Opening Remarks. Alan Greenspan

Similar documents
Overview. Stanley Fischer

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

One Policymaker s Wait for Better Economic Data

January minutes: key signaling language

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. Information Note on Modifications to the Fund s Debt Sustainability Assessment Framework for Market Access Countries

Macrostability Ratings: A Preliminary Proposal

A Robust Quantitative Framework Can Help Plan Sponsors Manage Pension Risk Through Glide Path Design.

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008

Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy. Remarks by. Richard H. Clarida. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Making Monetary Policy: Rules, Benchmarks, Guidelines, and Discretion

Remarks on Monetary Policy Challenges. Bank of England Conference on Challenges to Central Banks in the 21st Century

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001

Why Monetary Policy Matters: A Canadian Perspective

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. Consultative Document. Pillar 2 (Supervisory Review Process)

A Symposium Sponsored By The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City POLICY IMPLICATIONS OF TRADE AND CURRENCY ZONES

Mr. Greenspan considers the recent history of the Federal Reserve System s policy process

THE FED AND THE NEW ECONOMY

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

Improving the Use of Discretion in Monetary Policy

William C Dudley: Financial conditions indexes a new look after the financial crisis

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation

Remarks on Monetary Policy Challenges

The papers and comments presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of

Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Charles I Plosser: Strengthening our monetary policy framework through commitment, credibility, and communication

FINANCIAL SECURITY AND STABILITY

Risk aversion, Under-diversification, and the Role of Recent Outcomes

How Will the Federal Reserve Adjust Its Balance Sheet During Policy Normalization? 12/10/2015

Publication date: 12-Nov-2001 Reprinted from RatingsDirect

Minutes of the Monetary Policy Council decision-making meeting held on 6 July 2016

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

I should firstly like to say that I am entirely supportive of the objectives of the CD, namely:

Monetary policy under uncertainty

III Econometric Policy Evaluation

Apontamentos do Presidente do Banco Central do Brasil, Ilan Goldfajn.

Overview of Standards for Fire Risk Assessment

Brian P Sack: The SOMA portfolio at $2.654 trillion

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises

Endogenous risk in a DSGE model with capital-constrained financial intermediaries

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

Strengthening Our Monetary Policy Framework Through Commitment, Credibility, and Communication

Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules

William C Dudley: A bit better, but very far from best US economic outlook and the challenges facing the Federal Reserve

Márcio G. P. Garcia PUC-Rio Brazil Visiting Scholar, Sloan School, MIT and NBER. This paper aims at quantitatively evaluating two questions:

More on Modern Monetary Policy Rules

PIMCO s Asset Allocation Solution for Inflation-Related Investments

THE BENEFITS OF SYSTEMATIC MONETARY POLICY

25 October 2007 MICRO DATA NEEDS FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY ANALYSIS PANEL INTERVENTION AT WORKSHOP ON THE USE OF CORPORATE BALANCE SHEET DATA

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications

Mr. Greenspan reviews current monetary policy in the United States

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Brian P Sack: Implementing the Federal Reserve s asset purchase program

What Is the Best Strategy for Extending the U.S. Economy s Expansion?

Macro vulnerabilities, regulatory reforms and financial stability issues IIF Spring Meeting

Survey of Primary Dealers Markets Group, Federal Reserve Bank of New York October, 2012

FRBSF Economic Letter

What Operating Procedures Should Be Adopted to Maintain Price Stability? Practical Issues

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

EBA/GL/2013/ Guidelines

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

causing the crisis and what lessons can be drawn for its future conduct?

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Main Features. Aid, Public Investment, and pro-poor Growth Policies. Session 4 An Operational Macroeconomic Framework for Ethiopia

Financial Instrument Accounting

Outline. 1. Overall Impression. 2. Summary. Discussion of. Volker Wieland. Congratulations!

How to Extend the U.S. Expansion: A Suggestion

Economic Response Models in LookAhead

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Measuring farmers risk aversion: the unknown properties of the value function

Lucas Papademos: Central banks in the 21st century

Adopting Inflation Targeting: Overview of Economic Preconditions and Institutional Requirements

Independent Review of the Operation of Monetary Policy in New Zealand: Report to the Minister of Finance

Threading the Needle. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Managing the Uncertainty: An Approach to Private Equity Modeling

Remarks of Nout Wellink Chairman, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision President, De Nederlandsche Bank

EconomicLetter. Insights from the. Accounting For the Bond-Yield Conundrum

Sustainability of Earnings: A Framework for Quantitative Modeling of Strategy, Risk, and Value

BEYOND THE 4% RULE J.P. MORGAN RESEARCH FOCUSES ON THE POTENTIAL BENEFITS OF A DYNAMIC RETIREMENT INCOME WITHDRAWAL STRATEGY.

