3

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Econ 101A Solution to Final Exam F13December.

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

Math 135: Answers to Practice Problems

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Answers to Odd-Numbered Problems, 4th Edition of Games and Information, Rasmusen. PROBLEMS FOR CHAPTER 14: Pricing

pq A q A = (6.01q A.01q C )q A q A = 6q A.01q 2 A.01q C q A q A.

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Economics 171: Final Exam

Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

Antoine Augustine Cournot was a French mathematician who, in 1838, wrote a book entitled Researches

There are 10 questions on this exam. These 10 questions are independent of each other.

Econ 815 Dominant Firm Analysis and Limit Pricing

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Transcription:

Static Games and Cournot Competition Lecture 3: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1

Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors oligopoly market Each firm has to consider rival s actions strategic interaction in prices, outputs, advertising This kind of interaction is analyzed using game theory assumes that players are rational Distinguish cooperative and noncooperative games focus on noncooperative games Also consider timing simultaneous versus sequential games 2

No single theory Oligopoly theory employ game theoretic tools that are appropriate outcome depends upon information available Need a concept of equilibrium players (firms?) choose strategies, one for each player combination of strategies determines outcome outcome determines pay-offs (profits?) Equilibrium first formalized by Nash: No firm wants to change its current strategy given that no other firm changes its current strategy 3

Nash equilibrium Equilibrium need not be nice firms might do better by coordinating but such coordination may not be possible (or legal) Some strategies can be eliminated on occasions they are never good strategies no matter what the rivals do These are dominated strategies they are never employed and so can be eliminated elimination of a dominated strategy may result in another being dominated: it also can be eliminated One strategy might always be chosen no matter what the rivals do: dominant strategy 4

Two airlines An example Prices set: compete in departure times 70% of consumers prefer evening departure, 30% prefer morning departure If the airlines choose the same departure times they share the market equally Pay-offs to the airlines are determined by market shares Represent the pay-offs in a pay-off matrix 5

The left-hand number is the pay-off to Delta The example 2 What is the equilibrium for this The Pay-Off Matrix game? Morning American Evening Delta Morning Evening (15, 15) (30, 70) The right-hand number is the (70, 30) pay-off (35, 35) to American 6

The example 3 If American The Pay-Off Matrix chooses a morning The morning departure The morning departure departure, If Delta is also a dominated is American a dominated will chooses an evening Both airlines strategy for American strategy for Delta American evening departure, Delta choose an will also choose evening Morning Evening evening departure Morning (15, 15) (30, 70) Delta Evening (70, 30) (35, 35) 7

The example 4 Now suppose that Delta has a frequent flier program When both airline choose the same departure times Delta gets 60% of the travelers This changes the pay-off matrix 8

The example 5 The Pay-Off Matrix American has no However, a But if Delta dominated morning departure If Delta strategy chooses American is still a dominated chooses an evening a morning departure, strategy for Delta American departure, American knows American this will and choose will sochoose Morning Evening chooses morning a morning evening departure Morning (18, 12) (30, 70) Delta Evening (70, 30) (42, 28) 9

Nash equilibrium What if there are no dominated or dominant strategies? Then we need to use the Nash equilibrium concept. Change the airline game to a pricing game: 60 potential passengers with a reservation price of $500 120 additional passengers with a reservation price of $220 price discrimination is not possible (perhaps for regulatory reasons or because the airlines don t know the passenger types) costs are $200 per passenger no matter when the plane leaves airlines must choose between a price of $500 and a price of $220 if equal prices are charged the passengers are evenly shared the low-price airline gets all the passengers The pay-off matrix is now: 10

The example If Delta prices high If both price highand The American Pay-Off Matrix low then both get 30 then American gets passengers. If Delta prices Profit lowall 180 passengers. American and per American passenger high isprofit If both per price passenger low then $300 Delta getsthey each is $20 get 90 all 180 passengers. passengers. P H = $500 P L = $220 Profit per passenger Profit per passenger is $20 P H = $500 is ($9000,$9000) $20 ($0, $3600) Delta P L = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) 11

