Submission to Standing Committee on Tax and Revenue inquiry into the Tax Expenditures Statement

Similar documents
Assessing the Threshold of the Division 293 Contributions Tax

The equity and sustainability of government assistance for retirement income in Australia

Commonwealth Budget Report

A gender impact assessment of Australia s retirement income policy

Exploring the Personal Income Tax System

Submission to Senate Standing Committees on Economics Inquiry into Economic Security for Women in Retirement

The ATO and loss of priority in insolvency: Does tax expenditure analysis provide a solution?

TAXING PERSONAL CAPITAL GAINS IN AUSTRALIA IS THE DISCOUNT READY FOR REFORM? JOHN MINAS* ABSTRACT

Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April Lower Personal Income Tax Rates. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne

SECURING RETIREMENT INCOMES. TAX & SUPERANNUATION: THE SHORTCOMINGS OF the SUPERANNUATION TAXATION EXPENDITURES

Superannuation changes

Guardian Investments - Budget 2016: What you need to know

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2009: RETIREMENT INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES AUSTRALIA

Superannuation changes

Labour Market Responses to the Abolition of Compulsory Superannuation

Federal Budget Summary

Exploring the Personal Income Tax System

THE PARLIAMENT OF THE COMMONWEALTH OF AUSTRALIA HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES INCOME TAX RATES AMENDMENT (WORKING HOLIDAY MAKER REFORM) BILL 2016

2016/17 Budget. 1. Effective Budget Night 7.30pm (AEST) 3 May New lifetime cap for non-concessional superannuation contributions

AIST. 22 October Sex Discrimination Commissioner Australian Human Rights Commission Level 3, 175 Pitt St SYDNEY NSW 200. Dear Ms Broderick,

Last night s Federal Budget contained a number of proposals that will impact the financial planning industry.

Budget Summary of Tax and Other Issues. Prepared by:

Optimum Corporate Super

Mythbusters. Myths that a 12 per cent SG is not needed. May Ross Clare, Director of Research ASFA Research and Resource Centre

Tax Reform: Informing the debate

FACT SHEET MAKING SUPERANNUATION FAIRER

Key changes for 2015 and beyond

Workforce Superannuation

Tax expenditure statement

Partnership Superannuation Plan

` CHARTERED ACCOUNTANTS. Making Your Business Count

ASFA 2014 National Conference

Tax and super. Member Booklet Supplement. 1 March 2018

LABOR PARTY RESPONSE TO THE FEDERAL PRE-ELECTION SUBMISSION FROM AIR

The great superannuation tax concession rort

Submission to the Senate Inquiry into the Major Bank Levy Bill 2017

Federal Budget May 2014

Superannuation Superannuation

Introduction... 1 Taxation... 2 Superannuation... 8 Social Security and Family Assistance Henry response confirmation... 13

Significant Events Notice. Product and investment changes for the year ending 30 June 2013

Re: Position Paper Means Test Rules for Lifetime Retirement Income Streams

Shaping the Future of Tax Reform. November 2015

Superannuation. A Financial Planning Technical Guide

Superannuation. A Financial Planning Guide

SMSF Association Budget Update : The most significant changes to superannuation since 2007

SUBMISSION. The Treasury. Retirement Income Disclosure. Consultation Paper 5 April 2019

Tax background paper. National Reform Summit John Daley, Grattan Institute August 2015

Superannuation. A Financial Planning Technical Guide

The Australia Taxation reflects legislation in place at 1 November Exam questions will be based upon the tax year.

Tax Transparency Code

Making sense of the budget crisis. ACOSS National Conference John Daley Grattan Institute 11 June 2014

2017 FEDERAL BUDGET SYNOPSIS

BWR Accountants & Advisers

Superannuation (also refer to summary on page 5)

Integrity Plus New Zealand National Integrity System Assessment. Additional Paper

THE PARLIAMENT OF THE COMMONWEALTH OF AUSTRALIA HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES TREASURY LAWS AMENDMENT (PERSONAL INCOME TAX PLAN) BILL 2018

SUBMISSION: CHARTER OF SUPERANNUATION ADEQUACY AND SUSTAINABILITY AND COUNCIL OF SUPERANNUATION CUSTODIANS

Swim between the flags SMSF Trustee Program. Module 6 of 7. TAXATION OF SMSF s. Financial education for all Australians

Accurium Federal Budget Report

From 1 July 2019, the Medicare levy will be increased to 2.5% to fund the National Disability Insurance Scheme.

