Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

Similar documents
Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Modelling Inflation Uncertainty Using EGARCH: An Application to Turkey

Bayesian Estimation of the Markov-Switching GARCH(1,1) Model with Student-t Innovations

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence

Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Fiscal Multipliers in Good Times and Bad Times

Volume 29, Issue 2. Measuring the external risk in the United Kingdom. Estela Sáenz University of Zaragoza

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Time series: Variance modelling

Oil Price Effects on Exchange Rate and Price Level: The Case of South Korea

MODELING VOLATILITY OF US CONSUMER CREDIT SERIES

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Modelling the stochastic behaviour of short-term interest rates: A survey

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Short-selling constraints and stock-return volatility: empirical evidence from the German stock market

Financial Econometrics

Experience with the Weighted Bootstrap in Testing for Unobserved Heterogeneity in Exponential and Weibull Duration Models

Discussion of Tracking Monetary-Fiscal Interactions across Time and Space

Sustainability of Current Account Deficits in Turkey: Markov Switching Approach

Modelling house price volatility states in Cyprus with switching ARCH models

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime

Volatility Spillovers and Causality of Carbon Emissions, Oil and Coal Spot and Futures for the EU and USA

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Commentary: Using models for monetary policy. analysis

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

GARCH Models for Inflation Volatility in Oman

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Chapter 1. Introduction

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach

Regime-dependent Characteristics of KOSPI Return

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Macro News and Exchange Rates in the BRICS. Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Fabio Spagnolo and Nicola Spagnolo. February 2016

Course Outline and Reading List

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

RETURNS AND VOLATILITY SPILLOVERS IN BRIC (BRAZIL, RUSSIA, INDIA, CHINA), EUROPE AND USA

Escaping the Great Recession 1

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Running head: IMPROVING REVENUE VOLATILITY ESTIMATES 1. Improving Revenue Volatility Estimates Using Time-Series Decomposition Methods

Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Midterm

RISK SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN THE CZECH FINANCIAL MARKET

A Simple Recursive Forecasting Model

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

MONETARY POLICY IN POLAND HOW THE FINANCIAL CRISIS CHANGED THE CENTRAL BANK S PREFERENCES

Modeling the volatility of FTSE All Share Index Returns

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

The Monetary Transmission Mechanism in Canada: A Time-Varying Vector Autoregression with Stochastic Volatility

Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession:

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Assessing Regime Switching Equity Return Models

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Volatility in the Indian Financial Market Before, During and After the Global Financial Crisis

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Empirical Analysis of Stock Return Volatility with Regime Change: The Case of Vietnam Stock Market

Optimal fiscal policy

Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme

Asian Economic and Financial Review A REGRESSION BASED APPROACH TO CAPTURING THE LEVEL DEPENDENCE IN THE VOLATILITY OF STOCK RETURNS

Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle

EXPECTATIONS AND THE IMPACTS OF MACRO POLICIES

A joint Initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität and Ifo Institute for Economic Research

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

The Zero Lower Bound

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Discussion of Corsetti, Meyer and Muller, What Determines Government Spending Multipliers?

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence.

Introductory Econometrics for Finance

Was the Recovery Due More to Demand or Supply Shocks?

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Transcription:

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities Libo Xu and Apostolos Serletis Department of Economics University of Calgary Calgary, Alberta T2N 1N4 Forthcoming in: Economics Letters June 12, 2016 Abstract This paper extends the ongoing literature on regime change. The extension allows time variation in disturbance variances of interest rate rules for monetary policy and tax rules for fiscal policy that switch stochastically between two regimes. We achieve superior modelings of monetary and fiscal policy rules with quarterly U.S. data. JEL classification: C22; C24; E42; E52; E62. Keywords: Monetary-fiscal interactions, Regime-switching, GARCH. We would like to thank a referee for comments that greatly improved the paper. Corresponding author. Phone: (403) 220-4092; Fax: (403) 282-5262; E-mail: Serletis@ucalgary.ca; Web: http://econ.ucalgary.ca/profiles/apostolos-serletis 1

