Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of Wealth Inequality

Similar documents
Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of. Wealth Inequality

Distribution of Wealth: Mechanisms

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WEALTH DISTRIBUTION AND SOCIAL MOBILITY IN THE US: A QUANTITATIVE APPROACH. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Wealth distribution and social mobility: A quantitative analysis of U.S. data

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Macroeconomic Models of Consumption, Saving, and Labor Supply

Wealth Returns Dynamics and Heterogeneity

Working paper series. Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo.

Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Distribution of Wealth: Mechanisms

Heterogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Household finance in Europe 1

Wealth Distribution. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. Econ821. February 9, / 25

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for the determinants of wealth concentration in the US

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE IMPLICATIONS OF RICHER EARNINGS DYNAMICS FOR CONSUMPTION AND WEALTH

The implications of richer earnings dynamics. for consumption, wealth, and welfare

Advanced Macroeconomic Theory I

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

The distribution of wealth and scal policy in economies with nitely lived agents

Online Appendix to The Dynamics of Inequality Xavier Gabaix, Jean-Michel Lasry, Pierre-Louis Lions, Benjamin Moll August 4, 2016

Earnings Inequality and Taxes on the Rich

The Historical Evolution of the Wealth Distribution: A Quantitative-Theoretic Investigation

Applying Generalized Pareto Curves to Inequality Analysis

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Age, Luck, and Inheritance

Macroeconomics and Inequality (Macro III)

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Limited Participation and Wealth Distribution

A Comprehensive Quantitative Theory of the U.S. Wealth Distribution

Macroeconomic Implications of Tax Cuts for the Top Income Groups:

NH Handbook of Income Distribution, volume 2B A.B. Atkinson and F.J. Bourguignon (Eds.) Chapter 15. Inequality in Macroeconomics

The distribution of wealth and scal policy in economies with nitely lived agents

Movements on the Price of Houses

Skewed Wealth Distributions: Theory and Empirics

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Skewed Wealth Distributions: Theory and Empirics

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

The Distribution of Wealth and the Marginal Propensity to Consume

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

During the last decade, most of the industrialized countries lived

Topics in Advanced Macroeconomics: Heterogeneity and Public Policy MIE7/PhD, Winter 2013/14

Wealth Distribution and Taxation. Frank Cowell: MSc Public Economics 2011/2

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

STUDIES ON EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF MA Title MODELS WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS

Wealth Returns Persistence and Heterogeneity

Pareto Distribution of Income in Neoclassical Growth Models

Continuous Time Bewley Models

Estate Taxation, Social Security and Annuity: the Trinity and Unity?

Family and Government Insurance: Wage, Earnings, and Income Risks in the Netherlands and the U.S.

About Capital in the 21 st Century

APPENDIX A: Income inequality literature review

USE IT OR LOSE IT: EFFICIENCY GAINS FROM WEALTH TAXATION

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

HOW IMPORTANT IS DISCOUNT RATE HETEROGENEITY FOR WEALTH INEQUALITY?

Inequality and Macroeconomics

Accounting for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth Inequality

Luxury Consumption, Precautionary Savings and Wealth Inequality

Nonlinear household earnings dynamics, self-insurance, and welfare

Higher Taxes at the Top: The Role of Entrepreneurs

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

On the Distribution of the Welfare Losses of Large Recessions

Topics in Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households and Firms

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HIGH MARGINAL TAX RATES ON THE TOP 1%? LESSONS FROM A LIFE CYCLE MODEL WITH IDIOSYNCRATIC INCOME RISK

Worker Betas: Five Facts about Systematic Earnings Risk

Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009.

The role of credit on wealth inequality in the USA:

On the Distribution of the Welfare Losses of Large Recessions

+1 = + +1 = X 1 1 ( ) 1 =( ) = state variable. ( + + ) +

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%?

Measuring the Trends in Inequality of Individuals and Families: Income and Consumption

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%?

