The Case for Tax Sparing Along with Expanding and Limiting the Subpart F Regime

Similar documents
TAX INCENTIVES OFFERED BY DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: ATTRACTING FOREIGN INVESTMENT OR CREATING DISASTER

Why Y? Reflections on the Baucus Proposal

SUPPLEMENTAL MATERIALS FOR

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC.

VIVE LA PETITE DIFFERENCE: CAMP, OBAMA, AND TERRITORIALITY RECONSIDERED

20 Tax Executives Institute

TAXATION OF FOREIGN INVESTORS IN LITHUANIA

December 6, The Honorable Paul Ryan Speaker U.S. House of Representatives H-232 The Capitol Washington, DC Dear Speaker Ryan:

International Competitiveness, Tax Incentives, and a New Argument for Tax Sparing: Preventing Double Taxation by Crediting Implicit Taxes

PENSION & BENEFITS! T he cross-border transfer of employees can have A BNA, INC. REPORTER

TAXATION AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER: KEY ISSUES

October 9, Re: REG Relating to the Proposed Regulations under Section 965

U.S. Tax Legislation Corporate and International Provisions. Corporate Law Provisions

1500 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW 1111 Constitution Avenue, NW Washington, D.C Washington, D.C

U.S. Tax Reform: The Current State of Play

Back from the Dead: How to Revive Transfer Pricing Enforcement

Volume Title: International Taxation and Multinational Activity. Volume URL:

IRS Issues a Warning to Canadian Law Firms with U.S. Branch Offices

Chapter URL:

Swimming Upstream? Subpart F and FTC Considerations in Upstream Oil and Gas Activities

THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION JOANN M. WEINER * & HUGH J. AULT **

AN INTERNATIONAL TAX SYSTEM FOR EMERGING ECONOMIES, TAX SPARING, AND DEVELOPMENT: IT IS ALL ABOUT SOURCE!

ARNOLD PORTER LLP. Special Edition: International Provisions of the American Jobs Creation Act. Overview INTERNATIONAL TAX HEADLINES DECEMBER 2004

The EU draft anti-avoidance directive (ATAD) A focus on CFC rules from a Swiss perspective

COMMENT ON GRUBERT AND NEWLON, THE INTERNATIONAL IMPLI- CATIONS OF CONSUMP- TION TAX PROPOSALS REUVEN S. AVI-YONAH *

PENSION RIGHTS CENTER

KPMG report: Initial impressions, proposed regulations implementing anti-hybrid provisions of new tax law

International. Contact us to learn more about our International Tax practice. Partnering With Our Colleagues. U.S. corporate tax directors and

NEW ZEALAND HONG KONG CEP DISCUSSION PAPER SUBMISSION BY BUSINESS NEW ZEALAND MAY 2001

Chairman Camp s Discussion Draft of Tax Reform Act of 2014 and President Obama s Fiscal Year 2015 Revenue Proposals

Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in Open Economies

2017 Tax Reform: Checkpoint Special Study on foreign income, foreign persons tax changes in the "Tax Cuts and Jobs Act"

Comments on Revised Discussion Draft on BEPS Action 6: Prevent Treaty Abuse

MANAGING INTERNATIONAL TAX ISSUES

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation

Report released by top US Senate Finance Committee Republican calls for international tax reform

U.S. Tax Reform: The Current State of Play

Double Taxation Relief

Comparison and Assessment of the Tax Treatment of Foreign Source Income in Canada, Australia, France, Germany and the United States

International Tax: Strategies for cross-border investing after tax reform

A Comparison of the Merger and Acquisition Provisions of Present Law with the Provisions in the Senate Finance Committee's Draft Bill

THE DIFFICULTIES WITH THE SUBPART F SYSTEM OF INTERNATIONAL TAXATION: HOW THE SCHERING- PLOUGH

State aid and distortion of competition

Advisory. International Tax. Special Alert. International Provisions of the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (the JOBS Act )

New Zealand s International Tax Review

OECD issues Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS)

Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L )

Territorial Tax Study Report

U.S. Tax Reform International Corporate Tax Provisions: The Good, the Bad and the Extremely Complex

Changes Abound in New Tax Bill for Multinational Companies

r u c h e l m a n IMPACT OF THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT ON U.S. INVESTORS IN FOREIGN CORPORATIONS A NEW TAX REGIME FOR C.F.C. S: WHO IS G.I.L.T.I.?

