Benefits of reducing health inequalities

Similar documents
The economic benefits of reducing health inequalities in England and Wales*

Estimating the costs of health inequalities

The economic benefits of reducing health inequalities in 11 European countries

Development of health inequalities indicators for the Eurothine project

HEALTH AND WELLBEING: AGEING WORKFORCE

25/11/2014. Health inequality: causes and responses: action on the social determinants of health. Why we need to tackle health inequalities

Report of the National Equality Panel: Executive summary

Stockport (Local Authority)

Socioeconomic inequalities in mortality and longevity

Social Determinants of Health: evidence for action. Professor Sir Michael Marmot 12 th Sept th anniversary of the Faculty of Medicine, Oslo

Global and National Action on SDH. Michael Marmot UCL

Sickness absence in the labour market: 2016

Risk Management - Managing Life Cycle Risks. Module 9: Life Cycle Financial Risks. Table of Contents. Case Study 01: Life Table Example..

Healthy life expectancy: key points (new data this update)

Neighbourhoods. The English Indices of Deprivation Bradford District. Neighbourhoods. Statistical Release. June 2011.

Stockport (Local Authority)

W o r k a n d w o r k l e s s n e s s 1. Contents

DECEMBER 2006 INFORMING CHANGE. Monitoring poverty and social exclusion in Scotland 2006

PENSIONS POLICY INSTITUTE. Automatic enrolment changes

Indirect Health Costs by Income Level in Canada:

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF SAFETY AND HYGIENE

Diversity and different experiences in the UK

Retirement planning YOUR GUIDE

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION IN SCOTLAND 2015

PPI Briefing Note Number 97 Page 1 5.9% 5.8% 5.9% 5.7% Source: PPI Aggregate Model

Changes to work and income around state pension age

Monitoring poverty and social exclusion 2009

Monitoring poverty and social exclusion

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Wealth inequality and accumulation. John Hills, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of Economics

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Ageing Well in Work A Public Health England and GMPHN Project

Social Determinants of Health: employment and working conditions

PPI PPI Briefing Note Number 83

OECD Financial sustainability of healthcare systems Healthcare Productivity in the UK

Health and Work Spotlight on Mental Health. Mental health conditions are a leading cause of sickness absence in the UK.

INDICATORS OF POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION IN RURAL ENGLAND: 2009

Work in Life. Work and health from a life course perspective. Prof. dr. Ute Bültmann

Age, Demographics and Employment

Distributional Implications of the Welfare State

Taking action on the Social Determinants of Health. Michael Marmot

Health and Work Spotlight on Mental Health. Mental health conditions are a leading cause of sickness absence in the UK.

Toolkit INTRODUCTION. Why have a Worksite Wellness Program

Build financial confidence

Work ability and challenges for employers and employees on sustainable employability

Value-Based Pricing Working Party #1: Briefing for DH presentation

John Hills The distribution of welfare. Book section (Accepted version)

What is the problem under consideration? Why is government intervention necessary?

Rising Inequality in Life Expectancy by Socioeconomic Status

THE DIRECT ECONOMIC BURDEN OF SOCIO-ECONOMIC HEALTH INEQUALITIES IN CANADA

Differentials in pension prospects for minority ethnic groups in the UK

The implications of mortality heterogeneity on longevity sharing retirement income products

Are you prepared for retirement?

Poverty, Inequality and the Welfare State

Economic impact of NHS spending in the Black Country. 21 July 2017

The economics of health inequalities in the English NHS. Miqdad Asaria

Social Security.

The number of unemployed people

Widening socioeconomic differences in mortality and the progressivity of public pensions and other programs

Analysing the costs and benefits of social care funding arrangements in England: technical report

Your Retirement Income Gap Worksheet How much money will you have to enjoy the future you want?

Decumulation more than you ever wanted to know about post retirement income. Steve Schubert Director, Superannuation Russell Investment Group

Distribution of Wealth In Ireland

Managing Your Finances

ECON 201. Learning Objectives. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 9/25/2009. Chapter 5 GDP & Economic Growth

The Economic Impact of Housing Organisations on the North: Wakefield and District Housing

TUC Statement on the HM Treasury Spring Statement : Time for action

DISCOVERY FLEXIBLE INVESTMENT PLANS

FINANCE COMMITTEE DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND AGEING POPULATION SUBMISSION BY AUDIT SCOTLAND

Retirement what s your plan?

