NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RULES AND THE MISMANAGEMENT OF MONETARY FLICY. Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. 122

Similar documents
THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY ON PRIVATE SAVING: THE TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE CASE AGAINST TRYING TO STABILIZE THE DOLLAR. Martin Feldatein. Working Paper No. 2838

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPUTING CORPORATE TAX LIABILITIES TO INDIVIDUAL TAXPAYERS. Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. 2349

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY IS THE DOLLAR SO HIGH? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper

Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

Chapter URL:

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity?

David C. Hartman. Working Paper No. 967

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework

The 2006 Economic Report of the President

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES. INFLATION, CAPITAL TAXATON AND t4netary POLICY. Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. 680

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4

Overview. Martin Feldstein

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

CRS Report for Congress

Working Paper No. 2032

THE NEW, NEW ECONOMICS AND MONETARY POLICY. Remarks Prepared by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

The Impact of an Increase In The Money Supply and Government Spending In The UK Economy

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

No 02. Chapter 1. Chapter Outline. What Macroeconomics Is About. Introduction to Macroeconomics

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Midterm #2, version A, given Spring 2002 Note question #50 is from Chapter 11, which students are not responsible for on Exam 2 - Summer 02.

Do Tax Havens Divert Economic Activity?

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

REGULATION Q AND THE BEHAVIOR OF SAVINGS AND SMALL TIME DEPOSITS AT COMMERCIAL BANKS AND THE THRIFT INSTITUTIONS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

Some Preliminary Macroeconomics of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF FEDERAL TAX DEDUCTIBILITY ON STATE AND LOCAL TAXES AND SPENDING. Gilbert Metcalf. Working Paper No.

The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary

Buoyant Economies. Formula for the Current Account Balance

Volume Author/Editor: Benjamin M. Friedman, ed. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press. Volume URL:

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Federal Budget Policy with an Aging Population and Persistently Low Interest Rates. Douglas Elmendorf and Louise Sheiner

Prefunding Medicare. The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters

Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 39: Indexation and the Inflation Tax

Current Economic Conditions and Selected Forecasts

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Principle of Macroeconomics, Summer B Practice Exam

Chapter 26 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence

Do high interest rates stem capital outflows?

5 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND INFLATION. Part Review. Reading Between the Lines WHERE WILL INTEREST RATES GO IN 2002?

Volume Title: The American Economy in Transition. Volume Author/Editor: Martin Feldstein, ed. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

Volume Title: The Behavior of Interest Rates: A Progress Report. Volume URL:

Exemplar for Internal Assessment Resource Economics Level 2

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

Case, Fair and Oster Macroeconomics Chapter 12 Problems -- Aggregate Demand in the Goods and Money Markets

Shanghai Livingston American School Quarterly / Trimester Plan 3 AP Macro

Practice Problems 30-32

Chapter URL:

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #3. February 12, 2018

PART ONE INTRODUCTION

Press Release - The Sveriges Riksbank (Bank of Sweden) Prize in Economics in Memory of Alfred Nobel

The Case for Price Stability with a Flexible Exchange Rate in the New Neoclassical Synthesis Marvin Goodfriend

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

Fiscal stimulus : A loanable funds critique. Author. Published. Journal Title. Copyright Statement. Downloaded from. Link to published version

How Important Are U.S. Capital Flows into Mexico?

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

Aggregate Demand in Keynesian Analysis

Chapter 25 Fiscal Policy Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

REFORMING PCA. Addendum to Submitted Statements of. Mary Cunningham. and. William Raker. to the. National Credit Union Administration s

A. unchanged decrease B. surplus decrease C. unchanged no change D. surplus increase E. unchanged increase A. A B. B C. C D. D E. E.

The Lack of an Empirical Rationale for a Revival of Discretionary Fiscal Policy. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Feldstein Proposal Increases Federal Revenues but the Devil s in the Details

The Supply-Side Effects of Economic Policy

PROSPECTS FOR THE UNITED STATES ECONOMY

SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS BSc. (APPLIED ACCOUNTING) GENERAL / SPECIAL DEGREE PROGRAMME YEAR II SEMESTER II END SEMESTER EXAMINATION APRIL 2015

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

Monetary Policy Frameworks

2014 Annual Review & Outlook

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

Yes, We Can Reduce the Unemployment Rate

CHAPTER 2 Measurement

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119

Effects of Taxes on Economic Behavior

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Implications of Financial Repression on Economic Growth: Evidence from Nigeria

Macroeconomics. Identify and apply relevant terminology and concepts to economic issues and problems.