T he relatively strong U.S. economy continues to attract

CHILE GLOBAL GUIDE TO M&A TAX: 2017 EDITION

Moving to a (Properly Designed) Territorial System of Taxation Will Make America s Tax System Internationally Competitive

U.S. TAX REFORM TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT December 5, 2017

Foreign Derived Intangible Income ( FDII ) Provision Mechanics, Issues, and Potential WTO or Other Challenges. November 2, 2018

New Tax Law: International

Bill of Tax Amendments for 2014 approved by the Lower House of the Mexican Congress

Divisional Reporting by Diversified Corporations: An Accountant's View

UNITED STATES * 4:17-MC-1557 * Houston, Texas VS. * * 10:33 a.m. JOHN PARKS TROWBRIDGE * September 13, 2017

Taxation of International Transactions

U.S. Tax Reform Legislative Updates

International Tax. Environments. Chapter Outline. Tax Neutrality INTERNATIONAL INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT

Canada: Limitation on the Elimination of Double Taxation Under the Canada-Brazil Income Tax Treaty

Captive insurance companies ( captives ) allow taxpayers with large risk exposures

United States Tax Alert

Notice 98-5, CB 334--IRC Sec(s). 42

Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 International Tax Provisions and Provisions Affecting Exempt Organizations

Report for Congress. Firms That Incorporate Abroad for Tax Purposes: Corporate Inversions and Expatriation. Updated January 30, 2003

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Is Foreign Direct Investment Sensitive to Taxes?

Exploitation of US Intellectual Property Rights in Ireland

International Tax Impact of Business Entity Selection for Foreign Operations of U.S. Companies

63200 Federal Register / Vol. 83, No. 235 / Friday, December 7, 2018 / Proposed Rules

SENATE TAX REFORM PROPOSAL INTERNATIONAL

International Income Taxation Chapter 13: DIRECT INVESTMENT ABROAD

New United States-Japan Tax Treaty Enters Into Force: New Withholding Rates Take Effect on July 1, 2004

Temporary and Proposed Regulations Under Section 883

The implications of US tax reform

SALE OF AN INTEREST BY A FOREIGN PARTNER IS REV. RUL BASED ON LAW OR ADMINISTRATIVE WISHES?

US Tax Reform For Canadian Companies

CHOICE OF ENTITY FOR INTERNATIONAL OPERATIONS AFTER THE 2017 TAXACT

CONFERENCE AGREEMENT PROPOSAL INTERNATIONAL

Consequences Of EU's Belgium Tax Scheme Decision

US Corporate Taxation

International tax implications of US tax reform

Should Retirees Still Consider Expatriating?

April 11, RE: NAM Comments on International Tax Reform Discussion Draft. Dear Chairman Camp:

WELCOME TO OUR WEBINAR

OFFSHORE CAPTIVE TAX AND REGULATORY CONSIDERATIONS. Angela J. Walitt, Partner Baker & McKenzie LLP February 13, 2017

SENATE TAX REFORM PROPOSAL INTERNATIONAL

International Law Firms in China: Market Access and Ethical Risks

PRACTICAL U.S. / DOMESTIC TAX STRATEGIES

Partnerships and the Foreign Affiliate Regime

A Transfer Pricing Update BEPS & U.S. Tax Reform

Back to the Future? The Potential Revival of Territoriality

Tax Cuts & Jobs Act: The Road to Reform Reform Results of Reform

Taxing Income Across International Borders. A Policy Framework

Abstract. Standard formulary apportionment, as currently adopted by states which impose a corporate level

