EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Similar documents
EconS Income E ects

EconS Substitution E ects

EconS Firm Optimization

EconS Consumer Theory: Additional Topics

EconS Utility. Eric Dunaway. Washington State University September 15, 2015

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

EconS Cost Functions

EconS Supply and Demand

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 7 of the text.

ECON Micro Foundations

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Costs. Lecture 5. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 7 1 / 63

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

EconS Industrial Organization Assignment 6 Homework Solutions

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare

Optimal Portfolio Selection

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

Linear Modeling Business 5 Supply and Demand

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

Chapter 5: Utility Maximization Problems

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Note 1: Indifference Curves, Budget Lines, and Demand Curves

Lecture 4: Consumer Choice

ECO101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS Notes. Consumer Behaviour. U tility fro m c o n s u m in g B ig M a c s

Problem Set 5 Answers. A grocery shop is owned by Mr. Moore and has the following statement of revenues and costs:

EconS Games with Incomplete Information II and Auction Theory

Chapter 4 Read this chapter together with unit four in the study guide. Consumer Choice

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Homework 3 Solutions

Problem Set I - Solution

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. Maximizing Utility. The Budget Set for Consumers. Slope =

Homework 1 Solutions

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

COMM 220 Practice Problems 1

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

EconS 301 Written Assignment #3 - ANSWER KEY

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. The Budget Set for Consumers. Indifference Curves are Like a Topographical Map for Utility.

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

CLAS. Utility Functions Handout

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Production Theory. Lesson 7. Ryan Safner 1. Hood College. ECON Microeconomic Analysis Fall 2016

Lecture 19 Monday, Oct. 26. Lecture. 1 Indifference Curves: Perfect Substitutes. 1. Problem Set 2 due tomorrow night.

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support will help

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Economics 101 Fall 2016 Answers to Homework #1 Due Thursday, September 29, 2016

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

The Ricardian Model. Rafael López-Monti Department of Economics George Washington University Summer 2015 (Econ 6280.

We are going to see the consumer s decision theory that you have seen in ECON 111 in another way.

Econ 344 Public Finance Spring 2005 Dzmitry Asinski. Homework Assignment 5 solution.

Lecture 3: Consumer Choice

Lecture 5: Individual and Market Demand

Solutions to Assignment #2

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis July 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm - Solutions

Solutions to Extra Business Problems

E&G, Ch. 1: Theory of Choice; Utility Analysis - Certainty

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Intro to Economic analysis

Section 2 Solutions. Econ 50 - Stanford University - Winter Quarter 2015/16. January 22, Solve the following utility maximization problem:

GE in production economies

Symmetric Game. In animal behaviour a typical realization involves two parents balancing their individual investment in the common

Macro Consumption Problems 33-43

MIDTERM EXAM ANSWER KEY

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 9 THE COSTS OF PRODUCTION

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

Lecture 5: Individual and Market Demand

* The Unlimited Plan costs $100 per month for as many minutes as you care to use.

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Transcription:

EconS 305 - Constrained Consumer Choice Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu September 21, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 1 / 49