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

During the global financial crisis, many central

Comments on Monetary Policy at the Effective Lower Bound

Helpful Hint Fiscal Policy and the AS-AD Model

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Saving, wealth and consumption

The transformation of public economics research: q

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

Monetary policy assessment of 12 March 2009 Swiss National Bank takes decisive action to forcefully relax monetary conditions

MONETARY POLICY: DOMESTIC TARGETS AND INTERNATIONAL CONSTRAINTS

ECO403 Macroeconomics Solved Online Quiz For Midterm Exam Preparation Spring 2013

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Transcription:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX RULES AND THE MISMANAGEMENT OF MONETARY FLICY Martin Feldstein Working Paper No. 122 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge MA 02138 January 1980 The research reported here is part of the NBER's research program in Taxation. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

NBER Working Paper #422 December, 1979 Tax Rules and the Mismanagement of Monetary Policy ABSTRACT This paper emphasizes the importance of the interaction between tax rules and the management of monetary policy. The monetary authorities' failure to recognize the implications of the tax structure has caused them to underestimate just how expansionary monetary policy has been. Moreover, because of our fiscal structure, attempts to encourage investment by an easy money policy have actually had an adverse impact on investment in plant and equipment. The paper discusses the desirability of substituting a policy of tight money and positive fiscal incentives for the traditional goals of easy money and fiscal restraint. More generally, the paper stresses the significance of the fiscal structure as a determinant of macroeconomic equilibrium. Martin Feldstein National Bureau of Economic Research 1050 Mass. Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 (617) 868 3905

Tax Rules and the Mismanagement of Monetary Policy Martin Feldstein* It is now widely agreed that the mismanagement of monetary policy over the past 15 years has been a major cause of our current obstinately high rate of inflation. I believe that an important source of this rne tary mismanagement has been the failure of the monetary authorities (and of economists in general) to understand how the interaction between inflation and our tax rules influences the effects of monetary policy. More specifically, as I shall explain in the present paper, I believe that the monetary authorities' failure to recognize the implications of the fiscal structure has caused them to underestimate just how expansionary monetary policy has been. Moreover, because of our fiscal structure, attempts to encourage investment by an easy money policy have actually had an adverse impact on investment in plant and equipment. The conventional prescription of "easy money and a tight fiscal position" has been an unfortunate guide for macroeconomic policy. The switch to floating exchange rates and the relaxation of some of the old restrictions on financial institutions have made it even more important to reject this conven.- tional prescription and to pursue instead a policy mix of "tight money and positive fiscal incentives". I. Misjudging Monetary Tightness During the dozen years after the 1951 accord between the Treasury

2 and the Fed, the interest rate on Baa bonds varied only in the narrow range between 3 1/2 percent and 5 percent. In contrast, the past 15 years have seen the Baa rate rise from less than 5 percent in 19614 to more than 10 percent at the beginning of 19T9. It is perhaps not surprising therefore that the monetary authorities, other government officials, and many private economists have worried throughout this period that interest rates might be getting "too high". Critics of what was perceived as "tight money" argued that such high interest rates would reduce investment and therefore depress aggregate demand. Against all this it could be argued, and was argued, that the real interest rate had obviously gone up much less. The correct measure of the real interest rate is of course the difference between the nominal interest rate and the rate of inflation that is expected over the life of the bond. A common rule of thumb approximates the expected future inflation by the average inflation rate experienced during the preceding three years. In 19614, when the Baa rate was 14.8 percent, this three year rise in the GNP deflator averaged 1.14 percent; the implied real interest rate was thus 3.14 percent. By the beginning of 1969, when the Baa rate was 10.0 percent, the rise in the GNP deflator for the previous 3 years had increased to 6.2 percent, implying a real interest rate of 3.8 percent. Judged in this way, the cost of credit has increased only slightly over the 15 year period. All of this ignores the role of taxes. Since interest expenses can be deducted by individuals and businesses in calculating taxable income, the net of tax interest cost is very much less than the interest rate