Testimony of David Balto, Senior Fellow, Center for American Progress

COMMENTS ON TEMPORARY AND PROPOSED REGULATIONS GOVERNING ALLOCATION OF PARTNERSHIP EXPENDITURES FOR FOREIGN TAXES (T.D. 9121; REG )

Transcription:

Penn State Law elibrary Journal Articles Faculty Works 1-1-2003 The Case for Tax Sparing Along with Expanding and Limiting the Subpart F Regime Samuel C. Thompson Jr. Penn State Law Follow this and additional works at: http://elibrary.law.psu.edu/fac_works Part of the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation Samuel C. Thompson Jr., The Case for Tax Sparing Along with Expanding and Limiting the Subpart F Regime, 35 Geo. Wash. Int'l L. Rev. 303 (2003). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Works at Penn State Law elibrary. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of Penn State Law elibrary. For more information, please contact ram6023@psu.edu.

THE CASE FOR TAX SPARING ALONG WITH EXPANDING AND LIMITING THE SUBPART F REGIME SAMUEL C. THOMPSON, JR.* I. INTRODUCTION I am particularly happy to participate in this important conference at The George Washington University School of Law. I feel as though I am caught in the middle of bipolar, policy approaches to international tax, championed by two outstanding George Washington Law School professors of international tax, Professor Robert Peroni and Professor Karen Brown. Professor Peroni has argued persuasively that the United States should end deferral, a policy under which U.S.-controlled foreign corporations (CFCs) are generally not subject to U.S. taxation until the earnings are distributed, essentially by adopting the partnership model for taxing the foreign source income of CFCs. 1 On the other hand, Professor Brown has made compelling arguments for the adoption of an exemption system for investment in developing countries (DCs), particularly those in Africa. 2 Under an exemption system, CFCs would not be subject to taxation in the United States, either at the time that foreign income is earned or at the time that such income is repatriated. Professor Brown's proposed exemption system would have an effect similar to that of a tax sparing policy. Under a tax sparing policy, pursuant to a treaty, for foreign tax credit purposes, the United States would treat CFCs as having paid the full foreign tax on foreign income, even though the income is subject to a lower tax pursuant to a tax holiday. The George Washington University School of Law is, indeed, privileged to have these two outstanding international tax scholars on its faculty. This Symposium is also privileged to host Professor Paul McDaniel, the author of an important and excellent paper * Professor and Director of the Center for the Study of Mergers and Acquisitions at the UCLA School of Law. I would like to thank Robert Clary, II, a third year student at the University of Miami School of Law and Ellis Green, my assistant at the UCLA School of Law, for their assistance in the preparation of this Article. 1. See, e.g., Robert J. Peroni, Deferral of U.S. Tax on International Income: End It, Don't Mend It-Why Should We Be Stuck in the Middle with Subpart F?, 79 TEXAS L. REV. 1609 (2001). 2. See, e.g., Karen B. Brown, Missing Africa: Should U.S. International Tax Rules Accommodate Investment in Developing Countries?, 23 U. PA. J. INT'L. ECON. L. 45 (2002).