Introduction We have analyzed what consumers prefer, in the form of utility. We have also analyzed what consumers can actually buy, in the form of budget constraints. It s time to put them together and derive demand curves. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 2 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice Given that consumers are constrained to choosing bundles that lie within their opportunity set, the want to choose the bundle that maximizes their utility. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 3 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice z Budget Line Opportunity Set x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 4 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 5 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 6 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 7 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice Intuitively, the consumer is going to choose the bundle on their budget line that is going to give them the highest utility. This corresponds to the indi erence curve that touches the budget line at only one point (a tangency point). We can nd this point mathematically. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 8 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice A great feature of the tangency point is that the rate of change (slope) of the indi erence curve at that point is exactly the same as the slope of the budget line. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 9 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 10 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 11 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice We actually calculated the rate of change of the indi erence curve last week. We called it the marginal rate of substitution. MRS = MU x MU z where MU x is the marginal utility with respect to x and MU z is the marginal utility with respect to z. (Note that I changed the y into a z from last week. No change in its meaning). Also, we calculated the slope of the budget line last week. We called it the marginal rate of transformation. MRT = p x p z where p x is the price of good x and p z is the price of good z. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 12 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice Thus, the point where the indi erence curve is tangent to the budget line will be where the marginal rate of substitution equals the marginal rate of transformation MRS = MRT MU x p x = MU z p z MU x = p x MU z p z Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 13 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice MU x MU z = p x p z This ratio is actually a representation of one of the most basic rules of economics. To see this, let s rearrange a few terms. MU x p x = MU z p z Remember that the marginal utility of x is the amount of utility the consumer gets for consuming one more unit of x. The price of x, p x is the price to consume one more unit of x. Same thing for good z. The consumer will want to consume until the relative gain to cost is the same across all goods. If it weren t the same, then they could get to a higher utility by switching the goods around. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 14 / 49

Constrained Consumer Choice Now that we have gured out where the tangency point is, we just need to use one more piece of information to solve for our demand. We know that the tangency point happens on the budget line. This tells us exactly what utility level we reach. Thus, our system of two equations and two unknowns to nd our solution are Let s look at an example. MU x = p x MU z p z p x x + p z z = Y Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 15 / 49

Example Consider the following utility function for two goods, x and z, Ū = x 0.75 z 0.25 The price for good x is p x = 3, the price for good z is p z = 4 and the consumer has an income of Y = 64. Derive the optimal quantity of x and z. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 16 / 49

Example Ū = x 0.75 z 0.25 Starting o, let s calculate our marginal utilities using the power rule: MU x = 0.75x 0.25 z 0.25 MU y = 0.25x 0.75 z 0.75 Next, the equation for our budget line is p x x + p z z = Y 3x + 4z = 64 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 17 / 49

Example Let s gure out our marginal rate of substitution MRS = MU x = 0.75x 0.25 z 0.25 MU z 0.25x 0.75 z 0.75 = 3z x and our marginal rate of transformation MRT = p x p z = 3 4 Together, we can set up our tangency condition, MRS = MRT 3 z 3 = x 4 3 z x = 3 4 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 18 / 49

Example 3 z x = 3 4 Let s rearrange some terms to make this a bit nicer. x = 4z Now, we just have this equation and the budget line to nd a solution 3x + 4z = 64 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 19 / 49

Example I can substitute x = 4z into the budget line to get 3(4z) + 4z = 64 16z = 64 z = 4 Then, I put this value back into x = 4z to get my solution for x, x = 4z = 4(4) = 16 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 20 / 49

Example z 24 16 4 16 21.3 24 x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 21 / 49

Example Ū = x 0.75 z 0.25 3x + 4z = 64 x = 16 z = 4 Does this answer make sense? Yes. From the utility function, we can see that the consumer gets a lot more utility from consuming good x than from good z. Also, good x is relatively cheaper than good z. We should expect in this case that x should be higher than z. Note: If x were more expensive than z, this might not be the case. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 22 / 49

Corner Solution A few notes: When utility functions are well behaved, our solution will always lie somewhere along the budget line. By this, I mean not at the end points. If the curvature of the indi erence curve is small (a relatively straight curve), we can get situations where the only intersection point is at an end point. When this happens, our tangency condition does not hold any more. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 23 / 49

Corner Solution z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 24 / 49

Corner Solution z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 25 / 49

Corner Solution If we let the budget line extend to the negative axis (either z is negative or x is negative), we would be able to nd a tangency point. But we don t consume negative quantities of goods. Therefore, if you re trying to solve a problem and you get that one of the goods is negative, set it to zero and solve for the other good. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 26 / 49