SMSF Legislative Changes Applicable from 1 July 2013

MYTH VS REALITY: THE CASE AGAINST INCREASING CAPITAL GAINS TAX. No. 18 March 2019

BOURKE O BRIEN KENNEDY

INTERNATIONAL ASPECTS OF AUSTRALIAN INCOME TAX

Active vs passive assets and the small business CGT concession

THE PARLIAMENT OF THE COMMONWEALTH OF AUSTRALIA HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

Submission to the Federal Tax Discussion Paper. Prepared by the Urban Development Institute of Australia (UDIA)

ASFA Pre-Budget submission for the 2016/2017 Budget. February 2016 The Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia (ASFA)

SUPER & PENSION PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT

REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA

INQUIRY INTO MINERAL RESOURCE RENT TAX BILL 2011 AND RELATED BILLS

Retirement Savings and Tax Expenditure Estimates

Improving the Efficiency of the Australian Tax System: a model-based analysis

The Medicare levy surcharge arrangements Tax penalty or hidden tax subsidy? Julie Smith

Submission to the Commonwealth Government on the Objective of Superannuation

2014 budget summary. Introduction 2 Superannuation 2

Removing the refundability of franking credits

JUNE 2017 NEWSLETTER. The 2017 financial year has seen the raft of changes, first introduced in the 2016 budget, legislated into law.

REPORT OF SENATE SELECT COMMITTEE ON SUPERANNUATION AND STANDARDS OF LIVING IN RETIREMENT: ANALYSIS AND REVIEW. Abstract

Australia s super system stacks up well internationally. Ross Clare, Director of Research ASFA Research and Resource Centre

Tax incentives for giving to charities and other non-profit organisations

Introducing the Grattan Retirement Incomes Model (GRIM)

Parliament of Australia Department of Parliamentary Services

Efficiency of the Tax System: a marginal excess burden analysis

Here s a round-up of what the Federal Budget could mean for your family finances.

Tax Reform. Tax Institute Financial Services Conference. 8 February Anna Bligh, Chief Executive Australian Bankers Association

InfoConnect Newsletter from the Aspiron Consulting Group Federal Budget Edition 2017/18

2015/2016 Budget Submission SUPERANNUATED COMMONWEALTH OFFICERS ASSOCIATION (FEDERAL COUNCIL) INC. ADVOCATING FOR A SECURE RETIREMENT.

Understanding retirement income Version 5.2

Budget Fairness, security and opportunity. P

We can afford fair GST reform

Financial Review: Banking & Wealth Summit A World-leading Superannuation System

Mythbusting superannuation tax concessions

Understanding superannuation Version 5.2

Off-market share buy-backs revisited

2017 Hub Wealth Management Federal Budget Summary

Budget Summary. Tuesday, 8 May 2018

Budget Changes & Tax Planning Strategies

Westpac Personal Superannuation Fund. Westpac Term Life as Superannuation.

IOOF LifeTrack employer super general reference guide (LT.13)

Transcription:

4 August 2015 Submission to Standing Committee on Tax and Revenue inquiry into the Tax Expenditures Statement John Daley, Danielle Wood, Brendan Coates