Age UK Waltham Forest Profile: Deprivation in Waltham Forest 08/01/2013

Work Life Expectancy. Work life expectancy is the length of time an individual is expected to participate in the workforce.

Wealth protection with added growth potential

Health inequalities in the EU. Final report of a consortium. Consortium lead: Sir Michael Marmot

THE DEMAND FOR SOCIAL RENTED HOUSING A REVIEW OF DATA SOURCES AND SUPPORTING CASE STUDY ANALYSIS

PUBLIC HEALTH PROGRAMME GUIDANCE SCOPE

1. Overview of the pension system

Public Health Portfolio Plan 2013/ /16

YOU ARE LOOKING FORWARD TO RETIREMENT BUT WHAT IF YOU NEED LONG-TERM CARE?

Running Head: The Value of Human Life 1. The Value of Human Life William Dare The University of Akron

Living Longer Working Longer. Older Workers in Ireland - Myths and Realities

Health and well-being in times of austerity

Macro- and micro-economic costs of cardiovascular disease

Counting the cost of UK poverty: Joseph Rowntree Foundation (JRF)Report

Income drawdown for corporate executives Received (in revised form): 18th March, 2002

Social costs tend to persist over a person s lifetime while most tangible costs are one-off

Understanding Income Distribution and Poverty

Chapter 4: Extending working life in an ageing society

Capital Stock Conference March 1997 Agenda Item V. The use of the Perpetual Inventory Method in the UK; Practices and Problems

Financial Intelligence Toolkit. 2018/19 Subscription. Financial Benchmarking - Unit Costs. Newtimber

The broader economic impact of healthcare: Assessing healthcare as

Deposited on: 29 May 2008 Glasgow eprints Service

DRAFT. A microsimulation analysis of public and private policies aimed at increasing the age of retirement 1. April Jeff Carr and André Léonard

HEALTH ECONOMICS GROUP Faculty of Medicine and Health Sciences Norwich Medical School

2. Employment, retirement and pensions

2011 Guide to Social Security

The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education

What happens next? Contact. Website:

Employment and Mortality of Older Canadians: Implications for Pensions

Healthy Workplace Conference. and 2019 Awards. Progress in Health Work and Wellbeing. Cornwall, 18 March Dame Carol Black

Transcription:

Benefits of reducing health inequalities Summary The benefits of reducing health inequalities are economic as well as social. The cost of health inequalities can be measured in both human terms, lost years of life and active life; and in economic terms, the cost to the economy of additional illness. If everyone in England had the same death rates as the most advantaged, people who are currently dying prematurely as a result of health inequalities would, in total, have enjoyed between 1.3 and 2.5 million extra years of life 1,2. They would, in addition, have had a further 2.8 million years free of limiting illness or disability 2. It is estimated that this illness accounts for productivity losses of 31-33 billion per year 2, lost taxes and higher welfare payments in the range of 20-32 billion per year 2 and additional NHS healthcare costs well in excess of 5.5 billion per year 3. If no action is taken, the cost of treating the various illnesses that result from inequalities in obesity alone will rise from 2 billion per year to 5 billion per year in 2025 4. 1 Background The overarching rationale for reducing socioeconomic inequalities in health is a moral or social justice one: health inequalities are seen as an issue of fairness. In this paper the benefits of reducing health inequalities are examined, by estimating what benefits might result, if health inequalities were reduced or even eliminated in England. There are few studies estimating the economic benefits of reducing health inequalities, or the cost of not doing so. The two most relevant studies are by Mackenbach et al 5 on the EU-25 countries and Dow and Schoeni 6 on the US. Mackenbach et al pursued two different approaches in measuring economic costs of health inequalities in one year, 2004: for the EU-25 as a whole the estimates of inequalities-related losses to health as a capital good (leading to less labour productivity) seem to be modest when compared to other economic indicators (1.4% of the value of GDP) but large in absolute terms ( 141 billion). They also valued health as a consumption good through the application of the concept of the value of a statistical life (VSL). From this more comprehensive perspective the economic impact of socioeconomic inequalities in health may well be large across the EU: in the order of about 1,000 billion, or 9.5% of the value of GDP. 1 Machenbach et al also separately estimated the impacts on costs of social security and health care systems and health care. Inequalities-related losses to health account for 15% of the costs of social security systems, and for 20% of the costs of health care systems in the European Union as a whole. It should, of course, be noted that the calculation