The Geo. Wash. Int'l L. Rev. [Vol. 35 entitled The U.S. Tax Treatment of Foreign Source Income Earned in Developing Countries. 3 I am, indeed, honored to have the opportunity to offer the following comments on Professor McDaniel's Article and to set forth my views on both the need for reform of the Subpart F regime and on the advisability of the adoption by the U.S. Treasury of a tax sparing policy. This Article proceeds as follows: Part II provides a brief comment on the current deferral system; Part III addresses the economic case for a tax sparing policy; Part IV provides a brief examination of Professor McDaniel's policy options; and Part V sets out the author's policy prescription. II. COMMENT ON THE CURRENT DEFERRAL SYSTEM I would like to start with a comment on the economic effect of the current system of deferral. Professor McDaniel claims that the current U.S. system prevents DCs from offering tax incentives, like tax holidays, to attract foreign direct investment (FDI).4 I have a small quibble with this statement, a quibble that goes to the heart of the deferral concept. I believe that his characterization is a bit too broad because, under the current deferral system for active income, tax incentives will provide an advantage as long as the income is not repatriated. As Professor McDaniel points out, longterm deferral approximates the benefits of exemption because of the lack of an interest charge on the deferral benefit. I believe that it is fair to say that the current deferral system is not, in and of itself, enough to encourage investment in DCs, even with substantial tax incentives. Subject to the Subpart F inclusion rules, the current deferral regime is available for CFCs wherever the foreign investment exists; therefore, the current deferral regime does not offer a greater incentive for investment in DCs than does investment in developed countries that offer tax incentives. Finally, it is important to remember that the deferral regime applies not just to tax holidays; it also applies to any situation in which the foreign corporate tax rate is lower than the U.S. corporate tax rate, such as with Ireland's 10% corporate tax rate. 3. Paul R. McDaniel, The U.S. Tax Treatment of Foreign Source Income Earned in Developing Countries: A Policy Analysis, 35 GEo. WASH. INT'L L. REV. 265 (2003). 4. Id.

2003] The Case for Tax Sparing III. THE EFFECTIVENESS OF TAX SPARING FOR THE ATTRACTION OF FDI IN DCs In addressing the question of whether tax sparing benefits or other incentives should be made available to DCs, it seems that the first issue is whether it is important for a DC to be concerned about the level of its inbound FDI. I believe that the answer is a resounding "Yes." For example, the 1998 article, How Does Foreign Investment Affect Economic Growth, cited by Professor McDaniel, firmly establishes that FDI contributes to economic growth. The authors, Borensztein, Gregorio and Lee, point out that: [o] ur results suggest that FDI is in fact an important vehicle for the transfer of technology, contributing to growth in larger measure than domestic investment... [T]here is a strong complimentary effect between FDI and human capital... Our results are supportive of a crowding-in effect, that is, a one-dollar increase in the net inflow of FDI is associated with an increase in total investment in the host country of more than one dollar. 5 This is a logical conclusion and it would appear that any rational finance minister, especially a finance minister in a DC, must be concerned with attracting FDI. Indeed, this was my personal experience while working, on behalf of the U.S. Treasury Department, as the Tax Policy Advisor to the Ministry of Finance in South Africa from 1999 to 2000. Thus, I think that it is crystal clear that FDI is an important element in the economic growth strategies of many DCs. The next question is whether either tax sparing benefits or a selective exemption system for DCs, like the one proposed by Professor Brown, could be effective in attracting FDI. Professor McDaniel cites the 1998 article by Hines, Tax Sparing and Direct Investment in Developing Countries, finding that tax sparing benefits are effective in stimulating FDI. 6 For example, Hines writes: [t] he results indicate that "tax sparing" is effective in stimulating FDI. Japanese firms locate a much higher fraction of their foreign investment in countries with whom Japan has tax sparing agreements than do American firms. Furthermore, host governments appear to grant Japanese firms significant tax reductions that are not available to their American counterparts. All other things equal, tax sparing agreements are associated with 140% to 240% higher FDI levels and 23% lower tax rates on FDI. 7 Further, it seems logical to conclude that the significant reductions in tax that can result from tax sparing would be effective in 5. Id. at 117-18. 6. james R. Hines, Jr., "Tax Sparing" and Direct Investment in Developing Countries, 1998 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES 1, available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w6728. 7. Id. at 3.