(P H, P H ) is a Nash Nash equilibrium There equilibrium. are two (P Nash H The, P L ) Pay-Off cannot be There Matrixis no simple If both are pricing a Nash equilibrium. (P L, P L ) is a Nash equilibria to this version way to choose between high Custom then neither wants If American prices equilibrium. of and game familiarity these equilibria might to change lead low both then to Delta shouldamerican If both are pricing (P L, P Regret H ) cannot might price highbealso price low low then neither wants a Nash cause equilibrium. both to to change P H = $500 P L = $220 If American price prices low high then Delta should also price Phigh H = $500 ($9000,$9000) $9000) ($0, $3600) Delta P L = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) 12

Oligopoly models There are three dominant oligopoly models Cournot Bertrand Stackelberg They are distinguished by the decision variable that firms choose the timing of the underlying game Concentrate on the Cournot model in this section 13

Start with a duopoly The Cournot model Two firms making an identical product (Cournot supposed this was spring water) Demand for this product is P = A - BQ = A -B(q 1 +q 2 ) where q 1 is output of firm 1 and q 2 is output of firm 2 Marginal cost for each firm is constant at c per unit To get the demand curve for one of the firms we treat the output of the other firm as constant So for firm 2, demand is P = (A - Bq 1 ) - Bq 2 14

The Cournot model 2 P = (A - Bq 1 ) - Bq 2 $ The profit-maximizing choice of output by firm 2 depends upon the output of firm 1 Marginal revenue for firm 2 is Solve this for output A - Bq 1 A - Bq 1 MR 2 = (A - Bq 1 ) - 2Bq 2 MR 2 MR 2 = MC q 2 c q* 2 If the output of firm 1 is increased the demand curve for firm 2 moves to the left Demand MC Quantity A - Bq 1-2Bq 2 = c \ q* 2 = (A - c)/2b - q 1 /2 15

q* 2 = (A - c)/2b - q 1 /2 The Cournot model 3 This is the reaction function for firm 2 It gives firm 2 s profit-maximizing choice of output for any choice of output by firm 1 There is also a reaction function for firm 1 By exactly the same argument it can be written: q* 1 = (A - c)/2b - q 2 /2 Cournot-Nash equilibrium requires that both firms be on their reaction functions. 16

(A-c)/B (A-c)/2B q C 2 q 2 Cournot-Nash equilibrium If firm 2 produces The reaction function The Cournot-Nash (A-c)/B then firm for firm 1 is equilibrium is at 1 will choose to q* 1 = (A-c)/2B - q 2 /2 the intersection produce no output If of firm the reaction 2 produces nothing functions then firmthe reaction function 1 will produce the for firm 2 is C monopoly outputq* 2 = (A-c)/2B - q 1 /2 (A-c)/2B Firm 1 s reaction function q C 1 (A-c)/2B Firm 2 s reaction function (A-c)/B q 1 17

(A-c)/B (A-c)/2B (A-c)/3B q 2 Cournot-Nash equilibrium 2 Firm 1 s reaction function C Firm 2 s reaction function q* 1 = (A - c)/2b - q* 2 /2 q* 2 = (A - c)/2b - q* 1 /2 \ q* 2 = (A - c)/2b - (A - c)/4b + q* 2 /4 \ 3q* 2 /4 = (A - c)/4b \ q* 2 = (A - c)/3b \ q* 1 = (A - c)/3b (A-c)/2B (A-c)/B q 1 (A-c)/3B 18

Cournot-Nash equilibrium 3 In equilibrium each firm produces q C 1 = q C 2 = (A - c)/3b Total output is, therefore, Q* = 2(A - c)/3b Recall that demand is P = A - BQ So the equilibrium price is P* = A - 2(A - c)/3 = (A + 2c)/3 Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c)q C 1 = (A - c) 2 /9B Profit of firm 2 is the same A monopolist would produce Q M = (A - c)/2b Competition between the firms causes them to overproduce. Price is lower than the monopoly price But output is less than the competitive output (A - c)/b where price equals marginal cost 19

Cournot-Nash equilibrium: many firms What if there are more than two firms? Much the same approach. Say that there are N identical firms producing identical products Total output Q = q 1 + q 2 + This + qdenotes N output Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q of every 1 + q firm 2 + other + q N ) than firm 1 Consider firm 1. It s demand curve can be written: P = A - B(q 2 + + q N ) - Bq 1 Use a simplifying notation: Q -1 = q 2 + q 3 + + q N So demand for firm 1 is P = (A - BQ -1 ) - Bq 1 20