1 Introduction In a series of recent papers, Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011) and Chung et al. (2007) resolve an inconsistency in the literature pertaining to the assumption that policy regimes are fixed and analyze the implications of regime switching. In doing so, they investigate how the impacts and analysis of macropolicies can change in environments in which policy regimes evolve according to a Markov process. In particular, they consider interest rate rules for monetary policy and tax rules for fiscal policy that switch stochastically between two regimes. In one regime monetary policy follows the Taylor (1993) principle (raising the nominal interest rate by more than any expected rise in inflation) and taxes rise strongly with increases in the real value of government debt; in another regime monetary policy does not follow the Taylor principle and taxes follow an exogenous stochastic process. Although Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011) and Chung et al. (2007) allow for heteroscedastic errors across regimes, they assume homoscedastic errors within regimes. In this paper, we follow Sims and Zha (2006) who argue that heteroscedastic errors are essential for fitting U.S. time series, and relax the assumption that the variance of the errors in each regime is constant and instead introduce time variation in disturbance variances, as in Cai (1994), Hamilton and Susmel (1994), Gray (1996), and Dueker (1997). We apply Bollerslev s (1986) generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (GARCH) model and achieve superior modeling of parametric (monetary and fiscal) policy regime-switching rules in which the unconditional variance is constant but the conditional variance, like the conditional mean, is a random variable depending on current and past information. The outline of the paper is as follows. In Section 2 we present the regime-switching GARCH model of macro policies with time-varying disturbance variances. In Section 3 we discuss the data and presents the estimation results. The final section briefly concludes the paper. 2 Switching-Regime GARCH Macro Policies Chung et al. (2007) and Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011) consider a standard Taylor (1993) monetary policy rule i t = a 0 (s m,t ) + a 1 (s m,t )π t + a 2 (s m,t )y t + ε m,t (1) where i t is the nominal interest rate, π t the inflation rate, y t the output gap, ε m,t = hm (s m,t )ɛ t and ɛ t iid N(0, 1). s m,t indicates the unobservable monetary policy regime, and is assumed to follow a first order, homogenous, two-state Markov chain governed by the transition matrix ( ) pm,11 p Π m = m,12 p m,21 p m,22 2

where p m,ij = P [s m,t = j s m,t 1 = i], i, j = 1, 2, and p m,11 = 1 p m,21 and p m,12 = 1 p m,22. Chung et al. (2007) and Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011) also consider the following fiscal policy rule τ t = α 0 (s f,t ) + α 1 (s f,t )b t 1 + α 2 (s f,t )y t + α 3 (s f,t )g t + ε f,t (2) where τ t is the lump-sum taxes-to-output ratio, b t the debt-to-output ratio, g t the government purchases-to-output ratio and ε f,t = h f (s f,t )ɛ t. s f,t is the unobservable fiscal policy regime, assumed to also follow a first order, homogenous, two-state Markov chain. The corresponding transition matrix is ( ) pf,11 p Π f = f,12 p f,21 p f,22 where p f,ij = P [s f,t = j s f,t 1 = i], i, j = 1, 2, and p f,11 = 1 p f,21 and p f,12 = 1 p f,22. Equation (1) suggests that monetary policy responds to the inflation rate, π t, and the output gap, y t, differently in different regimes, since a 1 (s m,t ) and a 2 (s m,t ), respectively, vary across regimes. Also, equation (2) suggests that fiscal policy responds to the lagged debt-to-output ratio, b t 1, the output gap, y t, and the government purchases-to-output ratio, g t, differently in different regimes, since α 1 (s f,t ), α 2 (s f,t ) and α 3 (s f,t ), respectively, vary across regimes. In this paper, we relax the assumption that the variance of the errors in each regime is constant and instead assume that it is time-varying. In particular, we assume the following conditional variance equation for monetary policy h m,t (s m,t ) = b 0 (s m,t ) + b 1 (s m,t )ε 2 m,t 1 + b 2 (s m,t ) h m,t 1 (3) where h m,t 1 denotes the regime-independent variance, as in Gray (1996) who uses this approach to remove the path-dependence in the regime-switching GARCH estimation. We also assume the following conditional variance equation for fiscal policy h f,t (s f,t ) = β 0 (s f,t ) + β 1 (s f,t )ε 2 f,t 1 + β 2 (s f,t ) h f,t 1 (4) where h f,t 1 is the regime-independent variance of fiscal policy. 3 Data and Estimation Results We use quarterly data for the United States over the period from 1949:Q1 to 2015:Q2. However, in estimating the monetary policy rule, equations (1) and (3), we only use data from 1960:Q1 to 2007:Q4, thus excluding the period before the 1960s with different approaches to monetary policy and the zero lower bound period after 2008 during which monetary policy has been passive. We use the same time series as in Davig and Leeper (2011). In particular, the nominal interest rate, i t, is the three-month Treasury bill rate in the secondary market. We define π t to be the inflation rate over the past four quarters, with the inflation rate calculated as 3