Distributional Macroeconomics

Discussion: Accounting for Wealth Inequality Dynamics: Methods, Estimates and Simulations for France ( )

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

At any time, wages differ dramatically across U.S. workers. Some

Topics in Macroeconomics

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Inequality in 3-D: Income, Consumption, and Wealth

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

Measuring Wealth Inequality in Europe: A Quest for the Missing Wealthy

Fiscal Policy and MPC Heterogeneity

Do credit shocks matter for aggregate consumption?

Transcription:

Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of Wealth Inequality By Jess Benhabib, Alberto Bisin and Mi Luo I. Introduction Increasing income and wealth inequality has led to renewed interest in understanding and explaining wealth and income distributions, and in particular the recent growth in their top shares (Piketty, 2014). The literature has largely emphasized the role of earnings inequality in explaining wealth inequality. Indeed, Bewley-Aiyagari economies, which focus on precautionary savings as an optimal response to stochastic earnings, represent the most popular approach of introducing heterogeneity into a representative consumer framework to study the distribution of wealth (see Benhabib and Bisin, 2017, for a survey). However, models of earnings inequality and precautionary savings find it generally di cult to reproduce the thick righttail of the wealth distribution observed in the data. In particular, these models cannot reproduce wealth distributions with substantially thicker right-tails (larger top shares) than earnings distributions. But, while comparable estimates of the statistical properties of wealth and earnings distributions are available only for a few countries, they invariably show that thicker wealth tails are a critical and robust feature of data. Consider to-date estimates of the tail index, a measure of the rate of decay of the right-tail of a distribution and hence a measure which is inversely related to its thickness: 1 Wealth and earnings indices are, respectively, 1.48 1.55 and 2 in the U.S.; 1.63 1.85 and 3 in Sweden; and New York University, 19 W 4th, New York, NY 10012; jess.benhabib@nyu.edu, alberto.bisin@nyu.edu, mi.luo@nyu.edu. Thanks to Xavier Gabaix, Luigi Guiso, Alexis Toda for insightful comments and suggestions. 1 In the standard and simplest case of a Pareto distribution, whose cumulative is F (x) =1 mx a for x 2 x [x m, 1) andx m, >0, the tail index coincides with the exponent. For a survey of power laws in economics, see Gabaix (2016). 1 1.33 1.54 and 2 in Canada. 2 More specifically, in the context of Bewley-Aiyagari models, simulations tend to produce tail indices of wealth close to those of the distribution of labor earnings which has been fed into the the model. This is explicitly noted, for instance by Carroll, Slacalek and Tokuoka (2013). Similar results are obtained by De Nardi et al (2016), which argues that adopting the exceptional recently available earnings data from Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, and Song (2015) allows for a much better fit of the wealth distribution relative to the bottom 60% of agents, but generates too little wealth concentration at the top of the wealth distribution; and most recently by Hubmer, Krusell, and Smith (2017), which aptly concludes: the wealth distribution inherits not only the Pareto tail of the earnings distribution but also its Pareto coe cient. Because earnings are considerably less concentrated than wealth, the resulting tail in wealth is too thin to match the data [...]. Most importantly, in economic environments in which wealth accumulation is mainly driven by stochastic earnings, it is natural to expect a positive relationship between earnings and wealth inequality: higher earning risk tends to increase wealth accumulation via precautionary savings, thereby spreading the distribution which in turn, under borrowing constraints, tends to increase wealth inequality (Aiyagari, 1994). Interestingly, on the other hand, the cross-country data does not display a statistically significant correlation between inequality in earnings and wealth, indicating a significant role for other factors to drive the distribution of wealth. Consider Gini coe cients, the standard inequality measure (which can also be consid- 2 Wealth estimates: Vermeulen (2015), Table 8, for U.S.; Cowell (2011) for Canada and Sweden. Earnings estimates: Badel, Dayl, Huggett and Nybom (2016).