The Cournot model: many firms 2 P = (A - BQ -1 ) - Bq 1 $ The profit-maximizing choice of output by firm 1 depends upon the output of the other firms Marginal revenue for firm 1 is Solve this for output MR 1 = (A - BQ -1 ) - 2Bq 1 MR 1 = MC A - BQ -1-2Bq 1 = c q 1 A - BQ -1 A - BQ -1 c q* 1 If the output of the other firms is increased the demand curve for firm 1 moves to the left MR \ q* 1 = (A - c)/2b - Q -1 /2 1 Demand MC Quantity 21

Cournot-Nash equilibrium: many firms q* 1 = (A - c)/2b - Q -1 /2 \ Q* How do we solve this -1 = (N - 1)q* 1 As the The for number firms q* are 1? of identical. \ q* 1 = (A - c)/2b - (N - 1)q* firms 1 So /2 increases As the number output of in equilibrium they of each firms increases falls \ (1 + (N - 1)/2)q* will have identical 1 = (A - c)/2b aggregate As the output number of outputs \ q* 1 (N + 1)/2 = (A - c)/2b firms As increases the increases number price of \ q* 1 = (A - c)/(n + 1)B firms tends increases to marginal profit cost of each firm falls \ Q* = N(A - c)/(n + 1)B \ P* = A - BQ* = (A + Nc)/(N + 1) Profit of firm 1 is P* 1 = (P* - c)q* 1 = (A - c) 2 /(N + 1) 2 B 22

Cournot-Nash equilibrium: different costs What if the firms do not have identical costs? Much the same analysis can be used Marginal costs of firm 1 are c 1 and of firm Solve 2 are this c 2. Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q 1 + q 2 ) for output We have marginal revenue for firm 1 as before MR 1 = (A - Bq 2 ) - 2Bq 1 A symmetric result Equate to marginal cost: (A holds - Bq 2 for ) - 2Bq output 1 = of c 1 firm 2 \ q* 1 = (A-c 1 )/2B - q 2 /2 \ q* 2 = (A-c 2 )/2B - q 1 /2 q 1 23

(A-c 1 )/B (A-c 2 )/2B Cournot-Nash equilibrium: different costs 2 q 2 R 1 R 2 q* 1 = (A - c 1 )/2B - q* 2 /2 The equilibrium If the marginal output cost of firm of firm 2 q* 2 2 = (A - c 2 )/2B - q* 1 /2 increases falls What and its reaction of happens \ q* 2 = to (A this -c 2 )/2B - (A - c 1 )/4B firm curve 1 equilibrium fallshifts to when + q* 2 /4 the costs right change? \ 3q* 2 /4 = (A - 2c 2 + c 1 )/4B \ q* 2 = (A - 2c 2 + c 1 )/3B C \ q* 1 = (A - 2c 1 + c 2 )/3B (A-c 1 )/2B (A-c 2 )/B q 1 24

Cournot-Nash equilibrium: different costs 3 In equilibrium the firms produce q C 1 = (A - 2c 1 + c 2 )/3B; q C 2 = (A - 2c 2 + c 1 )/3B Total output is, therefore, Q* = (2A - c 1 -c 2 )/3B Recall that demand is P = A - B.Q So price is P* = A - (2A - c 1 -c 2 )/3 = (A + c 1 +c 2 )/3 Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c 1 )q C 1 = (A - 2c 1 + c 2 ) 2 /9 Profit of firm 2 is (P* - c 2 )q C 2 = (A - 2c 2 + c 1 ) 2 /9 Equilibrium output is less than the competitive level Output is produced inefficiently: the low-cost firm should produce all the output 25

Concentration and profitability Assume there are N firms with different marginal costs We can use the N-firm analysis with a simple change Recall that demand for firm 1 is P = (A - BQ -1 ) - Bq 1 But then demand for firm i is P = (A - BQ -i ) - Bq i Equate this to marginal cost c i A - BQ -i - 2Bq i = c i But Q* This can be reorganized to give the equilibrium -i + q* condition: i = Q* and A - BQ* = P* A - B(Q* -i + q* i ) - Bq* i -c i = 0 \ P* - Bq* i -c i = 0 \ P* -c i = Bq* i 26

