Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

Similar documents
Business Cycles in. Mundell Fleming with Fixed Exchange Rates. Andrew Rose, Global Macroeconomics 10

The Mundell Fleming Model. The Mundell Fleming Model is a simple open economy version of the IS LM model.

Question 5 : Franco Modigliani's answer to Simon Kuznets's puzzle regarding long-term constancy of the average propensity to consume is that : the ave

QUESTIONS CHAPTER 25 SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC POLICY

The Sustainability of Sterilization Policy

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Understanding Krugman s Third-Generation Model of Currency and Financial Crises

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Part B (Long Questions)

Examiners commentaries 2011

file:///c:/users/moha/desktop/mac8e/new folder (13)/CourseComp...

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Learning objectives. Macroeconomics I International Group Course Topic 8: AGGREGATE DEMAND IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

yp^\ .^^CHL UBRARIES -X'

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

The Mundell-Fleming-Tobin Model

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2018

Exercise 3 Short Run Determination of Output, the Interest Rate, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account in a Mundell Fleming Model

CHAPTER 23 OUTPUT AND PRICES IN THE SHORT RUN

SUMMER TERM 2017 ECON1604: ECONOMICS I (Combined Studies)

University of Toronto July 21, 2010 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Topic 7: The Mundell-Fleming Model

Lecture 5: Flexible prices - the monetary model of the exchange rate. Lecture 6: Fixed-prices - the Mundell- Fleming model

Answers to Questions: Chapter 8

5. An increase in government spending is represented as a:

International Linkages and Domestic Policy

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Problem Set 5

YORK UNIVERSITY. Suggested Solutions to Part C (C3(d) and C4)

Intermediate Macroeconomics-ECO 3203

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer NOTES ON THE MIDTERM

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

6 The Open Economy. This chapter:

The IS-LM-BP=0 Model (aka Mundell-Fleming ) under Fixed Rates

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 6

dr Bartłomiej Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

Final Exam - Answers April 26, 2004

EC202 Macroeconomics

The Open Economy Revisited: the Exchange-Rate Regime

Please choose the most correct answer. You can choose only ONE answer for every question.

TOPIC 9. International Economics

The Credit Crunch. Macroeconomics IV. Ricardo J. Caballero. Spring 2011 MIT. R.J. Caballero (MIT) The Credit Crunch Spring / 16

Chapter 18 (7) Fixed Exchange Rates and Foreign Exchange Intervention

Online Appendix A to chapter 16

José Darío Uribe E. Governor central bank of colombia October 13, 2011

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

Macroeconomics in an Open Economy

MACROECONOMICS. The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime MANKIW N. GREGORY

Bubbles and Capital Flow Volatility: Causes and Risk Management

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Open Economy. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Open Economy 1 / 66

3. OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS

LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

Answers to Questions: Chapter 7

The Mundell-Fleming Model. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

macro macroeconomics Aggregate Demand in the Open Economy N. Gregory Mankiw CHAPTER TWELVE PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich fifth edition

The Mundell-Fleming-Tobin model

ECM134 International Money and Finance 2012/13 Exam Paper Model Answers

Panel on market liquidity

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 17 Appendix B

Suggested Solutions Assignment 4 (OPTIONAL)

2nd Exam Macroeconomics IBA

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Winter 2009 Solutions to Problem Set 2.

CAPITAL FLOWS: EMERGING ISSUES Guillermo A. Calvo University of Maryland Bogota, October 1, 1997

Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto Universtiy SB, Spring 2016, Solution to Problem Set 4

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

7.1 Assumptions: prices sticky in SR, but flex in MR, endogenous expectations

Simultaneous Equilibrium in Output and Financial Markets: The Short Run Determination of Output, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account

Goals of Topic 8. NX back!! What is the link between the exchange rate and net exports? How do different policies affect the trade deficit?

EC 205 Lecture 20 04/05/15

The Open Economy. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

Chapter 13 The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

14.02 Quiz #2 SOLUTION. Spring Time Allowed: 90 minutes

The Mundell-Fleming model

EC3115 Monetary Economics

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

The Impact of an Increase In The Money Supply and Government Spending In The UK Economy

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2. December 13, 2017

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT MAKES US GOVERNMENT BONDS SAFE ASSETS? Zhiguo He Arvind Krishnamurthy Konstantin Milbradt

Chapter 18: Output and the Exchange Rate in the Short Run

Chapter 2. Literature Review

Lectures µy, ε,weseethata

An Introduction to Basic Macroeconomic Markets

Macroeconomics II The Small Open Economy IS-LM - Mundell-Fleming Model

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Overborrowing, Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policy

Handout #7 A Fixed Price Model of Aggregate Output

Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control

Global Imbalances and Financial Fragility

Introduction: macroeconomic implications of capital flows in a global economy

Macro-Insurance. How can emerging markets be aided in responding to shocks as smoothly as Australia does?