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Proposed International Standard on Auditing. Review of Interim Financial Information Performed by the Auditor of the Entity.

Review of the literature on the comparison

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

November minutes: key signaling language

Discussion of Fiscal Policy and the Inflation Target

Monetary Policy Objectives During the Crisis: An Overview of Selected Southeast European Countries

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Views on the Economic and Policy Outlook. Raphael Bostic President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

The Economic Effects of a Wealth Tax in Germany

The U.S. Economy: An Optimistic Outlook, But With Some Important Risks

Are We There Yet? The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Remarks by

Digitized for FRASER Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Eric S Rosengren: A US perspective on strengthening financial stability

Special Report. Using Dynamic Analysis Makes Tax Reform 30 Percent Less Challenging. Key Findings. August 2013 No. 210

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK Far out in the tails

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy

Supervisory Frameworks and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Transcription:

Opening Remarks Alan Greenspan Uncertainty is not just an important feature of the monetary policy landscape; it is the defining characteristic of that landscape. As a consequence, the conduct of monetary policy in the United States at its core involves crucial elements of risk management, a process that requires an understanding of the many sources of risk and uncertainty that policymakers face and the quantifying of those risks when possible. It also entails devising, in light of those risks, a strategy for policy directed at maximizing the probabilities of achieving over time our goal of price stability and the maximum sustainable economic growth that we associate with it. Toward that objective, we have drawn on the work of analysts who over the past half century have devoted much effort to improving our understanding of the economy and its monetary transmission mechanism. A critical result has been the identification of a relatively small set of key relationships that, taken together, provide a useful approximation of our economy s dynamics. Such an approximation underlies the statistical models that we at the Federal Reserve employ to assess the likely influence of our policy decisions. Despite the extensive efforts to capture and quantify these key macroeconomic relationships, our knowledge about many of the 1

2 Alan Greenspan important linkages is far from complete and in all likelihood will always remain so. Every model, no matter how detailed or how well designed conceptually and empirically, is a vastly simplified representation of the world that we experience with all its intricacies on a day-to-day basis. Consequently, even with large advances in computational capabilities and greater comprehension of economic linkages, our knowledge base is barely able to keep pace with the ever-increasing complexity of our global economy. Given this state of flux, it is apparent that a prominent shortcoming of our structural models is that, for ease in parameter estimation, not only are economic responses presumed fixed through time, but they are generally assumed to be linear. An assumption of linearity may be adequate for estimating average relationships, but few expect that an economy will respond linearly to every aberration. Although some nonlinearities are accounted for in our modeling exercises, we cannot be certain that our simulations provide reasonable approximations of the economy s behavior in times of large idiosyncratic shocks. Recent history has also reinforced the perception that the relationships underlying the economy s structure change over time in ways that are difficult to anticipate. This has been most apparent in the changing role of our standard measure of the money stock. Because an interest rate, by definition, is the exchange rate for money against non-monies, money obviously is central to monetary policy. However, in the past two decades, what constitutes money has been obscured by the introduction of technologies that have facilitated the proliferation of financial products and have altered the empirical relationship between economic activity and what we define as money, and in doing so has inhibited the keying of monetary policy to the control of the measured money stock. 1 Another example of ongoing structural change relates to innovations in mortgage finance. This includes the elimination of Regulation Q, the emergence of variable rate loans, the growth of the mortgagebacked securities market, and improvements in the efficiency of the

Opening Remarks 3 credit application process. These developments appear to have buffered activity in the housing market to some extent from shifts in monetary policy. But some of the same innovations in housing finance have opened new avenues of policy influence on economic behavior. For example, households have been able with increasing ease to extract equity from their homes, and this doubtless has helped support consumer spending in recent years, complementing the traditional effects of monetary policy. What then are the implications of this largely irreducible uncertainty for the conduct of monetary policy? A well-known proposition is that, under a very restrictive set of assumptions, uncertainty has no bearing on the actions that policymakers might choose, and so they should proceed as if they know the precise structure of the economy. 2 These assumptions linearity in the structure of the economy, perfect knowledge of the interest-sensitivity of aggregate spending and other so-called slope parameters, and a very specific attitude of policymakers toward risk are never met in the real world. Indeed, given our inevitably incomplete knowledge about key structural aspects of our ever-changing economy and the sometimes asymmetric costs or benefits of particular outcomes, a central bank seeking to maximize its probability of achieving its goals is driven, I believe, to a risk-management approach to policy. By this I mean that policymakers need to consider not only the most likely future path for the economy but also the distribution of possible outcomes about that path. They then need to reach a judgment about the probabilities, costs, and benefits of the various possible outcomes under alternative choices for policy. A policy action that is calculated to be optimal based on a simulation of one particular model may not, in fact, be optimal once the full extent of uncertainty in the policymaking environment is taken into account. In general, it is entirely possible that different policies will exhibit different degrees of robustness with respect to the true underlying structure of the economy. For example, policy A might be judged