1 Summary We welcome the Standing Committee on Tax and Revenue s inquiry into the Tax Expenditures Statement (TES). Tax expenditures are government revenues foregone because certain activities or classes of taxpayers receive preferential tax treatment. Tax expenditures can take many forms including exemptions, deductions, concessional rates or deferral of tax liabilities. 1 Estimates of tax expenditures inform public discussion of the cost of tax concessions. Because tax expenditures are inherently more difficult to measure and observe than government spending, they do not attract the same scrutiny, despite their often large budget impact. 2 The annual TES provides a regular assessment of the size and scope of these expenditures. Ultimately, this improves the transparency and accountability of government. Transparency could be further improved by publishing long-term projections of the costs of major tax expenditures in the Australian Government s Intergenerational Report every five years. This submission considers three criticisms frequently levied at the tax expenditure estimates and presents our views on whether refinements to the TES reporting and methodology are justified. A common criticism of the TES is the choice of benchmark for estimating expenditures for savings tax concessions. Some argue that concessional tax treatment of savings, relative to other income, is a desirable structural feature of the tax system so tax expenditures should be measured from an expenditure rather than an income tax benchmark. But the income benchmark remains the best measure of the revenue costs of providing these concessions. Policy arguments in favour of the concessional tax treatment of savings are separate from the question of how the costs of these concessions are measured. There are also complaints that the standard revenue foregone tax expenditure estimates do not factor in behaviour change. Revenue foregone estimates are useful because they are a mirror of the government payment estimates reported in the Budget. But for large and contentious tax expenditures such as superannuation tax concessions and GST exemptions we see merit in Treasury separately publishing revenue gain estimates that incorporate behaviour change. A further criticism from the superannuation industry is that tax expenditures for superannuation do not account for reductions in government outlays on the Age Pension. Treasury s approach of excluding second round effects is consistent with the international standard and should be retained. However there would be value in Treasury publishing additional estimates of the net fiscal cost of superannuation tax concessions to inform the retirement incomes debate. 1 Treasury (2015), p.3; Brixi, et al. (2004), p.3. 2 Treasury (2010), p.719.

2 The choice of benchmark A recurring issue with tax expenditures is the choice of benchmark. A benchmark is the standard tax treatment or tax norms against which the size of any tax exemptions or concessions can be assessed. 3 The challenge is defining the standard tax treatment. As one commentator puts it [o]ne person s idea of an unjustifiable concession could be another s idea of a desirable structural feature of the tax system. 4 For taxes on income, Australia s tax expenditures use a comprehensive income tax benchmark. This compares the tax collected under the concessional regime with the tax that would be paid if the income were taxed at an individuals marginal rate of personal income tax. 5 Some commentators and industry groups argue that an income tax benchmark is not appropriate for savings tax concessions, particularly for long term savings such as superannuation, because it would be inappropriate to tax savings in the same ways as ordinary income. In particular, taxes on savings create a bias in favour of current over future consumption. 6 These commentators often claim that an expenditure tax benchmark which implicitly sets a zero tax benchmark on income from savings would be more appropriate. 7 It is unsurprising that those who prefer lower taxes on savings in general also prefer benchmarks that reduce the apparent size of the tax expenditures. Under the pre-paid expenditure tax benchmark advocated by some, 8 earnings and benefits are untaxed but contributions are fully taxed at marginal tax rates. This substantially reduces the size of the estimated tax expenditures. In 2013-14, the estimated tax expenditures were $16 billion for superannuation contributions concessions and around the same for earnings tax concessions relative to an income tax benchmark. 9 In contrast, using the pre-paid expenditure benchmark, contributions concessions still cost $16 billion in foregone revenue while the earnings regime provides a 3 Treasury (2015), p. 3; Brixi, et al. (2004), p. 9. 4 Carling (2015), p.6. 5 Personal income tax rates include the Medicare Levy and the Low Income Tax Offset, plus the Temporary Budget Repair Levy for 2014-15 to 2016-17. The income tax benchmark for assessing tax expenditures also incorporates some structural elements of the tax system such as the progressive income tax rate scale for individual taxpayers. The structural elements considered in the benchmark are themselves open to debate. Treasury (2015), Appendix A. 6 Taxes on savings are double taxation, wage income is taxed when it is earned and again when it generates investment income. This promotes current consumption at the expense of saving. This bias is reinforced when there is inflation because effective tax rates on real returns are high if nominal gains are taxed at marginal income tax rates. 7 There are two types of expenditure tax benchmark: (a) a pre-paid expenditure tax benchmark based on the direct taxation of labour income with an exemption for saving; and (b) a post-paid expenditure tax benchmark based on the taxation of consumption, with no taxation of income. 8 See Carling (2015), p.6; Sloan (2015). 9 Treasury (2014), p.12.