Chapter 22 THE MUNDELL-FLEMING MODEL WITH PARTIAL INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY

Transcription:

u MMBH

Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/dualliquiditymodoocaba

1 i3i 1415 Dewe y >3 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series A DUAL LIQUIDITY MODEL FOR EMERGING MARKETS Ricardo J. Caballero Arvind Krishna murthy Working Paper 02-03 June 2002 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract= 2971 7

iv\ Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series A DUAL LIQUIDITY MODEL FOR EMERGING MARKETS Ricardo J. Caballero Arvind Krishnamurthy WORKING PAPER 02-03 January 2002 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge trom the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssm.com/abstract=xxxxx MASSACHUSETTS INS I OF TECHNOLOGY MAR 7 2002 LIBRARIES

A Dual Liquidity Model for Emerging Markets By Ricardo J. Caballero and Arvind Krishnamurthy 1 January 8, 2002 The last few years have seen a significant re-evaluation of the models used to analyze crises in emerging markets. Recent models typically stress financial constraints or distorted financial incentives. While this certainly represents progress, these models share a weakness with the earlier work: neither is uniquely about emerging markets. Adaptations of the Mundell-Fleming model represent Argentina as a Belgium with larger external shocks. Likewise, emerging market models of financial constraints are adaptations of developed economy ones with tighter financial constraints. In our work, we have advocated a model which distinguishes between the financial constraints affecting borrowing and lending among agents within an emerging economy, and those affecting borrowing from foreign lenders (Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2001a, b, c). Financial claims on future flows that can be sold to foreign and domestic lenders alike are labeled international liquidity, while those that can be sold solely to other domestic agents are labeled domestic liquidity. Belgium in our model is a country where most claims are international liquidity, while Argentina is a country where most claims are domestic liquidity. The dual liquidity model offers a parsimonious description of the behavior of firms, governments, and asset prices during financial crises. It also provides prescriptions for optimal policy responses to these crises. in a framework akin to the Mundell-Fleming model. This paper presents a simple sketch of our ideas The graphical analysis allows us to pose a rich array of questions and illustrates how our answers differ from standard ones. The welfare statements we make below hold up in specifications that are tighter than the model we deploy (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2001d). I International liquidity, domestic liquidity, and crises Let us simplify matters at the outset and assume that all private investment and public expenditure has to be financed from abroad. That is, I + G = CF where / is domestic investment, G is government expenditures, and CF is net capital inflows. The simplification highlights the impact of external shocks on investment. Respectively: MIT and NBER; Northwestern University. E-mails: caball@mit.edu, a- krishnamurthy@northwestern.edu. We are grateful to Guido Lorenzoni and Jaume Ventura for their comments. Caballero thanks the NSF for financial support.

There are two central assumptions in our analysis. The first one regulates the country's access to international financial markets, and the second one determines the functioning of domestic financial markets: An external crisis is a situation where CF is not enough to implement the desired levels of I + G. We assume that at the time of the crisis, claims on some special future cash flows ("international liquidity") is all that can be sold to foreigners. The country has a stock of international liquidity given by IL, and we require that, CF < IL, so that I + G < IL. Loans backed by international liquidity are at the international dollar-rate oil* Not all of the country's international liquidity is in the hands of those that use it in real investment. The latter need to borrow some of the international liquidity from other domestic agents. Their domestic liquidity or net worth, DL, regulates their borrowing from other domestic agents. DL includes marketable domestic assets, such as real estate and domestic financial assets. We assume that DL is a decreasing function of i p, the domestic peso-interest rate. 2,3 Let i d denote the interest rate faced by a firm when borrowing dollars (international liquidity) from other domestic agents. As we will see, this rate will generally be higher than Zq during a crisis. Under these assumptions, firms' investment is a decreasing function of d i and V. Since firms need to borrow dollars to finance investment, and i d is the dollar-cost-of-capital, a rise in d i lowers investment. Tighter monetary policy that is, an increase inz p causes DL to fall, constraining firms ability to borrow: Taking i p and G as given for now, Figure la illustrates our modeling of crises. On the horizontal axis is aggregate investment plus government expenditure. The limited international liquidity of the country is represented by the reversed-l shaped supply curve. A crisis is an event when the quantity of international liquidity is low relative to investment needs. An external shock decreases the available international liquidity, moving supply to the dashed line and reducing aggregate investment. I(i d,ip) + G = IL. (1) 2 See Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2001d) for a model connecting domestic liquidity, monetary policy, and investment. 3 Ben Bernanke and Alan Blinder (1988) also outline a model in which there are two forms of liquidity: bonds and bank-loans. However in their case the two liquidities are substitutes. In contrast, in our model there is a hierarchy: IL is ultimately what is needed for investment, while DL serves only to aggregate the IL of the economy.

