Technical Appendix to Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy

Similar documents
Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy

Asset prices in a Huggett economy

Slides III - Complete Markets

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

Solutions to Midterm Exam. ECON Financial Economics Boston College, Department of Economics Spring Tuesday, March 19, 10:30-11:45am

1 Mar Review. Consumer s problem is. V (z, K, a; G, q z ) = max. subject to. c+ X q z. w(z, K) = zf 2 (K, H(K)) (4) K 0 = G(z, K) (5)

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Background Risk and Trading in a Full-Information Rational Expectations Economy

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Homework Assignment #1: Answer Sheet

The Analytics of Information and Uncertainty Answers to Exercises and Excursions

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY ECONOMICS NOTE 8b

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Consumption and Asset Pricing

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

LECTURE 12: FRICTIONAL FINANCE

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Characterization of the Optimum

Practice Exam Questions 2

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Game Theory Fall 2003

Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Games when Players Belief Are Not in Equilibrium

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh

Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999)

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Dynamic programming

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

A simple wealth model

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

The Zero Lower Bound

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

6. Deficits and inflation: seignorage as a source of public sector revenue

Advanced (International) Macroeconomics

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

1.3 Nominal rigidities

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 8

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

This assignment is due on Tuesday, September 15, at the beginning of class (or sooner).

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

14.54 International Economics Handout 5

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Problem Set. Solutions to the problems appear at the end of this document.

Period State of the world: n/a A B n/a A B Endowment ( income, output ) Y 0 Y1 A Y1 B Y0 Y1 A Y1. p A 1+r. 1 0 p B.

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Transcription:

Technical Appendix to Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy Per Krusell, Toshihiko Mukoyama, Anthony A. Smith, Jr. October 2010 1 Assets in positive net supply: introduction We consider assets in positive supply here. The purpose is to show that such economies, both in the case with without aggregate uncertainty, there is an equivalent economy with assets in zero supply but with appropriately adjusted, looser borrowing constraints. We demonstrate this in a slightly differently way than in the paper (where only the case without aggregate shocks is discussed). In particular, we show that if the economies with positive asset supplies are amended with the appropriate higher, positive, values for the lower bound of assets the risk-free asset in the first economy the contingent claims in the second then those economies have identical prices to those studied in the paper. 2 No aggregate uncertainty Suppose that there is an asset, called a tree, that generates a constant amount η every period. 1 Let the price of the tree be p the individual holding of the tree be x. Then the individual consumer s problem becomes V s (a, x) = max c,a,x 1 σ + β[π shv h (a, x ) + (1 π sh )V l (a, x )] c = a + (p + η)x + ɛ s qa px. In equilibrium, the bond the tree have to generate the same return (no arbitrage), so (p + η)/p = 1/q. Therefore, p = q(p + η) holds. Using this, the budget constraint can be rewritten as c = (a + (p + η)x) + ɛ s q(a + (p + η)x ). Let â a + (p + η)x. Then the problem can be rewritten as ˆV s (â) = max c,â 1 σ + β[π sh ˆV h (â ) + (1 π sh ) ˆV l (â )] c = â + ɛ s qâ. 1 A similar argument can be made if there is a constant positive supply of outside, say government, bonds, with an associated government budget constraint. 1