gain to the budget of $5.8 billion, on the basis that the earnings paid at least some tax. 10 However, an expenditure tax benchmark is divorced from reality: few people seriously suggest that income generated by savings should be tax free. 11 A benchmark should reflect the standard tax treatment of a particular activity: it should not favour one activity over another. 12 Other types of savings income such as bank interest are taxed at a taxpayer s full marginal rate of income tax. Bur even where there are other tax-advantaged savings vehicles taxpayers could choose, this does not mean they are the relevant benchmark. The point of tax expenditures is to allow comparison of all such tax-advantaged vehicles so that the policy outcomes can be compared with their costs. For this reason the comprehensive income tax benchmark remains the most appropriate benchmark for estimating the Commonwealth Government s tax expenditures on concessional tax treatment of superannuation earnings and other forms of savings income. This is not to say that there is no policy case for treating savings income concessionally. But the income tax benchmark allows the community to understand the costs of providing these concessions and to assess whether they provide value for money in meeting those policy goals. 10 Ibid., p.193. 11 Most economists accept the equity and efficiency arguments for some taxation of savings income, although they do not always agree that labour and savings income should be taxed at the same rate. Carling (2015), p. 8; Treasury (2010), p. 4. 12 Treasury (2014), p. 195.

3 Accounting for behavioural change Consistent with most OECD countries, Treasury estimates tax expenditures based on the revenue forgone to the budget from the expenditure. Revenue forgone estimates indicate the benefit to taxpayers from a particular concession. There are frequent complaints that revenue forgone estimates do not provide an accurate measure of the tax revenue that would be gained if the expenditure was abolished. 13 This is because they do not account for behavioural change. But revenue forgone estimates are not intended to measure incremental revenues from policy changes. Instead, they are a mirror of the estimates of government payments reported in the Budget. Spending estimates do not adjust for offsetting fiscal impacts from behavioural change if spending were ceased. For example, estimates of outlays on the Age Pension measure the value of Age Pension payments to individuals not the saving to the budget if the Age Pension were abolished. The latter would be far more difficult to produce as it would need to account for things like the offsetting impact of higher spending on other welfare and social programs. Of course, tax expenditure estimates that account for behaviour change are also informative, where they can be credibly estimated. Such revenue gain estimates provide a better picture of the revenue benefits should the government abolish the concessions. These estimates also provide a useful response to vested interests seeking to discredit tax expenditures on the grounds they do not include behavioural change. Superannuation tax concessions are a prominent example of how the failure to account for behaviour change can be used as a smokescreen to distract from the size of the tax expenditure. Although many have commented at length about the failure to account for behaviour change, 14 it doesn t make much difference. Even if substantial elements of the superannuation regime were changed, behaviour would change little. Alternative savings vehicles are much less generous than superannuation. Unlike other savings vehicles, superannuation allows saving from pre-tax income (less 15 per cent), and imposes much lower tax rates. Treasury estimates that if superannuation tax breaks were abolished, the additional revenue after accounting for behaviour change would only be marginally lower than the revenue forgone estimates. Treasury estimates that revenue forgone from contributions concessions was $16.3 billion and earnings concessions was $13.4 billion in 2014-15. 15 Treasury s revenue gain estimate for contributions concessions is 95 per cent of the original tax expenditure and 88 per cent for super earnings concessions. Treasury uses a sophisticated approach to estimating behavioural change. It assumes that if contributions tax concessions were abolished, contributions to superannuation would instead be directed towards alternative tax-preferred investments. The revenue gain estimate for earnings concessions factors in lower 13 Clare (2015); ASFA (2015); Mercer (2013) 14 For example see ASFA (2015), p.3, 28.; Mercer (2013), p.7; FSC (2015), p.13. 15 Treasury (2015), p. 7.

contributions as super becomes a less attractive savings vehicle and account holders withdraw savings to take advantage of taxfree thresholds and offsets available outside of superannuation. Treasury s revenue gain estimates for superannuation tax concessions advanced the public debate. But requiring all tax expenditures be reported net of behavioural changes would substantially increase the complexity and cost of the calculations. In our view, this exercise should only be undertaken where there is significant benefit because the tax expenditures are large and contentious.