The Geo. Wash. Int'l L. Rev. [Vol. 35 attracting FDI. I believe that the previously mentioned economic studies of the effectiveness of FDI and tax sparing lead to some important conclusions. First, the adoption by the United States of a tax sparing policy, or similar selective exemption policy, as proposed by Professor Brown, would likely increase the amount of U.S. source FDI flowing to a host DC that received the benefits of such a policy. Second, this increased FDI would likely increase the rate of domestic investment and economic growth in the host DC. IV. AN ExAMINATION OF PROFESSOR MCDANIEL'S POLICY OPTIONS Given this background, let me turn to an examination of the various policy options analyzed by Professor McDaniel in his Article. 8 I will begin by noting those points as to which Professor McDaniel and I reasonably agree at certain levels. Specifically, I will address the reduction of U.S. corporate tax on income earned in DCs, the relaxation of Subpart F rules, and the modification of Section 482. First, Professor McDaniel concludes that reducing the U.S. corporate tax on income earned in DCs is unlikely to be more effective than an exemption system. Although I do not support this type of policy approach, it would appear that such an approach could be designed to reach the same or similar result to that provided by tax sparing or an exemption system. Second, I agree with Professor McDaniel's finding that a relaxation of the Subpart F rules for investment in DCs would not likely be effective. This type of policy would unlikely increase economic growth in DCs and would permit DCs to be used as mere tax havens for economic activity occurring in other countries. Third, I agree with Professor McDaniel's conclusion that modifying the Section 482 transfer pricing rules for investment in DCs is not an appropriate policy. In addition to violating the WTO, such an approach would unlikely increase economic growth in DCs. Below, I will address those of Professor McDaniel's contentions with which I take issue, including the exemption system, tax sparing, and the suggestion of increased official development aid (ODA). A. Exemption System Professor McDaniel argues that an exemption system for investment in DCs is unlikely to increase FDI flowing into DCs, so long as the current, U.S.-modified worldwide system (i.e., the CFC regime) 8. McDaniel, supra note 3, at 285-94.

2003] The Case for Tax Sparing is in effect. I think that his conclusion is inconsistent with findings in the Borensztein, Gregorio and Lee study discussed in Part IV on the effect of tax sparing on FDI. '- Although I am not aware of any studies on the effect of a selective exemption system on FDI, Hines' Tax Sparing study seems to logically apply to a selective exemption system. It is noteworthy, however, that if the United States were to adopt a generalized exemption system for all FDI, as has been proposed recently by some international tax professionals, so that the exemption applied without respect to the location of the investment, then I would agree that such a system would unlikely be effective in attracting FDI to DCs. Although, as indicated below, I recommend the adoption of a selective tax sparing system, I do not support a generalized exemption system for investment in DCs. B. Tax Sparing Approach Professor McDaniel opposes a tax sparing approach. He argues that there are many obstacles to this approach, including the following: (1) general ineffectiveness; (2) the inability of DCs to implement exchange of information agreements and source rules; (3) the limited resources in the Treasury's International Tax Counsel's (ITC) office; and (4) the complexity associated with such a system. I will address each of these concerns in turn. First, I think Professor McDaniel's conclusion regarding the effectiveness of tax sparing is inconsistent with the previously discussed findings concerning the relationship between FDI and tax sparing. Second, as I will propose below, tax sparing should only be available to those DCs that can properly implement information exchange agreements and otherwise provide proper administration of the tax system. Based on my experience serving as the Tax Policy Advisor to the Ministry of Finance in South Africa, I also believe that the United States could help these DCs dramatically improve their tax systems. If the United States were to adopt a tax sparing policy for DCs that adhere to principles of good government, the DCs would both be able to and have an incentive to comply with their information exchange obligations. My experience in South Africa leads me to conclude that many DCs would welcome our assistance in this regard. Third, regarding Professor McDaniel's point on a lack of resources, certainly, if the U.S. decided to adopt a tax sparing policy, it could find the resources to enhance the ITC office so that we 9. Id. at 283.