Now, suppose that the borrowing constraint is â p + η, i.e., we use a borrowing constraint on total wealth rather than on the holdings of individual assets. Below, we will show that the equilibrium is that â = p + η for everyone. One allocation that achieves this is a = 0 x = 1 for everyone that is, no one holds bonds everyone owns the same amount of the tree. Other asset holding patterns are also possible some can hold a < 0 x > 1 while others can have a > 0 x < 1. The only requirements for an equilibrium are that â = p + η for everyone, a sums up to zero, x sums up to one. To show that â = p + η for everyone is the only equilibrium, define ã â p η ɛ s ɛ s + η. 2 Then the problem becomes Ṽ s (ã) = max c,ã 1 σ + β[π shṽh(ã ) + (1 π sh )Ṽl(ã )] c = ã + ɛ s qã ã 0, which is identical to the original problem. Therefore, the equilibrium is autarky: ã = 0 c = ɛ s. ã = 0 implies â = p + η. As long as the borrowing constraint is set at an appropriate level, we can transform an economy where there are assets in positive net supply into an economy with a bond in zero net supply. Thus, the borrowing constraint here means that agents have to have at least a certain (positive) amount of the asset. 3 Aggregate uncertainty First, we consider a case where there is one tree in addition to the two Arrow securities. Let the tree price at state z be p z, the dividend of the tree at state z be η z, the tree holding be x. The problem becomes V (a, x; s, z) = max c,a g,a b,x 1 σ +β [ φ zz [π sh zz V (a z, x ; h, z ) + (1 π sh zz )V (a z, x ; l, z )] c = a + (p z + η z )x + ɛ s Q zg a g Q zb a b p z x borrowing constraints. From arbitrage, p z = Q zg (p g + η g ) + Q zb (p b + η b ) has to hold. Thus the budget constraint can be rewritten as c = (a + (p z + η z )x) + ɛ s Q zg (a g + (p g + η g )x ) Q zb (a b + (p b + η b )x ). Let â z = a z + (p z + η z )x. Then the problem can be rewritten as c ˆV 1 σ (â; s, z) = max c,â g,â b 1 σ + β φ zz [π sh zz ˆV (â z ; h, z ) + (1 π sh zz ) ˆV (â z ; l, z )] 2 This is the transformation that we use in the main text of the paper. ] 2

c = â + ɛ s Q zg â g Q zb â b. Let us impose the borrowing constraints â g p g + η g â b p b + η b. We will show that in equilibrium â g = p g + η g â b = p b + η b. One set of asset holdings that can achieve this equilibrium is a g = 0, a b = 0, x = 1 for everyone. Again, it is important that the constraints are on the total amount of asset, rather than individual assets, for example a g < 0, a b < 0 x > 1 for one consumer can be consistent with an equilibrium, as long as â g = p g + η g â b = p b + η b are satisfied the total asset dem equals the total supply for each asset. Let ã z â z p z η z ɛ sz ɛ s + η z. Then the problem can be rewritten as Ṽ (ã; s, z) = max c,ã g,â b 1 σ + β φ zz [π sh zz Ṽ (ã z ; h, z ) + (1 π sh zz )Ṽ (ã z ; l, z )] with c = ã + ɛ sz Q zg ã g Q zb ã b, ã g 0 ã b 0. This is equivalent to our baseline problem, therefore Q zg Q zb are the same, except that ɛ s is adjusted to ɛ sz. The equilibrium is autarky the individual consumption is equal to ɛ sz. ã g = 0 ã b = 0 imply that â g = p g + η g â b = p b + η b. 3.1 A representation with a bond a stock In the previous section, the stock (claim for the tree ) was a redundant asset in the sense that the two aggregate states are already spanned by the Arrow securities. This allowed us to price the stock with arbitrage. In this section, we consider an economy where there are only two assets, a bond a stock. As in the previous section, the stock yields η z every period. One unit of the bond provides one unit of consumption good regardless of the aggregate state. The total supply of stock is 1 unit the bond is in zero net supply. Assume p g + η g p b + η b. Denote the stock holding by x the bond holding by y. Let p z be the stock price at state z q z be the bond price at z. We first show that we can replicate the payoffs of Arrow securities by combining the bond the stock with appropriate proportions. Let us define x g 1 Then, we can easily see that y g p b + η b. y g + (p g + η g )x g = 1 3