3 itself. Indeed, since the nominal interest expense can be deducted, the real net of tax interest cost has actually varied inversely with the nominal rate of inflation. What appears to have been a rising interest rate over the past 15 years was actually a sharply falling rei after tax cost of funds. The failure to recognize the rol" i taxes prevented the monetary authorities from seeing how expansionary monetary policy had become. The implication of tax decutibility is seen most easily in the case of owner occupied housing. A married couple with a $30,000 taxable income now has a. marginal federal income tax rate of 37 percent. The 10 percent mortgage rate in effect at the beginning of 1979 implied a net of tax cost of funds of 6.3 percent. Subtracting the 6.2 percent estimate of the rate of inflation leaves a real net oftax cost of funds of only 0.1 percent. By comparison, the 1.8 percent interest rate for 196I translates into a 3.0 percent net of tax rate and a 1.6 percent real net of tax cost of funds. Thus, although the nominal interest rate had more than doubled and the real interest rate had also increased, the relevant net of tax real cost of funds had actually fallen from 1.6 percent to only 0.1 percent. As this example shows, taking the effects of taxation into account is particularly important because the tax rules are so non neutral when there is inflation. If the tax rules were completely indexed, the effect of the tax system on the conduct of monetary policy would be much less significant. But with existing tax rules, the movements of the pretax real interest rate and of the after tax real interest rates are completely dif

it ferent. I think that monetary policy in the last decade was overly expansionary because the monetary authorities and others believed that the cost of funds was rising or steady when in fact it was falling significantly. The fall in the real after tax interest rate has caused a rapid increase in the price of houses relative to the general price level (see e.g., Hendershott and Hu, 1979) and has sustained a high rate of new residential construction. There were, of course, times when the ceilings on the interest rates that financial institutions could pay caused disinter mediation and limited the funds available for housing. To that extent, the high level of nominal interest rates restricted the supply of funds at the same time that the corresponding low real after tax interest cost increased the demand for funds. More recently, the raising of certain interest rate ceilings and the development of mortgage backed bonds that can short circuit the disintermediation process have made the supply restrictions much less important and have therefore made any interest level more expansionary that it otherwise would have been. The low real after tax rate of interest has also encouraged the growth generally, of consumer credit and the purchase of consumer durables. More even households that do not itemize their tax deductions are affected by the low real after tax return that is available on savings. Because individuals pay tax on nominal interest income, the real after tax rate of return on saving has become negative. It seems very likely that this substantial fall in the real return on savings has contributed to the

5 fall in the personal saving rate and the rise in consumer deniand.- For corporate borrowers, the analysis is nre complex because inflatiqn changes the effective tax rate on investits as well as the real net of tax interest rate. More specifically, historic cost depreciation and inventory accounting rules reduce substantially the real after tax return on corporate investments (see Feldstein and Sununers, 1979). An easy money policy raises the demand for corporate capital only if the real net cost of funds falls by more than the return that firms can af fort to pay. This balance between the lower real net interest cost and the lower real net return on investment depends on the corporation's debt equity ratio and on the difference between the real yields that must be paid on debt and on equity funds. It is difficult to say just what has happened on balance. In a preliminary study, Lawrence Summers and I concluded that the rise in the nominal interest rate caused by inflation was slightly less than the rise in the maximum interest rate that firms could afford to pay (Feldstein and Sunnners, 1978). However, this analysis made no allowance for the effect of inventory taxation or for the more complex effects of inflation on equity yields that I have more recently investigated (Feldstein, 1979a). My current view is that on balance monetary policy reduced the demand for business investment at the same time that it increased the demand for residential investment and for consumption goods. It is useful to contrast the conclusion of this section with the conventional Keynesian wisdom. According to the traditional view, monetary expansion