4 Alan Greenspan as best advancing the policymakers objectives, conditional on a particular model of the economy, but might also be seen as having relatively severe adverse consequences if the true structure of the economy turns out to be other than the one assumed. On the other hand, policy B might be somewhat less effective in advancing the policy objectives under the assumed baseline model but might be relatively benign in the event that the structure of the economy turns out to differ from the baseline. These considerations have inclined Federal Reserve policymakers toward policies that limit the risk of deflation even though the baseline forecasts from most conventional models would not project such an event. At times, policy practitioners operating under a risk-management paradigm may be led to undertake actions intended to provide some insurance against the emergence of especially adverse outcomes. For example, following the Russian debt default in the fall of 1998, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) eased policy despite our perception that the economy was expanding at a satisfactory pace and that, even without a policy initiative, was likely to continue to do so. 3 We eased policy because we were concerned about the low-probability risk that the default might severely disrupt domestic and international financial markets, with outsized adverse feedback to the performance of the U.S. economy. The product of a low-probability event and a severe outcome, should it occur, was judged a larger threat than the possible adverse consequences of insurance that might prove unnecessary. The cost or premium of the financial-contagion insurance was the associated increase in the risk of higher inflation at some future date. This cost was viewed as relatively low at the time, largely because increased competition, driven by globalization, thwarted employers ability to pass through higher labor costs into prices. Given the Russian default, the benefits of the unusual policy action were deemed to outweigh its costs. Such a cost-benefit analysis is an ongoing part of monetary policy decisionmaking, and tips more toward monetary ease when the

Opening Remarks 5 fallout from a contractionary event such as the Russian default seems increasingly likely and its occurrence seems especially costly. Conversely, in 1979, with inflation threatening to get out of control, the cost to the economy of a major withdrawal of liquidity was judged far less than the potential long-term consequences of leaving accelerating prices unaddressed. In implementing a risk-management approach to policy, we must confront the fact that only a limited number of risks can be quantified with any confidence. And even these risks are generally quantifiable only if we accept the assumption that the future will replicate the past. Other risks are essentially unquantifiable representing Knightian uncertainty, if you will because we may not fully appreciate even the full range of possibilities, let alone each possibility s likelihood. As a result, risk management often involves significant judgment on the part of policymakers, as we evaluate the risks of different events and the probability that our actions will alter those risks. For such judgment, we policymakers, rather than relying solely on the specific linkages expressed in our formal models, have tended to draw from broader, though less mathematically precise, hypotheses of how the world works. For example, inference of how market participants might respond to a monetary policy initiative may need to reference past behavior during a period only roughly comparable to the current situation. Some critics have argued that such an approach to policy is too undisciplined judgmental, seemingly discretionary, and difficult to explain. The Federal Reserve should, some conclude, attempt to be more formal in its operations by tying its actions solely to the prescriptions of a formal policy rule. That any approach along these lines would lead to an improvement in economic performance, however, is highly doubtful. Our problem is not the complexity of

6 Alan Greenspan our models but the far greater complexity of a world economy whose underlying linkages appear to be in a continual state of flux. Rules by their nature are simple, and when significant and shifting uncertainties exist in the economic environment, they cannot substitute for risk-management paradigms, which are far better suited to policymaking. Were we to introduce an interest rate rule, how would we judge the meaning of a rule that posits a rate far above or below the current rate? Should policymakers adjust the current rate to that suggested by the rule? Should we conclude that this deviation is normal variance and disregard the signal? Or should we assume that the parameters of the rule are misspecified and adjust them to fit the current rate? Given errors in our underlying data, coupled with normal variance, we might not know the correct course of action for a considerable time. Partly for these reasons, the prescriptions of formal interest rate rules are best viewed only as helpful adjuncts to policy, as indeed many proponents of policy rules have suggested. In summary then, monetary policy based on risk management appears to be the most useful regime by which to conduct policy. The increasingly intricate economic and financial linkages in our global economy, in my judgment, compel such a conclusion. Over the next couple of days, we will have the opportunity to consider in greater detail some important changes in our economic and financial systems and their implications for the conduct of monetary policy. As always, I look forward to an engaging discussion.

Opening Remarks 7 Endnotes 1 Nonetheless, in the tradition of Milton Friedman, it is difficult to disregard the long-run relationship between money and prices. In particular, since 1959 unit money supply, the ratio of M2 to real GDP, has increased at an annual rate of 3.7 percent and GDP prices have risen 3.8 percent per year. (A consistent time-series for M2 is available back to 1959. Among other changes, deposit data at a daily frequency were incorporated in measures of the monetary aggregates as of that date.) 2 William Brainard, Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy, American Economic Review, May 1967, pp. 411-25. 3 See minutes of the FOMC meeting of September 29, 1998.