Fixing In this crisis equilibrium, domestic firms finance investment by selling their domestically liquid assets in exchange for international liquidity. The price of the limited international liquidity d (i ) rises above ij$ to clear the market. Foreign investors do not arbitrage the difference of d i Iq because they are unwilling to exchange international liquidity for domestically liquid assets. In contrast, the lower panel represents a standard modeling of crises. The usual smallopen-economy assumption means that the supply of dollars is elastic at the international interest rate. The external shock is a rise in the interest rate (or risk premium) that raises i d from Iq to the dashed line (i*). Since the interest rate on borrowing dollars rises, investment falls. While for an appropriate rescaling the external shock leads to the same equilibrium levels of d i and / than in the dual liquidity economy, the fact that the supply of international funds is inelastic at the equilibrium point in the latter has important ramifications for what follows. II Domestic interest parity condition Let us now see how d i affects domestic asset prices. Consider the marginal domestic investor in the crisis equilibrium of Figure la with a unit of international liquidity (say, one dollar). There are two options available to the agent. The first is to lend this to a domestic firm and earn interest at the rate of d i one period hence. The second is to convert the dollar into pesos, at the exchange rate of e and invest these pesos in a domestic bond to earn interest of p i. the future exchange rate at e, and since the agent must be indifferent in equilibrium between the two strategies, we obtain a domestic interest parity condition: e Rewriting and dropping the higher order term, we arrive at: i d ^i p + e, (2) where e = e/e 1, is the expected appreciation of the domestic currency. A rise in i d, as in the external shock of Figure la, causes the exchange rate to depreciate in order to yield an expected appreciation. Alternatively, the monetary authority may defend the currency by raising the domestic interest rate of i p. If we replace the domestic bond in the previous argument with any (only) domestically liquid asset, then the rise in i d will result in the dollar-price of that asset to fall. The model thus provides a simple account of the fall in domestic asset prices and exchange rate depreciations accompanying external crises. It is also worth noting that the fall in domestic asset prices is due to an aggregate shortage of international liquidity, as opposed to a problem of domestic assets - i.e. the price of real estate falls not because real estate will generate less revenues in the future, but due to limited IL.

id, I(i d Jp) + G i d External Shock ; * J v ^ \. y ^v International Liquidity (a) Dual-liquidity model I + G (b) Standard model I + G Figure 1 : External Crises

Ill LM curve and Equilibrium The peso-interest rate i p is determined by a (nearly) conventional LM curve, L(i p, I + G) = M, (3) where we have used nominal money stock on the right-hand-side, as opposed to ^ or ^. Using real money stock does lead to some interesting issues when the central bank postcrisis inflation target is not credible (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2001d). But, for present purposes, it only complicates the analysis. ip M International Liquidity Constraint I + G Figure 2: Equilibrium Figure 2 depicts the equilibrium of (1) and (3). The curve IS' corresponds to a case where international liquidity is not scarce, while the dual liquidity model is represented by 75. The international liquidity is constrained in the vertical segment of the IS curve, and I + G is determined by IL as opposed to i p. Figure 2 along with Figure la describe the equilibrium of (I + G,i d,i p ). Combined with (2), this also describes the exchange rate. IV Monetary policy From the IS' curve we note the standard effect of monetary policy in models with financial constraints. An expansion in money, shifts out the LM curve, lowering i p. The latter raises firms' net worth and thereby relaxes their domestic financial constraint and facilitates investment. In our modeling of crises (IS), this logic does not apply. Monetary policy has no contemporaneous effect on investment. This is because we assumed that at the aggregate level investment was dependent only on IL during the crisis.