2 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR ered a proxy for the inverse of tail indices), reported in see Figure 1. Indeed, the slope coe cient from a linear regression of wealth Gini on earnings Gini is 0.258, not statistically significant with a standard error of 0.296. Though only suggestive due to the paucity of data, we consider this as additional evidence that earnings inequality does not adequately explain wealth inequality. II. A Theoretical Explanation A simple but deep theoretical result is useful to understand why it is di cult to reproduce important statistical properties of the wealth distribution which are observed in the data with earnings inequality and precautionary savings alone. Consider a linear individual wealth accumulation equation, (1) w t+1 = r t w t + y t c t ; where w t,y t,c t and r t are wealth, earnings, consumption and rate of return at time t. We may assume {y t,r t } are stationary stochastic processes. Consider also a linear consumption function, c t = w t + t. We can then write the wealth accumulation equation as (2) w t+1 =(r t ) w t +(y t t ). Suppose that r t and y t > 0 are both random variables, independent and i.i.d over time and independent of w t. Suppose also that t 0, 3 0 <E(r t ) < 1, and prob (r t >1) > 0 for any t 0. 4 The stationary distribution for w t can be characterized by applying a theorem due to Grey (1994), extending results of Kesten (1973), to (2). Theorem 1. Suppose y t t has a thick right-tail, with tail index > 0. If 3 Note that t will depend on the stochastic properties (i.e. the persistence and variance of its innovations) of the earnings process. 4 Some additional regularity conditions are required; see Benhabib, Bisin, Zhu (2011) for details. E (r t ) < 1, and E ((r t ) ) < 1 for some > >0, then the right-tail index of the stationary distribution of wealth will be. If instead E ((r t ) )=1for <,then the right-tail index of the stationary distribution of wealth will be. The Theorem makes clear that the righttail index of the wealth distribution induced by the accumulation equation, (2), is either, which depends on the stochastic properties of returns, or, the right-tail of y t t. With t 0 the right tail of y t t will be no thicker than that of than that of y t. 5 In other words, it is either stochastic returns via the the accumulation process or skewed earnings which determine the thickness of the right-tail of the wealth distribution, not both. Theorem 1 is of course obtained under very specific assumptions and, furthermore, pertains literally only to economies with linear consumption rules, that is, to very special microfoundations. Indeed infinitely-lived agent models with stochastic earnings and precautionary savings as in Aiyagari-Bewley economies generally display concave consumption functions. But assumptions can be substantially relaxed to allow for persistent (Markov-dependent) earning processes y t t, as well as for earnings and returns r t which are correlated (see Ghosh et al., 2010 and Roitershtein, 2007). Also, with Constant Relative Risk Aversion preferences, the consumption function in this class of models becomes linear at high wealth levels and the Theorem applies asymptotically (Benhabib, Bisin and Zhu, 2016, for a rigorous exposition and proofs). Moreover, linearity obtains in a larger class of Overlapping Generations Economies (Benhabib, Bisin and Zhu, 2011). Even when holding as an approximation, the result does clearly point to the potential di culty of matching the right-tail of wealth distribution by relying solely on earnings. First of all, since the distribution of wealth has a thicker tail than the dis- 5 This is because y t t is a left shift of the earnings density y t and if indeed it has a thick power tail, it must by its definition be decreasing in the right tail.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EARNINGS AND WEALTH INEQUALITY 3 Figure 1. Earnings and Wealth Gini Wealth Gini.55.6.65.7.75.8 Sweden Italy Canada Germany US Spain Russia UK.3.4.5.6 Earnings Gini Mexico Note: Wealth: Davies, Sandström, Shorrocks, and Wol (2011). Earnings: special issue of the Review of Economic Dynamics (2010), titled Cross-sectional facts for macroeconomists, edited by Krueger, Perri, Pistaferri, and Violante. tribution of earnings, Theorem 1 directly suggests that the distribution of earnings cannot by itself explain the thick tail of the wealth distribution. In fact, the implications of the Theorem are even more striking: the distribution of earnings cannot even partially contribute to explain the thickness of the tail of the wealth distribution; the burden for explaining the thick tails of wealth distribution will have to rely on other factors, like stochastic idiosyncratic returns on wealth r t. Second, if indeed it is other factors which are driving wealth inequality, then the lack of a a positive relationship between earnings and wealth inequality which we observe in the available cross-country data, Figure 1, is in fact not surprising at all. III. Further Empirical Considerations Theorem 1 also suggests an explanation why several studies which postulate extraordinarily high earnings states, originally to account for top-coding in earnings data, do in fact match the wealth distribution even if relying solely on earnings and precautionary savings as a determinant wealth accumulation. In fact, Theorem 1 suggests that, working with models in which earnings and precautionary savings are the main determinant of wealth accumulation, a much thicker distribution of earnings than the observed distribution is required to fit wealth data. This is exactly what the awesome state estimates, introduced with great success by Castañeda et al. (2003), e ectively achieve. More precisely, an awesome state is a state added to the observed stochastic process for earnings whose properties are estimated in order to better match the wealth distribution. Castañeda et al. (2003), in a rich overlapping-generation model with various demographic and life-cycle features, obtain estimates of the awesome state which requires the top 0.039% earners to have about 1, 000 times the average labor endowment of the bottom 61%. With the recent availability of earnings data which have not been top coded we can assess the reliability of this estimate. In fact, the ratio between even the top.01% and the median is at most of the order of 200 in the World Wealth and Income Database (WWID) by Alvaredo, Atkinson, Piketty, Saez, and Zucman (since 2011). 6 Similarly, Krueger and Kindermann (2014) s awesome state in their Aiyagari-Bewley model requires the top 0.25% earnings to be 400 to 600 larger than the median. Instead, according to the WWID, even the top 0.1% 6 We use WWID earnings data for 2014. The argument is not much changed even when considering average income, excluding capital gains.