6 lowers interest rates which reduces the cost of funds to investors and therefore encourages the accumulation of plant and equipment. This statement is wrong in three ways. First, a sustained monetary expansion raises nominal interest rates. Second, although the interest rate ir higher, the real net of tax cost of funds is lower. And, third, the lower cost of funds produced in this way encourages investment in housing and consumer durables (as well as greater consumption in general) rather than more investment in plant and equipment. II. The Correct Mix of Monetary and Fiscal Policies There is widespread agreement on two central goals for macroeconomic policy: (1) achieving a level of aggregate demand that avoids both unemployment and inflation, and (2) increasing the share of national income that is devoted to business investment. Monetary and fiscal policy provide two instruments with which to achieve these two goals. The traditional view of the effect of monetary policy has led to the conventional prescription of easy money (to encourage investment) and a tight fiscal policy (to limit demand). This policy mix could in principle achieve its two goals. A government surplus would permit a reduction in the supply of government liabilities (money and bonds) and would thereby facilitate increased capital accumulation. The required change in the interest rate would depend on the relative interest sensitivities of the market demand for bonds and money. In the likely case in which the demand for money is relatively inelastic, the government surplus must be accompanied by a lower rate of interest and the substitution of real capital for government bonds..2

7 Unfortunately, the traditional prescription of easy money and a tight fiscal position is almost bound to fail in practice because of the political difficulty of achieving and maintaining a government surplus. During the past twenty years, there have not been any two successive years in which the federal government budget shoved a surplus. As a result, the pursuit of an easy money policy has produced inflation. Although..ne inflationary increase in the money supply did reduce the real after tax cost of funds, this only diverted the flow of capital away from investment in plant and equipment and into owner occupied housing and consumer durables. By reducing the real net return to savers, the reduced the total amount of new saving. easy money policy has probably also The inappropriateness of the traditional policy mix reflects not only its overoptimistic view about the feasibility of government surpluses but also its overly narrow conception of the role of fiscal policy. In the current macroeconomic tradition, fiscal policy has been almost synonymous with variations in the net government surplus or deficit the potentially powerful incentive effects of taxes and has generally ignored that influence marginal prices. A more appropriate policy mix for achieving the dual goals of balanced demand and increased business investment would combine a tight money policy and fiscal incentives for investment and saving. A tight money policy would prevent inflation and would raise the real net rate of interest. Although the higher real rate of interest would tend to deter all forms of investment, specific incentives for investment in plant and equipment could more than offset the higher cost of funds. The combination of the higher real net interest rate and

8 the targeted investment incentives would restrict housing construction and the purchase of consumer durables while increasing the flow of capital into new plant and equipment. Since housing and consumer durables now account for substantially more than half of the private capital stock, such a restructuring of the investment mix could have a substantial favorable effect on the stock of plant and equipment. A rise in the overall saving rate would permit a greater increase in business investment. The higher real net rate of interest would in itself tend to induce such a higher rate of saving. This could be supplemented by explicit fiscal policies that reduced the tax rate on interest income and other income from saving. Switching from an easy money policy to a policy mix with high real interest rates would have a further advantage. Because of the current system of floating exchange rates, a rise in the real interest rate would cause an appreciation of the dollar which would in turn reduce the price level directly (see e.g., Dornbusch and Krugman, 1977). With less than perfect international capital mobility, higher interest rates could persist and would tend to attract some inflow of foreign capiti that would further augment investment in the United States. III. Macroeconomic Importance of the Fiscal Structure The misjudgement of monetary tightness and the advocacy of an inappropriate policy mix suggest the importance of recognizing that the fiscal structure of our econonr is a key determinant of the macroeconomic equilibrium and therefore of the effect of monetary policy. Conventional

9 macroeconomic analyses that ignore the fiscal structure (or that assume that all taxes are equivalent to lump suni taxes) can be seriously misleading.3 The fact that the real interest rate can simultaneously rise on a pretax basis and fall on a net of tax basis shows that fiscal efects with the existing U.S. tax law are qualitatively as well as quantitatively important. The common tendency to ignore the tax structure in macroeconomic analysis is due at least in part to the fact that taxes were much less important at the time that the current nxdels of macroeconomic analysis were developed. When Keynes' General Theory was first published, less than five percent of American families were affected by the income tax and the median tax rate among those who paid tax was less than five percent. The greater current significance of the the fiscal structure reflects not only the growth of the income tax but also the increased importance of social insurance programs like unemployment insurance and social security. The tax structure is particularly important as a cause of the macroeconomic non neutrality of inflation. Irving Fisherts (1930) famous conclusion that inflation raises the nominal interest rate but leaves the real rate unchanged is appropriate for an economy with no taxes but not for an economy in which nominal interest payments are reflected in income and profits that are subject to substantial marginal tax rates. I have shown elsewhere (Feldstein, 19T6) that in an economy with economic depreciation and a 50 percent tax rate,