The Geo. Wash. Int'l L. Rev. [Vol. 35 could implement an effective tax sparing policy. The same is true of a selective exemption system. Fourth, I believe that Professor McDaniel's position on the complexity of a tax sparing regime is one that essentially ignores the finding of the Hines study regarding the Japanese system. Clearly, if the Japanese can adopt an effective tax sparing policy, the United States can do the same. Finally, although the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) is opposed to what it refers to as "Harmful Tax Competition,"" ' a recent study by the OECD is quite balanced in its assessment of tax sparing.i l For example, the report concludes: "The analysis of this report does not suggest that OECD and other countries which have traditionally granted tax sparing should necessarily cease to do so."12 The report goes on to urge countries that employ tax sparing to "achieve a better targeting of the provisions and to reduce the potential for abuse."' 13 C. Suggestion for More ODA As an alternative to providing tax incentives for investment in DCs, Professor McDaniel suggests increasing ODA. This suggestion is consistent with United Nations proposals that each developed country devote 0.7 percent of its GNP to ODA. 14 I agree that there should be more ODA, and the United States' current contribution is much too low, at 0.2 percent of GNP, or $4 per taxpayer. But the political scene in the U.S. makes a substantial increase in ODA unlikely. Although ODA clearly should be increased, it is also true that U.S. companies may earn substantial benefits by investing, through properly targeted and focused tax sparing agreements, in active business operations in DCs. As indicated above, there is economic evidence that an increase in FDI increases economic growth. Accordingly, I do not think that an obvious need for an increase in ODA can be used as a basis for not supporting a properly structured tax sparing policy. 10. ORGANIZATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT, HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION: AN EMERGING GLOBAL ISSUE 7 (1998). 11. ORGANIZATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT, TAX SPARING: A RECONSIDERATION (1998). 12. Id. at 42. 13. Id. 14. See generally McDaniel, supra note 3, at 278-79.

2003] The Case for Tax Sparing V. MY POLICY PRESCRIPTIONS In this section, I begin by outlining the reasons why I think we should retain the current deferral system and not adopt Professor Peroni's anti-deferral regime, which is fundamentally inconsistent with providing any type of tax incentives for investment in DCs. Second, I address changes in the current Subpart F regime for CFCs that I think are needed, even if a tax sparing approach is adopted. Finally, I provide the general structure of a targeted and focused tax sparing program that could be implemented through the Treasury's treaty policy. This tax sparing program would not apply to income otherwise subject to taxation under the Subpart F regime, as proposed to be modified here. A. Continuation of the Present Deferral System Although I see the logic in ending deferral along the lines proposed by Professor Peroni, I believe that such a policy may run the risk of hurting competitiveness of U.S. firms. For example, assume that a U.S. firm is competing for an industrial project in a foreign country that has a corporate tax rate below the U.S. rate or in a foreign country that is offering a tax holiday for the project. Also assume that the foreign competitors for the project are located in countries that have exemption systems. Under the anti-deferral regime proposed by Professor Peroni, the U.S. firm is at a tax disadvantage. Under the current deferral system, the U.S. firm is on the same footing as the foreign competitors at the time the income is earned and as long as the income is reinvested and not repatriated. If the income is reinvested for a significant period, the deferral facilitates an effect like that of exemption, thus reducing the competitive advantage of the foreign competitor. With proper planning, repatriation of the income may be done at a time when other high taxed foreign income is repatriated, thereby using cross-crediting, under the foreign tax credit rules, that generates the same effect as an exemption system. This demonstrates that the current deferral system already addresses many of the concerns that the Nation Foreign Trade Council (NFTC) and others have expressed with competitiveness.' 5 I would thus retain our current deferral system with the modifications suggested below. 15. Basically, the argument is that the current CFC regime puts U.S. firms doing business in foreign markets at a competitive disadvantage relative to their foreign competitors that are located in countries without CFC regimes. See alho NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INTERNATIONAL TAX POLICY FOR THE 21sT CENTURY (Dec. 15, 2001).