4 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR are just about 34 times larger than the median. Finally, Díaz et al. (2003) estimate a top 6% of the population to earn 46 times the labor earnings of the median, while the top 5% in WWID earns about 5 times the median. To better account for wealth inequality, and especially top wealth shares, we conclude, it is necessary to rely on other factors. Remaining close to the Bewley- Aiyagari environment, for instance, several papers exploit heterogeneous life-spans, adding death rates independent of age ( perpetual youth ) to amplify wealth inequality (see Benhabib and Bisin, 2017, for a survey). In such a framework, however, standard calibrations of demographics imply that a significant fraction of agents enjoy counter-factually long lifespans. With stochastic but realistic finite life-spans, these models fail to match the top shares of the wealth distribution (De Nardi et al, 2016, p. 44). Theorem 1 suggests instead a role for stochastic idiosyncratic returns to wealth. Available evidence suggests that the idiosyncratic rate of return on wealth (capital income) is composed in large part of returns to entrepreneurship (returns to private business equity). 7 Since a good measure of these returns is generally hard to find, Benhabib, Bisin, Luo (2016) explicitly estimates the stochastic properties of the Markov process for returns to match the distribution of wealth. 8 Its conclusions are that stochastic idiosyncratic returns are essential for explaining the thickness of the wealth distribution. Finally, other promising factors which possibly help explain the thick tail of the wealth distribution include nonhomogeneous bequests (see De Nardi, 2004) and savings rates (increasing in wealth) as well as returns to wealth which 7 See Quadrini (2000) and Cagetti and De Nardi (2006), and equivalently for stochastic discount factors, see Krusell and Smith (1998). 8 Interestingly, the mean and standard deviation of estimated returns, 2.76% and 2.54%, respectively, closely match those estimated by Fagereng, Guiso, Malacrino and Pistaferri (2015) for the idiosyncratic component of the lifetime rate of return on wealth. are increasing in wealth (see Fagereng, Guiso, Malacrino and Pistaferri, 2015). Benhabib, Bisin, Luo (2016) find that all these are statistically significant in a model which includes also stochastic earnings as well as stochastic returns to wealth. REFERENCES Aiyagari, S. Rao. 1994. Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(3): 659 684. Alvaredo, Facundo, Anthony B. Atkinson, Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman. since 2011. World Wealth and Income Database. http://wid.world. Badel, Alejandro, Moira Daly, Mark Huggett, and Martin Nybom. 2016. Top Earners: Comparing the US, Canada, Denmark and Sweden. Mi Luo. 2015. Wealth Distribution and Social Mobility in the US: A Quantitative Approach. NBER Working Paper 21721. Shenghao Zhu. 2011. The Distribution of Wealth and Fiscal Policy in Economies With Finitely Lived Agents. Econometrica, 79(1): 123 157. Shenghao Zhu. 2015. The Wealth Distribution in Bewley Models with Capital Income. Journal of Economic Theory, 489 515. Benhabib, Jess, and Alberto Bisin. 2017. Skewed Wealth Distributions: Theory and Empirics. Cagetti, Marco, and Mariacristina De Nardi. 2006. Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth. Journal of Political Economy, 114(5): 835 870. Carroll, Christopher D., Jiri Slacalek, and Kiichi Tokuoka. 2013. The Distribution of Wealth and the Marginal Propensity to Consume.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EARNINGS AND WEALTH INEQUALITY 5 Castañeda, Ana, Javier Díaz- Gimínez, and José-Víctor Ríos- Rull. 2003. Accounting for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth Inequality. Journal of Political Economy, 111(4): 818 857. Cowell, Frank A. 2011. Inequality among the Wealthy. Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, LSE CASE Papers case150. Davies, James B., Susanne Sandström, Anthony Shorrocks, and Edward N. Wol. 2011. The Level and Distribution of Global Household Wealth. Economic Journal, 121(551): 223 254. De Nardi, Mariacristina. 2004. Wealth Inequality and Intergenerational Links. Review of Economic Studies, 71: 743 768. De Nardi, Mariacristina, Giulio Fella, Gonzalo Paz Pardo. 2016. The Implications of Richer Earnings Dynamics for Consumption and Wealth. NBER Working Paper 21917. Díaz, Antonia, Josep Pijoan-Mas, and José-Victor Ríos-Rull. 2003. Precautionary savings and wealth distribution under habit formation preferences. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(6): 1257 1291. Fagerang, Andreas, Luigi Guiso, Davide Malacrino, and Luigi Pistaferri. 2016. Heterogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth. Gabaix, Xavier. 2016. Power Laws in Economics: An Introduction. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30(1): 185 206. Ghosh, A. P., D. Hay, V. Hirpara, R. Rastegar, A. Roitershtein, and J. Suh A. Schulteis. 2010. Random Linear Recursions with Dependent Coe cients. Statistics and Probability Letters, 80: 1597 1605. Grey, D. R. 1994. Regular Variation in the Tail Behaviour of Solutions of Random Di erence Equations. The Annals of Applied Probability, 4(1): 169 183. Guvenen, Fatih, Fatih Karahan, Serdar Ozkan, and Jae Song. 2015. What Do Data on Millions of U.S. Workers Reveal about Life-Cycle Earnings Risk? National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc NBER Working Papers 20913. Hubmer, Joachim, Per Krusell, and Anthony A. Smith. 2015. The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation. Kesten, Harry. 1973. Random Di erence Equations and Renewal Theory for Products of Random Matrices. Acta Mathematica, 131(1): 207 248. Kindermann, Fabian, and Dirk Krueger. 2015. High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%? Lessons from a Life Cycle Model with Idiosyncratic Income Risk. NBER Working Paper 20601. Krueger, Dirk, Fabrizio Perri, Luigi Pistaferri, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2010. Cross Sectional Facts for Macroeconomists. Review of Economic Dynamics, 13(1). Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith. 1998. Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy. Journal of Political Economy, 106(5): 867 896. Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge, MA:Harvard University Press. Roitershtein, Alexander. 2007. One- Dimensional Linear Recursions with Markov-Dependent Coe cients. The Annals of Applied Probability, 17(2): 572 608. Vermeulen, Philip. 2015. How Fat Is the Top Tail of the Wealth Distribution? European Central Bank Working Paper Series 1692.