Concentration and profitability 2 P* -c i = Bq* i The price-cost margin Divide by P* and multiply the right-hand for each firm side is by Q*/Q* P* -c i = BQ* q* i determined by its P* P* Q* market share and demand elasticity But BQ*/P* = 1/h and q*/q* = s i (B=dP/dQ!) so: P* -c i = s i P* h Extending this we have P* -c = H P* h (p. 155) Average price-cost margin is determined by industry concentration 27

Price Competition: Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete in prices Internet access Restaurants Consultants Financial services With monopoly setting price or quantity first makes no difference In oligopoly it matters a great deal nature of price competition is much more aggressive the quantity competition 28

Price Competition: Bertrand In the Cournot model price is set by some market clearing mechanism An alternative approach is to assume that firms compete in prices: this is the approach taken by Bertrand Leads to dramatically different results Take a simple example two firms producing an identical product (spring water?) firms choose the prices at which they sell their products each firm has constant marginal cost of c inverse demand is P = A B.Q direct demand is Q = a b.p with a = A/B and b= 1/B 29

Bertrand competition We need the derived demand for each firm demand conditional upon the price charged by the other firm Take firm 2. Assume that firm 1 has set a price of p 1 if firm 2 sets a price greater than p 1 she will sell nothing if firm 2 sets a price less than p 1 she gets the whole market if firm 2 sets a price of exactly p 1 consumers are indifferent between the two firms: the market is shared, presumably 50:50 So we have the derived demand for firm 2 q 2 = 0 if p 2 > p 1 q 2 = (a bp 2 )/2 if p 2 = p 1 q 2 = a bp 2 if p 2 < p 1 30

Bertrand competition 2 This can be illustrated as follows: Demand is discontinuous The discontinuity in demand carries over to profit p 1 p 2 There is a jump at p 2 = p 1 a - bp 1 (a - bp 1 )/2 a q 2 31

Firm 2 s profit is: Bertrand competition 3 p 2 (p 1,, p 2 ) = 0 if p 2 > p 1 p 2 (p 1,, p 2 ) = (p 2 -c)(a -bp 2 ) if p 2 < p 1 p 2 (p 1,, p 2 ) = (p 2 -c)(a -bp 2 )/2 if p 2 = p 1 Clearly this depends on p 1. For whatever reason! Suppose first that firm 1 sets a very high price: greater than the monopoly price of p M = (a +c)/2b 32

What price Bertrand competition should firm 42 set? With p 1 > (a + c)/2b, Firm 2 s profit looks like this: Firm 2 will only earn a positive Firm profit 2 s Profit by cutting its At p2 = p1 The monopoly price to (a + c)/2b or less firm 2 gets half of the price So firm 2 should just monopoly profit undercut p 1 a bit and p 2 < p get almost all the 1 monopoly profit What if firm 1 prices at (a + c)/2b? p 2 = p 1 p 2 > p 1 c (a+c)/2b p 1 Firm 2 s Price 33

Bertrand competition 5 Now suppose that firm 1 sets a price less than (a + c)/2b Firm 2 s profit looks like this: What price Firm 2 s Profit As long as p 1 > c, Of course, firm 1 Firm should 2 should firm aim 2 just will then undercut to undercut set now? firm 1 firm 2 and so on p 2 < p Then firm 2 should also price 1 at c. Cutting price below cost gains the whole market but loses What money if firm on 1every customer prices at c? p 2 = p 1 p 2 > p 1 c p 1 (a+c)/2b Firm 2 s Price 34

Bertrand competition 6 We now have Firm 2 s best response to any price set by firm 1: p* 2 = (a + c)/2b if p 1 > (a + c)/2b p* 2 = p 1 - something small if c < p 1 < (a + c)/2b p* 2 = c if p 1 <c We have a symmetric best response for firm 1 p* 1 = (a + c)/2b if p 2 > (a + c)/2b p* 1 = p 2 - something small if c < p 2 < (a + c)/2b p* 1 = c if p 2 <c 35

Bertrand competition 7 These best response functions look like this p 2 The best response function for firm 1 R 1 The best response function for firm 2 (a + c)/2b c R 2 The Bertrand equilibrium has both firms charging marginal cost The equilibrium is with both firms pricing at c c (a + c)/2b p 1 36

Bertrand Competition Why the wildly different result from Cournot? -Homogenous goods no difference -One-shot game no difference -Demand no difference -In Bertrand, the firm supplies all demand Key difference -How realistic? 37