4 Tax expenditures and offsetting spending impacts increasing the Super Guarantee rate to 12 per cent as part of the Cooper Review. 18 A final criticism of tax expenditures is they do not adjust for offsetting impacts on government outlays. The superannuation industry claims that estimates of tax expenditures for super tax concessions are overstated because they do not account for reduced Age Pension payments as superannuation benefits increase. 16 In Australia and across other economies, tax expenditures are measured as the difference between total tax revenue in the presence and absence of the particular tax concession, assuming everything else remains unchanged. 17 Excluding second round effects on government spending or tax collections ensures the analysis is tractable and consistent across measures. There is no case for Treasury departing from the standard approach to estimating expenditures for superannuation tax concessions. However, given the centrality to the retirement incomes debate there would be value in Treasury producing a separate estimate of the net fiscal impact of superannuation tax concessions, including fiscal savings from reduced Age Pension outlays. Treasury already has the modelling capability to do this: it previously prepared estimates of the long run fiscal impact of 16 Mercer, p.5-6; FSC (2015), p.13-14; Clare (2015), p.3. 17 Brixi, et al. (2004), p.26. 18 Cooper Review (2013), p.11.

5 Reference ASFA (2015) Submission to the Treasury: Response to the tax discussion paper, Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia accessed 24 June 2015, from http://www.superannuation.asn.au/policy/submissions/ Brixi, H. P., Valenduc, C. and Smith, Z. L. (2004) Tax Expenditures--Shedding Light on Government Spending through the Tax System : Lessons from Developed and Transition Economies, World Bank accessed 2 August 2015, from http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/abs/10.1596/0-8213-5601-1 Carling, R. (2015) Right or Rort? Dissecting Australia's Tax Concessions, Research Report, April 2015, Centre for Independent Studies, accessed 2 August 2015, from http://www.cis.org.au/images/stories/research-reports/rr2.pdf Clare, R. (2015) Mythbusting superannuation tax concessions, Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia accessed 30 June 2015, from http://www.superannuation.asn.au/policy/reports Cooper Review (2013) A Super Charter: Fewer Changes, Better Outcomes, Council of Superannuation Custodians, accessed 2 August 2015, from http://www.treasury.gov.au/policy-topics/superannuationandretirement/supercharter/~/media/treasury/policy Topics/Superannuation/supercharter/Downloads/PDF/super_charter_report.ashx FSC (2015) Tax White Paper Submission, Financial Services Council, accessed 23 February 2015 Mercer (2013) Tax & Superannuation: The shortcomings of the superannuation taxation expenditures, accessed 30 April 2015, from http://www.mercer.com.au/content/dam/mercer/attachments/asia-pacific/australia/insights/shortcomings-of-super-tax-expenditures.pdf Sloan, J. (2015) 'Superannuation tax system needs to be simplified', The Australian, 24 February 2015, accessed 25 July 2015, from http://www.theaustralian.com.au/opinion/columnists/superannuation-tax-system-needs-to-be-simplified/story-fnbkvnk7-1227236107004 Treasury (2010) Australia's future tax system - Report to the Treasurer, The Treasury, Australian Government, accessed October 2013, from http://taxreview.treasury.gov.au/content/content.aspx?doc=html/pubs_reports.htm Treasury (2014) Tax expenditures statement 2013, accessed 27 July 2015, from http://treasury.gov.au/~/media/treasury/publications and Media/Publications/2014/TES 2013/Documents/PDF/TES-13-Consolidated.ashx

Treasury (2015) Tax Expenditures Statement 2014, The Treasury, Australian Government accessed 23 March 2015, from http://www.treasury.gov.au/publicationsandmedia/publications/2015/tes-2014