the log difference in the GDP deflator. The output gap, y t, is the log deviation of nominal GDP from potential nominal GDP, τ t is the nominal GDP share of federal tax receipts net of total federal transfer payments, b t 1 is the lagged nominal GDP share of the market value of privately held gross federal debt over the past four quarters, and g t is the nominal GDP share of federal government consumption expenditures and gross investment. The three-month Treasury bill rate and the GDP deflator are obtained from the Federal Reserve Economic Database (FRED) maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The potential nominal GDP series is obtained from the Congressional Budget Offi ce and the privately held gross federal debt series from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Finally, the nominal GDP, federal tax receipts, total federal transfer payments, government consumption expenditures, and gross investment series are all obtained from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. To validate our regime-switching conditional heteroscedasticity models of the policy rules, we first estimate equations (1) and (2) under the assumption of homoscedastic errors and test for ARCH effects in the residuals using Engle s (1982) Lagrange multiplier test. However, this test cannot be applied to the estimated errors directly, since the errors are regimedependent. As suggested by Daniel (2008), we follow Gourieroux et al. (1987) and calculate the regime-independent generalized errors which are the expected errors conditional on lagged information. We apply the Engle (1982) ARCH test to the generalized errors and find significant ARCH effects up to 10 lags in both policy rules. We therefore proceed to estimate regime-switching conditional heteroscedasticity models. Parameters estimates of the regime-switching GARCH models, equations (1) and (3) and (2) and (4), are presented in Tables 1 and 2 for monetary and fiscal policy, respectively; the estimated transition probabilities are also shown in panel C. As shown in panel A of Table 1, monetary policy fluctuates between being active, responding strongly to inflation consistent with the Taylor principle (ˆα 1 = 1.655 with a p-value of 0.000), and being passive, not responding in accordance with the Taylor principle (ˆα 1 = 0.691 with a p-value of 0.000). Moreover, passive monetary policy responds almost twice as strongly to the output gap (ˆα 2 = 0.203 in the passive regime while ˆα 2 = 0.127 in the active regime), suggesting that the Fed pays less attention to inflation stabilization, consistent with Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011). Regarding fiscal policy, as shown in panel A of Table 2, it breaks into periods when it is active, responding negatively to debt (ˆα 1 = 0.004 with a p-value of 0.000), and periods when it is passive, responding positively to debt (ˆα 1 = 0.017 with a p-value of 0.000). Also, consistent with Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011), active tax policy reacts strongly to government spending, but by less than one-to-one (ˆα 3 = 0.901 with a p-value of 0.000), while passive tax policy reacts more weakly to government spending (ˆα 3 = 0.396 with a p-value of 0.000). Finally, in both regimes, tax policy reacts positively to the output gap, y t ; ˆα 2 = 0.262 with a p-value of 0.000 in the active regime and ˆα 2 = 0.345 with a p-value of 0.000 in the passive regime. 4