Bertrand Equilibrium: modifications The Bertrand model makes clear that competition in prices is very different from competition in quantities Since many firms seem to set prices (and not quantities) this is a challenge to the Cournot approach But the extreme version of the difference seems somewhat forced Two extensions can be considered impact of capacity constraints product differentiation 38

Capacity Constraints For the p = c equilibrium to arise, both firms need enough capacity to fill all demand at p = c But when p = c they each get only half the market So, at the p = c equilibrium, there is huge excess capacity So capacity constraints may affect the equilibrium Consider an example daily demand for skiing on Mount Norman Q = 6,000 60P Q is number of lift tickets and P is price of a lift ticket two resorts: Pepall with daily capacity 1,000 and Richards with daily capacity 1,400, both fixed marginal cost of lift services for both is $10 39

The Example Is a price P = c = $10 an equilibrium? total demand is then 5,400, well in excess of capacity Suppose both resorts set P = $10: both then have demand of 2,700 Consider Pepall: raising price loses some demand but where can they go? Richards is already above capacity so some skiers will not switch from Pepall at the higher price but then Pepall is pricing above MC and making profit on the skiers who remain so P = $10 cannot be an equilibrium 40

The example 2 Assume that at any price where demand at a resort is greater than capacity there is efficient rationing serves skiers with the highest willingness to pay Then can derive residual demand Assume P = $60 total demand = 2,400 = total capacity so Pepall gets 1,000 skiers residual demand to Richards with efficient rationing is Q = 5000 60P or P = 83.33 Q/60 in inverse form marginal revenue is then MR = 83.33 Q/30 41

The example 3 Residual demand and MR: Price Suppose that Richards sets $83.33 P = $60. Does it want to change? $60 since MR > MC Richards does not want to raise price and lose skiers $36.66 since Q R = 1,400 Richards is at capacity and does not want to reduce price MR Demand $10 MC 1,400 Same logic applies to Pepall so P = $60 is a Nash equilibrium for this game. Quantity 42

Logic is quite general Capacity constraints again firms are unlikely to choose sufficient capacity to serve the whole market when price equals marginal cost since they get only a fraction in equilibrium so capacity of each firm is less than needed to serve the whole market but then there is no incentive to cut price to marginal cost So the efficiency property of Bertrand equilibrium breaks down when firms are capacity constrained 43

Product differentiation Original analysis also assumes that firms offer homogeneous products Creates incentives for firms to differentiate their products to generate consumer loyalty do not lose all demand when they price above their rivals keep the most loyal 44

An example of product differentiation Coke and Pepsi are similar but not identical. As a result, the lower priced product does not win the entire market. Econometric estimation gives: Q C = 63.42-3.98P C + 2.25P P MC C = $4.96 Q P = 49.52-5.48P P + 1.40P C MC P = $3.96 There are at least two methods for solving for P C and P P 45

Bertrand and product differentiation Method 1: Calculus Profit of Coke: p C = (P C - 4.96)(63.42-3.98P C + 2.25P P ) Profit of Pepsi: p P = (P P - 3.96)(49.52-5.48P P + 1.40P C ) Differentiate with respect to P C and P P respectively Method 2: MR = MC Reorganize the demand functions P C = (15.93 + 0.57P P ) - 0.25Q C P P = (9.04 + 0.26P C ) - 0.18Q P Calculate marginal revenue, equate to marginal cost, solve for Q C and Q P and substitute in the demand functions 46

Bertrand and product differentiation 2 Both methods give the best response functions: P C = 10.44 + 0.2826P P P P = 6.49 + 0.1277P C These can be solved for the equilibrium prices as indicated The equilibrium prices are each greater than marginal cost $8.11 $6.49 P P The Note Bertrand that these equilibrium are upwardis at sloping their intersection B $10.44 $12.72 R C R P P C 47

Bertrand competition and the spatial model An alternative approach: spatial model of Hotelling a Main Street over which consumers are distributed supplied by two shops located at opposite ends of the street but now the shops are competitors each consumer buys exactly one unit of the good provided that its full price is less than V a consumer buys from the shop offering the lower full price consumers incur transport costs of t per unit distance in travelling to a shop Recall the broader interpretation What prices will the two shops charge? 48