10 each on percent increased in the inflation rate raises the nominal interest rate by two percent. With other depreciation rules, the effect of the inflation rate on the interest rate can be more than one to one or less than one to one (Feldstein, Green and Sheshinski, 1978). More generally, the tax structure determines how inflation influences the real values of corporate equities (Feidstein, 1978b, 1979a and Hendershott, 1979) of residential real estate (Hendershott and Hu, 1979), and of such "store of value" assets as land and gold (Feldstein, 1979b). As Hartrnan (1979) has shown, the tax rules may also induce international capital flows in response to changes in inflation that would have no real effect in the absence of taxation. IV. Some Conclusions This paper has emphasized the importance of the fiscal structure as a determinant of the macroeconomic equilibrium. It discussed the desirability of substituting a policy of tight money and positive fiscal incentives for the traditional goals of easy money and fiscal restraint. More specifically, it identified the failure to recognize the effects of the tax rules as an important reason for the mismanagement of monetary policy. Although the guidance of shortrun monetary policy may now give more weight to controlling the money supply and credit aggregates, interest rates will almost certainly continue to influece the determination of longer term monetary policy. The correct interpretation of the relation between interest rates and inflation therefore remains important and will become even more important if the authorities attempt to shift to a policy of tighter money and an altered tax structure.

11 Bibliography Boskin, Michael, J.,, "Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of Interest," Journal of Political Economy, 86, No. 2, Part 2 (April 1978), S3-S27. Dornbusch, Rudiger and P. Krugman, "Flexible Exchange Rates in the Short Run," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 1976, 537-584. Feldstein, Martin, "Inflation, Income Taxes and the Rate of Interest: Theoretical Analysis," American Economic Rev3w, Vol. 66, No. 5, December 1966, 809-820. "The Rate of Return, Taxation, and Personal Saving," Economic Journal, Vol.88, No. 351, September, l978a, 482-487. "Inflation and the Stock Market," American Economic Review, (1978b), "Inflation, Tax Rules, and the Stock Market," NBER Working Paper Series, No. 403 (1979a). "The Effect of Inflation on the Prices of Land and Gold," NBER Working Paper Series, No. 296 (l979b). "Fiscal Policies, Inflation and Capital Formation," American Economic Review, (1980)., J. Green and E. Sheshinski, "Inflation and Taxes in a Growing Economy with Debt and Equity Finance," Journal of Political Economy, 86, No. 2, Part 2 (April 1978), S53-S70. and L. Summers, "Inflation, Tax Rules and the Long-Term Interest Rate," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1978, 61-100. "Inflation and the Taxation of Capital Income in the Corporate Sector," National Tax Journal, forthcoming. Hartinan, David, "Taxation and tie Effects of Inflation on the Real Capital Stock in an Open Economy," International Economic Review, Vol.20, No.2, June 1979, 417-425.

12 Hendershott, Patric, "The Decline in Aggregate Share Values: Inflation and Taxation of the Returns from Equities and Owlier-Occupied Housing," NBER Working Paper Series, No. 370, 1979. and Sheng Cheng Hu, "Inflation and the Benefits from Owner- Occupied Housing," NBER Working Paper Series, No. 383, 1979. Summers, Lawrence H., "Tax Policy in a Life Cycle Model," NBER Working Paper Series, No. 302, 1978, and American Economic Review, forthcoming.

13 Footnotes * Harvard University and the National Bureau of Economic Research. This paper will be presented at the annual meeting of the American Economic Association on December 28, 1979. The views expressed here are the authorts and should not be attributed to any organization. 1Although the response of household saving to even a compensated change in the interest rate is theoretically ambiguous (Feldstein, 1978A), plausible parameter values and some econometric evdence support a positive saving elasticity (Boskin, 1978; Summers, 1979). 2See Feldstein (1980) for a formal model of the relation of fiscal policy, monetary policy and capital formation in a fully employed economy. 3lgnoring the tax structure is analagous to ignoring the international aspects of domestic economic equilibrium; there are issues for which both taxes and international aspects can be ignored but there are others for which doing so would be very inappropriate.