If we imagine an experiment where we increased the DL of a single firm, holding all other firm's DL fixed, it will be true that this firm's investment will raise. The firm will sell its extra DL for some IL and thereby increase its real investment. However, lowering i v has the effect of increasing all firm's DL. Since in aggregate IL is fixed, this action will only bid up the domestic price of international liquidity. It will shift up the I(i, rp) curve in Figure la, and raise d i. ip International Liquidity Constraint Figure 3: Interest and Exchange Rate Figure 3 illustrates the impact of monetary policy on exchange rates in our model. First, from (2), lowering i p while holding d i fixed leads to the standard exchange rate depreciation. This is the first segment in the downward-sloping curve. However, in our model, when IL is constrained, lowering i p also causes d i to rise. This shift in the domestic interest-parity condition reinforces the exchange rate depreciation. Thus the curve becomes flatter at this point (the second segment). 4 These last observations lead to an insight regarding monetary policy: If rather than expanding, the central bank tightens monetary policy during a crisis, it does not reduce investment further, but it does alleviate the exchange rate depreciation that a crisis-high d i would bring about. If the monetary authority is at all concerned about meeting an exchange rate/inflation target, it will tend to tighten monetary policy during a crisis. Thus our model rationalizes "fear of floating" as a positive description of central banks behavior in emerging markets (see Guillermo Calvo and Carmen Reinhart, 2000). 4 An interesting detour is obtained if we write the international liquidity constraint as I + G = IL(e). This is the case where devaluations may increase exports that count as international liquidity. In this case, loosening monetary policy depreciates the exchange rate and increases output, via relaxing the external constraint. On the other hand, one may also believe that DL is decreasing in e, perhaps because firm's have a substantial amount of dollar debt, so that devaluations decrease their net worth. In this case, the opposite conclusion may obtain if the decline in DL is sharp enough so that the country ends up wasting aggregate international liquidity (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2001b).

V Fiscal policy The model's implication for fiscal policy are also worth highlighting. In the standard Mundell-Fleming setup, an expansionary fiscal policy (right-shift in IS') raises p i and in the process partially crowds out I. The rise in the peso-interest rate appreciates the exchange rate. In the dual liquidity economy, fiscal policy competes with the private sector for international liquidity, and since IL is fixed it crowds out private investment one-for-one. An expansionary fiscal policy has no effect on the vertical part of IS. The competition for IL raises d i rather than i p. As a result, the domestic interest parity condition shifts from the (new) kink to the right and causes a depreciation of the exchange rate (see Figure 4). ip Figure 4: Expansionary Fiscal Policy The differences are even starker in a fixed exchange rate regime. In the standard model, fiscal policy is potent because it is reinforced by an endogenous expansion in monetary policy: The rise in i p tends to appreciate the exchange rate, which is offset only by a monetary expansion. In contrast, in the dual liquidity model the exchange rate tends to depreciate as a result of the fiscal expansion since i d rises, have to tighten to preserve the peg. and hence monetary policy will VI Overborrowing and Ex-ante Policy Options During a crisis, the stock of IL fully determines investment. Let us imagine shifting prior to the crisis, to a point in time where private and central bank actions may influence this stock. We will discuss two actions that may affect IL: private external borrowing, and central bank reserve accumulation. Define ILq as the initial international liquidity, Do as external debt, and Rq as foreign reserves accumulated. Normalizing the world gross interest

rate to one, we have IL = ILq - D + R - A private agent contemplating taking on some external debt and importing goods faces a tradeoff: Importing goods increases consumption or investment today, but reduces IL that would otherwise relax the aggregate investment constraint during the crisis. The agent values the latter benefit at d i. We have shown elsewhere (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2001a) that when domestic financial markets are underdeveloped there is an externality - akin to a free-rider problem - whereby the market value of this benefit, i d, is less than its social value. In this circumstance, the private sector overborrows and arrives at a crisis with too little IL. There are three basic instruments at the Central Bank's disposal to offset the tendency of the private sector. First, it can increase foreign reserves (Rq) and thereby increase IL. Our model provides a natural motivation for both centralized holding of reserves, as well holding them in the form of international liquidity. One concern here is that, in some circumstances, increasing Ro may in turn exacerbate the external overborrowing problem and raise Do (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2001c). Second, it can tax capital inflows and directly reduce Do, so as to increase IL. Of course, taxes may lead to other distortions. Third, and most interestingly, it can commit to expand monetary policy during the crisis just the opposite as it will be inclined to do during the crisis. Since lowering p i during the crisis raises i d, it increases the private sector's valuation of IL and alters the private sector's borrowing incentives.

References [1] Bernanke, Ben and Alan Blinder, "Credit, Money and Aggregate Demand," American Economic Review, May 1988, 75(2), pp. 435-439. [2] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy. "International and Domestic Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crises," Journal of Monetary Economics. December 2001a, 48(3), pp. 513-548. [3] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy, "Excessive Dollar Debt: Financial Development and Underinsurance." Mimeo, MIT, 2001b. [4] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy. "International Liquidity Illusion: On the Risks of Sterilization." Mimeo, MIT, 2001c. [5] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy. "A Vertical Analysis of Central Bank Interventions During Crises." Mimeo, MIT., 2001d. [6] Calvo, Guillermo, and Carmen Reinhart. "Fear of Floating." Mimeo, University of Maryland, 2000.

Date Due ^M/m Lib-26-67

MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02527 8851