y g + (p b + η b )x g = 0 are satisfied. This means that by holding y g units of the bond x g units of the stock, one can guarantee to receive 1 unit if the next period aggregate state is g receive 0 unit if the next period aggregate state is b. Therefore, holding the bundle (x g units of stock, y g units of bond) is identical to a g-state Arrow security. Similarly, the bundle of x 1 b units of the stock y b p g + η g units of the bond yields an identical payoff to a b-state Arrow security. acquiring these bundles be Q zg Q zb. That is, Let the cost of Q zg p z p z q z (p b + η b ) q z (p g + η g ) Q zb +. We can easily check the following simple relationships between Q zz the stock/bond prices: Q zg + Q zb = q z (1) (p g + η g )Q zg + (p b + η b )Q zb = p z. (2) Let a z be the dem of the z -state security bundle. Then the corresponding total dem for stock is a x = x ga g + x ba g a b b = (3) the total dem for bonds is y = y ga g + y ba b = a b (p g + η g ) a g(p b + η b ). (4) Note that there is one-to-one correspondence between (x, y ) (a g, a b ). That is, by deming two sets of bundles, the consumers are indirectly deming the stock the bond. By adjusting the bundle dems a g a b, they can adjust the dems for stocks bonds as if they were directly choosing x y. Therefore, if (a g, a b ) maximizes the utility given Q zz, the corresponding (x, y ) from (3) (4) also maximizes the utility given the prices (p z, q z ) that satisfy (1) (2). The budget constraint for the original bond--stock economy is c = (p z + η z )x + y + ɛ s p z x q z y. 4

Using (1), (2), (3), (4), this can be rewritten as c = a z + ɛ s Q zg a g Q zb a b. Now, let us impose the borrowing constraint a g p g + η g a b p b + η b. Since a z = (p z + η z )x + y from (3) (4), these are equivalent to (p g + η g )(x 1) + y 0 (p b + η b )(x 1) + y 0. As in the previous section, consider the transformation ã z = a z p z η z (5) ɛ sz = ɛ s + η z. (6) Then the budget constraint the borrowing constraint can be rewritten as c = ã z + ɛ sz Q zg ã g Q zb ã b. ã g 0 ã b 0. In sum, we have demonstrated the equivalence of the problem V (x, y; s, z) = max c,x,y 1 σ + β φ zz [π sh zz V (x, y ; h, z ) + (1 π sh zz )V (x, y ; l, z )] c = (p z + η z )x + y + ɛ s p z x q z y (p g + η g )(x 1) + y 0 (p b + η b )(x 1) + y 0; the problem Ṽ (ã; s, z) = max c,ã g,â b 1 σ + β φ zz [π sh zz Ṽ (ã z ; h, z ) + (1 π sh zz )Ṽ (ã z ; l, z )] c = ã + ɛ sz Q zg ã g Q zb ã b ã g 0 ã b 0, (P 1) (P 2) where ɛ sz = ɛ s + η z. The prices are one-to-one linked by (1) (2), the quantities are one-to-one linked by (3), (4), (5), (6). The second problem (P 2) is familiar to us: the equilibrium is autarky. It means that the borrowing constraints hold with equality, which in turn implies that the borrowing constraints in the first problem (P 1) also hold with equality. Therefore, x = 1 y = 0 hold in equilibrium (there is no indeterminacy as in 5

the previous section because there is no redundant asset). Q zg Q zb are determined in a familiar manner this can be translated into p z q z using (1) (2). The equivalence of the two problems can also be seen from the Euler equations. Recall that the Euler equation for (P 2) with autarky is Q zz ɛ σ sz + βφ zz [π sh zz ɛ σ hz + (1 π sh zg ) ɛ σ lz ] + λ z sz = 0, (7) for z = g, b. By adding this up for z = g z = b, we obtain [ q z ɛ σ sz + β (φ zz [π sh zz ɛ σ hz + (1 π sh zg ) ɛ σ lz ] + λ z sz) ] = 0, (8) where we used the relationship (1). By multiplying (p z + η z ) on each sides of (7) add up for z = g z = b, we obtain p z ɛ σ sz + β (p z + η z )(φ zz [π sh zz ɛ σ hz + (1 π sh zg ) ɛ σ lz ] + λ z sz) = 0, (9) where we used the relationship (2). It is straightforward to see that (8) (9) are the Euler equations for (P 1) with x = 1 y = 0. Therefore, if (7) holds (that is, ã g = 0 ã b = 0 are the optimal choices in (P 2) given Q zz ), (8) (9) also hold x = 1 y = 0 are the optimal choices given q z p z in (P 1). 6