of GDP does not include health, so that this sum does not represent a valuation of the impact on GDP. Rather it sets the value of this consumption good against the basket of economic activity that is included. Dow and Schoeni applied the VSL approach to the US. They also found a large potential benefit of improving the health of disadvantaged Americans: raising the health of all Americans to that of college educated Americans would result in annual gains of just over 1 trillion dollars worth of increased health as of 2006. This paper focuses on a number of different approaches, both the human and economic costs of: loss of life years loss of active life years the economic costs of lives lost the cost to the economy of loss of activity 2 Loss of years of life Inequalities in are only part of the overall health inequalities that exist between socioeconomic groups. However they provide a sound starting point for building up an estimate of the full benefits of reducing health inequalities. The size of socioeconomic inequalities in health depends, among others, on the socioeconomic indicator chosen. Here we present three approaches. Two are based on different socioeconomic status (SES) variables, occupational class (NS-SEC) and education. 1 The third is based on systematic neighbourhood differences in life expectancy by income deprivation. 2 In each case potential reductions in the social gradient in health are identified and the value of the improvement this would represent in deaths avoided and extra population longevity is quantified. The economic benefits of each scenario are estimated using the value of a statistical life. 2.1 Occupational class Using occupational class data available around the time of the 2001 Census in England and Wales, Mazzuco, Meggiolaro and Suhrcke 1 focused on deaths in a core set of working ages (ages 30-59), to avoid problems of misclassification. As a result, no estimate was made of premature deaths prevented at younger or older ages. Four of the scenarios they considered are presented here: 1. rates of routine classes, never worked and long term unemployed to the level of semi-routine occupations (NS-SEC 6)

2. rates of the above classes and all other classes contained in the broad grouping routine and manual classes to the level of small employers and own account workers (NS-SEC 4) 3. Reduce by half the difference between the rates of the higher managerial and professional class (NS-SEC 1)and each of the other classes 4. the rates of all classes to that higher managerial and professional class Table 1 Estimated number of premature deaths prevented and life years that could be saved under alternative scenarios based on occupational class (NS-SEC), persons aged 30-59 in England and Wales, 2003. Scenarios for targeting improvement Potential premature deaths prevented at ages 30-59 in 2003 Potential years of extra lives lived among those dying at ages 30-59 in 2003 rates to NS-SEC 6 levels rates to NS-SEC 4 levels Halve differences between each class and NS- SEC 1 rates to NS- SEC 1 levels 13,158 32,672 33,324 66,611 391,909 1,054,163 1,049,079 2,301,500 This suggests that if, under scenario 4 above, the rates of all classes in this core working age group had been the same as the higher managerial and professional class in England and Wales in 2003, around 67,000 fewer premature deaths in this age group would have taken place and a total of 2.3 million years of life potentially saved. On a proportionate basis, this equates to 62,000 fewer deaths and 2.2 million years if life potentially saved in England. 2.2 Education A similar analysis of was carried out by Mazzuco, Meggiolaro and Mazzuco, Meggiolaro and Suhrcke 1 based on educational qualification recorded in the Census using data on education from the Office for National Statistics Longitudinal Study of England and Wales that had been supplied to the Eurothine project, an EU-wide effort to produce data on socioeconomic inequalities in health, see http://survey.erasmusmc.nl/eurothine/. In this analysis, attention was focused on those who are beyond normal ages of

attaining qualifications (aged 30 and over). Three of the scenarios examined are presented here: 1. level of people with no qualifications below A-level to that of the people with A-level; 2. Decrease by half the difference between the rate of people with and without degree level qualifications 3. the level of all people to that of those with degree level qualifications. Table 2 Estimated number of premature deaths prevented and life years that could be saved under alternative scenarios based on historic levels of educational attainment, persons aged 30 and over Scenarios for targeting improvement Potential premature deaths prevented at ages 30 and over each year Potential years of extra lives lived among those dying each year at ages 30 and over rates to rates of those with A-levels only Halve differences between each educational level and those with degrees 47,323 100,968 201,938 rates to rates of those with degrees 782,085 1,161,017 2,569,306 This suggests (scenario 3) that if the level of all people was the same as for those with degree-level qualifications, 202,000 premature deaths would be prevented at ages 30 and over each year and 2.6 million years of life potentially saved. On a proportionate basis, this equates to around 2.5 million years of life for England. 2.3 Neighbourhood Finally, scenarios were considered by Frontier Economics 2 that relate to improvement in the rates of neighbourhoods. Specifically, this was done by considering potential reductions in life expectancy differences among middle level super output areas (MSOAs). While there is a strong relationship between deprivation of these areas and their life expectancy levels, there is also considerable variability between areas with the same level of deprivation (principally due to the region in which the area is located). For this reason, Frontier Economics considered two scenarios that did not remove the variability between areas with the same level of deprivation:

1. life expectancy in the bottom half of the deprivation distribution to exactly match the life expectancy distribution of the top half 2. life expectancy in the bottom ninety per cent of the deprivation distribution to exactly match the life expectancy distribution within the top ten per cent. Table 3 Estimated number life years that could be saved under alternative scenarios based on neighbourhood deprivation Scenarios for targeting area life expectancy improvement Potential years of extra lives lived among those dying in 2010 Potential years of extra lives lived among those born in 2010 Potential years of extra lives lived by everyone alive in 2010 LE to level of top 50 per cent of areas 400,000 600,000 LE to level of top 10 per cent of areas 800,000 1,300,000 58 million 98 million This suggests that, under scenario 2, that if life expectancy we raised to the level of the least deprived ten per cent of neighbourhoods in England, there would be around 600,000 extra years of life lived among those who will die in 2010. The method also allows us to estimate the extra years that would be lived if all those born in 2010 experienced the current death rates in the 10 per cent of least deprived areas (1.3 million years) or if everyone currently alive experienced these more favourable death rates (98 million extra years). 3 Loss of healthy life years This section focuses on years spent with a limiting long-term illness or disability. By applying the technique used in the previous example of neighbourhood s variation to disability free life expectancy, Frontier economics produced estimates of the extra years spent with a limiting longterm illness or disability by those in neighbourhoods in England with higher levels of deprivation 2. For consistency, the same scenarios as those considered for life expectancy reduction were used. Clearly, the potential extra years of healthy life shown in Table 4 include the extra years lived shown in Table 3. Table 4 Estimated number life years that could be saved under alternative scenarios based on neighbourhood deprivation

Potential extra healthy years of life among those born in 2010 Potential extra healthy years of life for everyone alive in 2010 Scenarios for targeting area life expectancy improvement LE to level LE to of top 50 per cent of level of top 10 areas per cent of areas 2,500,000 4,100,000 171 million 285 million This analysis suggests that if all those born in 2010 experienced the current rates of illness, disability and death seen in the 10 per cent of least deprived areas they would enjoy some 4.1 million extra years of healthy life. The comparable gain for everyone currently alive is 285 million years of healthy life. 4 The economic cost of years of life lost Mazzuco, Meggiolaro and Suhrcke 1 identified a number of estimates of the VSL in the literature, including a growing number based on European labour market data. For example, one recent study, using surveys from France, Italy and the UK, estimated a VSL range of 1.052 to 2.258 million, with a life year valued between 55,000 and 142,000. These estimates are comparable to those from a 2006 study of German labour market data, which estimated the VSL at 1.9 million to 3.5 million, depending on the method of calculation. These estimates are not too dissimilar from values that have been proposed and are being used in the UK. A seemingly well established VSL estimate has been derived by the Department for Transport: 1.25 million (in 2002 prices), based on 2002 road traffic data. 7 This value has been used, typically with a range of plus or minus 25 per cent around its central value, by the Home Office, HSE, Environment Agency, Food Standards Agency and other government bodies. 8 With a number of simplifying assumptions it is possible to convert the VSL value into a Value of a Statistical Life Year (VoSLY) using the standard compound interest formulae and a discount rate of 3.5 per cent. In addition to the critical assumption that each year of life over the life cycle has the same value, this approach assumes that the VSL can be expressed as the present discounted value of these annual amounts. In practice, a number of factors are likely to lead to differences in how one values survival at different ages, e.g. changes in wealth levels, family responsibilities, health status, and other aspects of one s life cycle. For a critical discussion of these issues see for