Corner Solution Lastly, let s talk about an extreme example: perfect substitutes. When we have perfect substitutes, the indi erence curves are straight lines. Remember that their marginal rate of substitution is constant no matter where on the line the bundle falls. Since it s constant, it s almost impossible for a tangency point to be found. This means that when we re dealing with perfect substitutes, we almost always have a corner solution The only exception is when the slope of the indi erence curve is the same as the slope of the budget line; then any bundle can be a solution! When dealing with perfect substitutes, people only buy the good that gives the highest utility. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 27 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve And that s equilibrium. But what about deriving the demand curve? This is actually pretty easy from here. All we need to do is start changing prices, and the curve will develop. Let s look back at our gures. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 28 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 29 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 30 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve z x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 31 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve z p x x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 32 / 49 x

Deriving the Demand Curve z p x x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 33 / 49 x

Deriving the Demand Curve z p x x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 34 / 49 x

Deriving the Demand Curve p x x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 35 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve p x x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 36 / 49

Deriving the Demand Curve Mathematically, we can derive the demand curve by not picking values for prices or income. This should make sense, since usually these are factors that determine the demand for an item. Let s go back to our example. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 37 / 49

Example Recall the utility function from our earlier example Ū = x 0.75 z 0.25 Now, we don t specify any prices or income and we leave the budget line in a general form p x x + p z z = Y Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 38 / 49

Example Our marginal rate of substitution hasn t changed, it is still MRS = MU x = 0.75x 0.25 z 0.25 MU z 0.25x 0.75 z 0.75 = 3z x We can also just express our marginal rate of transformation in general terms MRT = p x p z Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 39 / 49

Example Now, we nd our tangency point Let s rearrange this for easier use MRS = MRT 3 z p x = x p z 3 z = p x x p z p x x = 3p z z Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 40 / 49

Example p x x = 3p z z Now, we use our tangency condition, along with the budget line and we can solve it for x and z p x x + p z z = Y Remember that the while we haven t given them numbers, we assume that we know what the prices and income are. We just need to solve for x and z as a function of those values. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 41 / 49

Example p x x = 3p z z p x x + p z z = Y Let s subtract both sides of the rst equation by p x x p x x + 3p z z = 0 p x x + p z z = Y and add the equations together (getting rid of p x x) which is the demand curve for z p x x + 3p z z + p x x + p z z = 0 + Y 4p z z = Y z = Y 4p z Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 42 / 49

Example z = Y 4p z Like before, we can plug this value back into our tangency point to get the demand for x p x x = 3p z z p x x = 3p z Y 4p z p x x = 3Y 4 x = 3Y 4p x which is the demand curve for x. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 43 / 49

Example x = 3Y 4p x z = Y 4p z These demand curves probably look strange. They re non-linear. It s actually really hard to pick well behaved utility functions that give linear demand curves. The important thing is that when their own price increases, the quantity demanded falls (Law of Demand). We can see this because p x is in the denominator. As it gets bigger, x gets smaller. The same thing happens with p z and z. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 44 / 49

Example p x x Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 45 / 49

Example x = 3Y 4p x z = Y 4p z When we plug in our original values, p x = 3, p z = 4 and Y = 64, we get the same solution from the rst example x = 3(64) 4(3) = 16 z = 64 4(4) = 4 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 46 / 49

Summary Combining utility functions with budget constraints allows us to gure out solve the constrained consumer choice problem, which in turn allows us to derive demand curves. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 47 / 49

Preview for Wednesday We are going to analyze what happens to the constrained consumer choice problem when prices and incomes vary. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 48 / 49

Assignment 3-1 (1 of 1) 1. Consider the following market with two goods, x and z. The consumer s utility function is Ū = x 0.2 z 0.8 a. Derive the demand curves for x and z. (Remember to include p x, p z and Y in there as unknowns. Look at the last example if you need help.) b. Let p x = 2, p z = 4 and I = 50. Find the equilibrium quantities demanded of x and z. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 12 September 21, 2015 49 / 49