Price Bertrand and the spatial model x m marks the location of the marginal buyer one who What Assume if shop that is 1 raises indifferent shop 1 setsbetweenprice price its price? 1 and buying shop 2 either sets firm s good price p 2 p 1 p 1 p 2 x x m m All consumers to the And all consumers Shop 1 left of x m x buy from m moves to the to the right buyshop from 2 left: some consumers shop 1 shop 2 switch to shop 2 49

Bertrand and the spatial model 2 p 1 + tx m = p 2 + t(1 - x m ) \2tx m = p 2 -p 1 + t \x m (p How is x m 1, p 2 ) = (p 2 -p 1 + t)/2t determined? There are N consumers in total This is the fraction of consumers who So demand to firm 1 is D 1 = N(p 2 -p 1 + buy t)/2t from firm 1 Price Price p 1 p 2 x m Shop 1 Shop 2 50

Bertrand equilibrium Profit to firm 1 is p 1 = (p 1 - c)d 1 = N(p 1 - c)(p 2 -p 1 + t)/2t This is the best p 1 = N(p 2 p 1 -p 12 + tp 1 + cp 1 -response cp 2 -ct)/2t function Solve this Differentiate with respect to p 1 for firm 1for p 1 N p 1 / p 1 = (p 2-2p 1 + t + c) = 0 2t p* 1 = (p 2 + t + c)/2 This is the best response What about firm 2? By function symmetry, for firm it 2has a similar best response function. p* 2 = (p 1 + t + c)/2 51

p* 1 = (p 2 + t + c)/2 Bertrand equilibrium 2 p 2 R 1 p* 2 = (p 1 + t + c)/2 2p* 2 = p 1 + t + c R 2 = p 2 /2 + 3(t + c)/2 c + t \ p* 2 = t + c \ p* 1 = t + c (c + t)/2 Profit per unit to each firm is t (c + t)/2 Aggregate profit to each firm is Nt/2 c + t p 1 52

Bertrand competition 3 Two final points on this analysis t is a measure of transport costs it is also a measure of the value consumers place on getting their most preferred variety when t is large competition is softened and profit is increased when t is small competition is tougher and profit is decreased Locations have been taken as fixed suppose product design can be set by the firms balance business stealing temptation to be close against competition softening desire to be separate 53

Strategic complements and substitutes Best response functions are very different with Cournot and Bertrand they have opposite slopes reflects very different forms of competition firms react differently e.g. to an increase in costs q 2 p 2 Firm 1 Firm 2 Firm 1 Cournot q 1 Firm 2 Bertrand p 1 54

Strategic complements and substitutes q 2 suppose firm 2 s costs increase this causes Firm 2 s Cournot best response function to fall at any output for firm 1 firm 2 now wants to produce less firm 1 s output increases and firm 2 s falls Firm 2 s Bertrand best response function rises at any price for firm 1 firm 2 now wants to raise its price firm 1 s price increases as does firm 2 s p 2 Firm 1 passive response by firm1 aggressive response by firm1 Firm 2 Firm 1 Firm2 q 1 p 1 Cournot Bertrand 55

Strategic complements and substitutes 2 When best response functions are upward sloping (e.g. Bertrand) we have strategic complements passive action induces passive response When best response functions are downward sloping (e.g. Cournot) we have strategic substitutes passive actions induces aggressive response Difficult to determine strategic choice variable: price or quantity output in advance of sale probably quantity production schedules easily changed and intense competition for customers probably price 56

Assume payoff (ie. profit) u for strategies (ie. prices, quantities) s The necessary first order condition (FOC) for player i is u ( s, s i s i -i i ) = 0 The Nash equilibrium is typically calculated by solving the system of equations determined by the FOC:s for each player. Consider a situation with two players (i and j). By totally differentiating the necessary FOC and noting that = ( ) s r s - i i i u ( r( s ), s ) u ( s, s ) '( ) + = 0 2 2 i i -i j i i j r 2 i s-i si si sj 57

58 the slope of player i s reaction function can be found to be 2 2 2 ), ( ), ( ) '( i j i i j i j i i i i s s s u s s s s u s r - = - { } = j i j i i i s s s s u sign r sign ), ( ' 2 0 ) ( 0 ), ( 2 < > j i j i i s s s s u Because we have assumed concavity it follows from this that Consequently, the reaction function is upward (downward) sloping if and only if.