Figures 1 and 2 show the smoothed probabilities of active and passive monetary and fiscal policy, respectively; these probabilities are reported at time t, conditional on the full sample information. In particular, the smoothed probabilities are highly consistent with Davig and Leeper (2007) and their interpretation of the evidence. For example, our estimates show that fiscal policy was active in the first half of the 1980s when the Reagan Administration s Economic Recovery Plan of 1981 was implemented. However, the probability of passive tax policy significantly increased by the mid-1980s. The reason is that legislation was passed in 1982 and 1984 to raise revenues in response to the rapidly increasing debt-output ratio. Moreover, as can be seen in Figure 2, fiscal policy has been active in the aftermath of the global financial crisis, consistent with the fact that in response to the global financial crisis, in October 2008, the U.S. Congress passed the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act, establishing a $700 billion bailout program known as the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP). Moreover, in February 2009, the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act was passed, a $787 billion fiscal stimulus package. In panel B of Table 1, we find evidence of positive and statistically significant ARCH effects in both monetary policy regimes, but a positive and statistically significant GARCH effect only in the active regime. The most striking finding is the very high ARCH coeffi cient on ε 2 m,t 1 when monetary policy is passive (ˆb 1 = 1.068 with a p-value of 0.000) relative to when it is active (ˆb 1 = 0.488 with a p-value of 0.000). This suggests that when monetary policy is passive, monetary policy volatility reacts intensely to monetary shocks. In the case of fiscal policy, as can be seen in panel B of Table 2, we find evidence of positive and statistically significant ARCH effects (of similar magnitude) in both regimes, but not evidence of GARCH effects. 4 Robustness and Shortcomings To address the issue of whether our model is over-parameterized, for each of the monetary and fiscal policy rules we turn off regime changes in policy and GARCH errors, but permit the variance of the policy shock to vary across regimes. For example, in the case of monetary policy we estimate the rule i t = a 0 + a 1 π t + a 2 y t + ε m,t where ε m,t = h(s ε,t )ɛ t, ɛ t iid N(0, 1), and s ε,t indicates the unobservable monetary policy shock regime assumed to follow a first order, homogenous, two-state Markov chain. We take a similar approach regarding the fiscal policy rule. This allows discontinuous regime switching in residuals, instead of GARCH, to capture changes in the shock variance that are very abrupt and discontinuous. We use the Bayes factor to conduct model comparison, since the unrestricted and restricted models are not 5

nested. In particular, the Bayes factor (BF) is BF = Pr (Data Unrestricted model ) Pr (Data Restricted model ). According to Kass and Raftery (1995), the logarithm of the Bayes factor could be approximated using Schwarz s Bayesian information criterion (BIC), as follows 2 ln BF = (BIC of Unrestricted model BIC of Restricted model), and if 2 lnbf > 10 then the superiority of the unrestricted model is decisive. In our case, with the monetary policy rule, 2 lnbf = 209.376, and with the fiscal policy rule, 2 lnbf = 169.214, suggesting that the regime-switching GARCH model of monetary and fiscal policy is superior compared to its restricted version. We would like to note that our simple two-equation model of monetary and fiscal policy rules may suffer from endogeneity and misspecification. In particular, the independent variables at time t, such as output, inflation, and government spending, in regression equations (1) and (2) are endogenously determined. Estimating the policy rules as part of a large system of equations, as in Sims and Zha (2006), or solving rational expectations models, as in Farmer et al. (2009, 2010), will address this problem. However, the focus of our paper is the econometric modeling of time-varying volatility, following existing empirical works by Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011), and we ignore these issues. Our results may not stand when the endogeneity and misspecification issues are taken care of, but we leave this as an area for potentially productive future research. 5 Conclusion This paper extends the ongoing literature on regime change initiated by Lucas (1976), building on Sims and Zha (2006), Davig and Leeper (2007, 2011), and Chung et al. (2007). The extension allows time variation in disturbance variances of interest rate rules for monetary policy and tax rules for fiscal policy that switch stochastically between two regimes. We achieve superior modeling of monetary and fiscal policy rules with quarterly U.S. data. References [1] Bollerslev, T. Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity. Journal of Econometrics 31 (1986), 307-27. [2] Cai, J. A Markov Model of Switching-Regime ARCH. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics 12 (1994), 309-316. 6