The Geo. Wash. Int'l L. Rev. [Vol. 35 B. Expansion of and Limitation on the Subpart F Regime I would both expand and limit the current Subpart F regime, pursuant to which the Subpart income of CFCs is currently imputed to certain controlling U.S. shareholders, thus denying the benefits of deferral. In order to take pressure off of the Section 482 transfer pricing rules, which are complex and difficult to administer, I would offer two suggestions. First, I would expand the definition of Subpart F income for outbound sales from U.S. parents to their CFCs. Second, I would consider limiting the definition of Subpart F income for foreign to foreign sales transactions, pursuant to which such income arises on sales by one CFC to a sister CFC where the sister sells the product outside of the country in which the sister is incorporated.' 6 First, with respect to outbound sales, the Subpart F regime should be expanded to include within foreign base company sales income (FBCSI) 1 7 and, therefore, Subpart F Income, all outbound sales by U.S. parent corporations (and their controlled U.S. subsidiaries) to their CFCs. This rule should apply without respect to where the product is resold by the CFC. Under the current definition of FBCSI, such transactions produce FBCSI only if the sale takes place outside of the country in which the CFC is incorporated. Under this proposal, for example, FBCSI would include income realized on the CFC's purchase of property from its U.S. parent and from the sale by the CFC of the property in the country of its incorporation. Presently, such income is not included in FBCSI because of the requirement that the sale take place outside of the country of incorporation of the CFC. This proposed extension of the FBCSI rules would take pressure off of Section 482 in the outbound context, while preserving deferral for real business activity in foreign countries, thus addressing the basic concern with competitiveness. Second, with respect to the foreign to foreign Subpart F provisions, consideration should be given to relaxing these rules to the extent that there is no Section 482 issue. This would address the essential competitiveness concerns set out in the NFTC Study. 16. Samuel C. Thompson Jr., A Critical Perspective on the Thomas Bill, 96 TAX NOTES 581 (2002) (presenting similar suggestions for expanding and limiting the Subpart F regime); see also Samuel C. Thompson Jr., Inversion Hearings Focus on Wrong Issues, 27 TAx NOTES INT'L 193 (2002). 17. I.R.C. 954(a)(2) (2000).

2003] The Case for Tax Sparing C. Adoption of a Focused Tax Sparing Regime I would adopt a focused tax sparing program for investment in certain DCs. The Treasury treaty program would implement the system with benefits that would apply only to active income earned in the applicable DC. The system would not apply to income earned from sales of property between the U.S. parent and the foreign subsidiary, i.e., income that would give rise to FBCSI under the proposed modification discussed above or to any other type of Subpart F income. Therefore, tax sparing would not apply to sales of property that would otherwise be subject to Section 482. The U.S. Treasury would also limit tax sparing benefits to those countries that meet certain minimum standards, including: (1) a commitment to basic democratic principles; (2) a commitment to basic human rights protections; (3) an effective tax system and information exchange program; (4) an adoption of good corporate governance principles; (5) compliance with environmental best practices; (6) compliance with basic labor law principles; (7) an adoption of anti-corruption policies, and (8) the satisfaction of other good government principles. The Treasury would consult with other branches of government in determining if the relevant parties satisfied all eight conditions. Thus, that benefits of this provision would only be available for those DCs that practiced good government principles, and it would be a carrot attracting commitments to good government. The following example illustrates the basic operation of this type of system. Assume that tax sparing benefits are extended by treaty to country DCX and that GM, a U.S. corporation, sets up, in DCX, an auto-manufacturing subsidiary, GMX. GMX makes no purchases of products from GM that would generate FBCSI under the rules suggested above, and GMX has no other Subpart F income. GMX manufactures the automobiles that are sold in DCX. The corporate tax rate in DCX is generally 35%; however, pursuant to a tax holiday for a period of ten years, DCX imposes a tax rate of only 10% on the income earned by GMX. For the current year, GMX has $100M of taxable income and pays $10M of income tax to DCX. When GM repatriates the $90M of after tax income from GMX, GM would not be subject to taxation on the $90M because, under the tax sparing principle, the income is deemed to have incurred a 35% corporate tax rate in DCX. Thus, the economic effect of conferring tax sparing benefits is the same as an exemption for the income earned by GMX in DCX. Without this system, assuming that GM's only foreign income was the