example Hammitt. 9 For the UK VoSLY would be about 58,000 on this basis. To express future amounts in present value terms (see Dow10and Schoeni 6 ), a discount rate of 3.5% is used. Using these figures the calculation of potential life years saved, shown in Tables 1-3, is presented in monetary terms in Tables 5-7 based on the respective calculations presented by Mazzuco, Meggiolaro and Suhrcke 1 and Frontier Economics. 2 The greatest part of these benefits are about the intangible economic value of life and health and, for this reason, they do not represent the value of potential savings. Table 5 Expected benefits (in billion ) associated with improved under alternative scenarios, NS-SEC classification, persons aged 30-59 in England and Wales. Expected economic benefit from premature deaths prevented at ages 30-59 Scenarios for targeting improvement Halve rates to rates to differences rates to NS- NS-SEC 6 levels NS-SEC 4 levels between each class and NS- SEC 1 SEC 1 levels 42.2 118 117.6 273 Range 31.6-52.7 88.5 147.5 88.2 147.0 204.8 341.2 Table 6 Expected benefits (in billion ) associated with improved under alternative scenarios, education classification, persons aged 30 and over in England and Wales. Expected economic benefit from premature deaths prevented at ages 30-59 Scenarios for targeting improvement Halve differences rates rates to rates between each of those with educational to rates of those with degrees A-levels only level and those with degrees 72.7 97.4 221.8 Range 54.5 90.9 73.0 121.7 166.5 277.3

In Tables 5 and 6, the range shown for each VoSLY estimate is based on +/- 25% of the mean value (i.e. 43,500 and 72,500). 1 Figures for England are approximately 94 per cent of those for England and Wales, on a pro rata basis. Table 7 Expected benefits (in billion ) associated with improved neighbourhood life expectancy under alternative scenarios. Expected economic benefit from extra years lived among those dying in 2010 Expected economic benefit from extra years lived among those born in 2010 Expected economic benefit from extra years lived by everyone alive in 2010 Scenarios for targeting area life expectancy improvement LE to level LE to of top 50 per cent of level of top 10 areas per cent of areas 20 36 2.2 3.5 900 1,500 5 Cost to the economy of lost activity or illness This section brings together several quantifiable dimensions of lost activity due to illness or disability. It draws on the work of Dame Carol Black s report, 10 analyses of the extra treatment costs borne by the NHS in England as a result of health inequalities 3 and work prepared for Foresight on the future costs of obesity. 4 By comparing the current situation, with its considerable levels of inequality, with one in which everyone had the same health outcomes as the richest 10 per cent of the population in England, Frontier Economics estimated 2 that there are currently: Productivity losses of 31-33 billion per year Lost taxes and higher welfare payments in the range of 20-32 billion per year Direct NHS healthcare costs in England associated with treating the consequences of inequality amount to 5.5 billion per year for treating acute illness and mental illness and prescriptions. 3 These activities represent

approximately one third of the NHS budget. In consequence, it is likely that the full impact of health inequalities on direct healthcare costs is considerably greater than this. Taking an alternative approach, by modelling the costs of treating the various illnesses that result from inequalities in obesity this time in England and Wales, McPherson K and Brown 4 estimated that inequalities in obesity currently cost 2 billion per year, predicted to rise to nearly 5 billion per year in 2025. Separate estimates could be made for other risk factors for illness (such as lifestyle behaviours). However, there would be an element of double counting involved in trying to estimate too many separate risk factors for different illnesses. 6 Conclusion These analyses, like others in this area, 5,6 do not measure the full social costs and benefits of particular policies and programs that could reduce health disparities. Equally, the scenarios are hypothetical. Nevertheless they clearly indicate the orders of magnitudes of the problems to be addressed when considering options that might help reduce health inequalities.

References 1 Mazzuco S, Meggiolaro S and Suhrcke M (2009) Submission to the Marmot Review. www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreview/documents 2 Frontier Economics (2009) Overall costs of health inequalities. Submission to the Marmot Review. www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreview/documents 3 Morris S (2009) Private communication. 4 McPherson K and Brown M (2009) Social class and obesity - effects on disease and health service treatment costs. Submission to the Marmot Review. www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreview/documents 5 Mackenbach, J.P., W.J. Meerding, and A.E. Kunst. 2007. Economic Implications of Socioeconomic Inequalities in Health in the European Union, Health and Consumer 6 Dow W., Schoeni R. F. (2008). Economic Value of Improving the Health of Disadvantaged Americans. Technical Report for Overcoming Obstacles to Health: Report from the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation to the Commission to Build a Healthier America. 7 Department for Transport s Highways Economics Notes, available at: http://www.dft.gov.uk/pgr/roadsafety/ea/ (last accessed 10/12/2009). 8 HM Treasury (2005). Managing Risks to the Public: Appraisal Guidance. 9 Hammitt J.K (2007) Valuing changes in risk: lives saved vs. life years saved, Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (2007), pp. 228 240. 10 Black C (2008) Working for a healthier tomorrow. London: TSO. http://www.workingforhealth.gov.uk/documents/working-for-ahealthiertomorrow-tagged.pdf.