[3] Chung, H., T. Davig, and E.M. Leeper. Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39 (2007), 809-842. [4] Daniel, R.S. Evaluating Specification Tests for Markov-Switching Time-Series Models. Journal of Time Series Analysis 29 (2008), 629-652. [5] Davig, T. and E.M. Leeper. Fluctuating Macro Policies and the Fiscal Theory. In D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2006. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press (2007), pp. 247-298. [6] Davig, T. and E.M. Leeper. Monetary-Fiscal Policy Interactions and Fiscal Stimulus. European Economic Review 55 (2011), 211-227. [7] Dueker, M.J. Markov Switching in GARCH Processes and Mean-Reverting Stock- Market Volatility. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics 15 (1997), 26-34. [8] Engle, R.F. Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflation. Econometrica 50 (1982), 987-1007. [9] Farmer, R.E., D.F. Waggoner, and T. Zha. Understanding Markov-Switching Rational Expectations Models. Journal of Economic Theory 144 (2009), 1849-1867. [10] Farmer, R.E., D.F. Waggoner, and T. Zha. Generalizing the Taylor Principle: Comment. American Economic Review 100 (2010), 608-617. [11] Gourieroux, C., A. Monfort, E. Renault, and A. Trognon. Generalized Residuals. Journal of Econometrics 34 (1987), 5-32. [12] Gray, S.F. Modeling the Conditional Distribution of Interest Rates as A Regime- Switching Process. Journal of Financial Economics 42 (1996), 27-62. [13] Kass, R.E. and A.E. Raftery Bayes Factors. Journal of the American Statistical Association 90 (1995), 773-795. [14] Hamilton, J.D. and R. Susmel. Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Changes in Regime. Journal of Econometrics 64 (1994), 307-333. [15] Lucas, Jr., R.E. Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1 (1976), 104 30. Amsterdam: North-Holland. [16] Sims, C.A. and T. Zha. Were There Regime Switches in U.S. Monetary Policy? American Economic Review 96 (2006), 54-81. [17] Taylor, J.B. Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39 (1993), 195-214. 7

Table 1. Switching-Regime GARCH Model of Monetary Policy Monetary policy Coe cient Active Passive A. Conditional mean equation a 0 0:030 (0:000) 0:025 (0:000) a 1 1:655 (0:000) 0:691 (0:000) a 2 0:127 (0:000) 0:203 (0:000) B. Conditional variance equation b 0 0:000 (0:001) 0:000 (0:006) b 1 0:488 (0:000) 1:068 (0:000) b 2 0:064 (0:013) 0:000 C. Transition probabilities P s m;t = active js m;t 1 = passive 0:016 (0:000) P s m;t = active js m;t 1 = active 0:935 (0:000) Notes: Sample period, quarterly data, 1960:Q1-2007:Q4. A coe cient of 0.000 indicates that the nonnegativity constraint is binding. Numbers in parentheses are p-values.

Table 2. Switching-Regime GARCH Model of Fiscal Policy Fiscal policy Coe cient Active Passive A. Conditional mean equation 0 0:001 (0:000) 0:025 (0:000) 1 0:004 (0:000) 0:017 (0:000) 2 0:262 (0:000) 0:345 (0:000) 3 0:901 (0:000) 0:396 (0:000) B. Conditional variance equation 0 0:000 (0:013) 0:000 (0:002) 1 0:774 (0:000) 0:756 (0:000) 2 0:090 (0:328) 0:064 (0:296) C. Transition probabilities P s f;t = active js f;t 1 = passive 0:054 (0:001) P s f;t = active js f;t 1 = active 0:923 (0:000) Notes: Sample period, quarterly data, 1949:Q1-2015:Q2. Numbers in parentheses are p-values.

Figure 1. Monetary Regime Probabilities 1.00 Probabilities of active monetary policy 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 1.00 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Probabilities of passive monetary policy 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

Figure 2. Fiscal Regime Probabilities 1.00 Probabilities of active fiscal policy 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 1.00 Probabilities of passive fiscal policy 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015