The Geo. Wash. Int'l L. Rev. [Vol. 35 amount repatriated, under the indirect foreign tax credit provisions in Section 902, GM would then be subject to a tax of $25M on the repatriated amount, i.e., the difference between the 10% rate in DCX and the 35% U.S. rate.' 8 This approach is consistent with the competitiveness concept, because it would offer U.S. firms doing business in such countries the same or similar benefits as those received by competing foreign firms that also benefit from tax sparing. Further, this concept can be justified on efficiency grounds. By promoting economic growth in DCs, this concept is likely to enhance long-term economic efficiency. Concededly, the distortion in investment decisions that this type of policy would encourage through its reduction in shortterm worldwide welfare, might hurt economic efficiency. The policy is, however, likely to promote long tern economic efficiency, because it helps DCs in growing their economies more effectively. The accelerating economic growth of DCs will make worldwide welfare greater in the long run. VI. CONCLUSION The events of September 11, 2001 demonstrate that we cannot expect to live in prosperity while others live in abject poverty. Just as after World War II, when the United States wisely adopted policies to help rebuild the economies of Germany and Japan, it would be prudent for the United States to adopt policies to help build the economies of DCs. A focused tax sparing program could be a powerful tool in this economic building process, and it is clearly worth the effort to pursue this policy option on the basis outlined in this Comment. The tax sparing program proposed here should not be viewed, however, as a substitute for other forms of foreign assistance, such as ODA. My proposal for a focused tax sparing program is not inconsistent with my support for anti-inversion legislation, which would prevent companies from unilaterally adopting a de facto territorial or exemption system of taxation through inversion transactions. 19 18. See, e.g., Damian Laurey, Reexamining U.S. Tax Sparing Policy with Developing Countries: The Merits of Falling in Line with International Norms, 30 VA. TAX REV. 467, 473-75 (2000). 19. Samuel C. Thompson Jr., Section 367: A 'Wimp' For Inversions and a 'Bully' For Real Cross- Border Acquisitions, 94 TAx NOTES 1505 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., IRC Section 367: A 'Wimp' for Inversions and a 'Bully' for Real Cross-Border Acquisitions, 26 TAX NoTEs brl'l 587 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson, Jr., Analysis of the Non-Wimpy Grassley-Baucus Inversion Bill, 26 TAx NOTES INT'i. 741 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., The Non-Wimpy Grassley/Baucus Inversion Bill, 95 TAx NOTES 1515 (2002); Samuel C.

20031 The Case for Tax Sparing While inversions undermine the current CFC regime on an ad hoc and arbitrary basis, the focused tax sparing program proposed here would be a judicious and carefully focused exception to the current system. Thompson, Jr., Treasury's Inversion Study Misses The Mark: Congress Should Shut Down Inversions Immediately, 26 TAX NOTES INT'L 969 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., Treasury's Inversion Study Misses the Mark, 95 TAX NOTES 1673 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., U.S. Treasury Official Gives Unconvincing Reason for Not 'Blockading' Inversions, 26 TAX NOTES INT'L 1321 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., Inversion Hearings Focus on Wrong Issues, 96 T,\x NOTES 154 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., Inversion Hearings Focus on Wrong Issues, 27 TAX NOTES INT'L 193 (2002); Samuel C. Thompson Jr., A Critical Perspective on the Thomas Bill, 96 TAx NOTES 581 (2002).