Demographic Transition, Consumption and Capital Accumulation in Mexico

Similar documents
Socioeconomic Differences in the Distribution by Age of Public Transfers in Mexico

Overview of Demographic Dividend. Andrew Mason Demographic Dividend Working Group Barcelona, Spain June 5 8, 2013

WESS Background Paper. Population Aging, Wealth, and Economic Growth: Demographic Dividends and Public Policy 1

Will Population Change be Good or Bad for the World s Economies?

Reform and support systems for the elderly in developing countries: capturing the second demographic dividend *

DYNAMIC DEMOGRAPHICS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN VIETNAM

Volume Title: The Economic Consequences of Demographic Change in East Asia, NBER-EASE Volume 19

National Transfer Accounts and the Demographic Dividend: An Overview

Dynamic Demographics and Economic Growth in Vietnam. Minh Thi Nguyen *

ISSUE BRIEF #1. Population Aging and the Global Economy: Weakening Demographic Tailwinds Reduce Economic Growth. Abstract.

Sustainable Economic Policies in an Aging World

Demographic Situation: Jamaica

Reformulating the Support Ratio to Reflect Asset Income and Transfers (Extended Abstract)

Economic Lifecycle and Demographic Dividends: Evidence and Implications for India

Generational Transfers and Population Aging in Latin America

THE NEWLY-EMERGING PATTERN OF FAMILIAL TRANSFERS IN AGING JAPAN

National Transfer Accounts: DATA SHEET 2011

The Economic Lifecycle and Population Age Structure:

ADB Economics Working Paper Series. Demographic Dividends for India: Evidence and Implications Based on National Transfer Accounts

Capturing the Demographic Dividend: Experience from South East Asian Countries

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital

Population Aging and the Generational Economy: A Global Perspective

Aging, Economic Growth and Old- Age Security in Asia

Increase in Life Expectancy: Macroeconomic Impact and Policy Implications

BULLETIN. Lower-Income Countries and the Demographic Dividend

Labor and Consumption across the Lifecycle

Intergenerational Transfers and National Transfer Accounts in East Asia. Andrew Mason University of Hawaii at Manoa East-West Center

Economic Inequality and Intergenerational Transfers: evidence from Mexico

How Population Aging Affects the Macroeconomy

Economic Life Cycle Deficit and Intergenerational Transfers in Italy: An Analysis Using National Transfer Accounts Methodology

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POPULATION AGING. David N. Weil. Working Paper

The Effect of Education on the Demographic Dividend

Indonesia Social Security and Support System of the Indonesian Elderly. Preliminary Draft January 20th, 2008 (not for citation) Maliki

Fiscal Sustainability Report 2017

CHAPTER 03. A Modern and. Pensions System

Population aging, intergenerational transfers, and economic growth: Latin America in a Global Context

Global Aging and Financial Markets

Fertility, Human Capital, and Economic Growth over the Demographic Transition

Impact of the demographic transition and its consequences for the achievement of the SDGs in El Salvador. July 2018

How Rich Will China Become? A simple calculation based on South Korea and Japan s experience

Transfers, Capital, and Consumption over the Demographic Transition: An International Comparison

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

MONEY SUPPLY ROLE IN ECONOMIC AND INDUSTRIAL GROWTH: THE CASE OF JORDAN ( )

Ageing and retirement security: United States, Mexico and Mexican Americans

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2017) All rights reserved

Demographic Dividend or Demographic Threat in Pakistan?

Long-Term Fiscal External Panel

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2018) All rights reserved

The Public Reallocation of Resources across Age: A Comparison of Austria and Sweden

Public Sector and Population Aging. 10 th Global NTA Meeting Beijing, China Andrew Mason

Very Low Fertility and the High Costs of Children and the Elderly in Japan and Selected Asian Countries: An NTA Approach

China s Age of Abundance: Tracking changes with NTA Analyses

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

Human capital, fertility decline, and economic development: the case of Costa Rica since 1950.

AGING, ECONOMIC GROWTH, AND OLD-AGE SECURITY IN ASIA

Population aging and the generational economy: Key findings

1 What does sustainability gap show?

Economic Effects of a New York Minimum Wage Increase: An Econometric Scoring of S6413

Volume Title: The Economic Consequences of Demographic Change in East Asia, NBER-EASE Volume 19

"The Demographic Transition and Economic Growth in the Pacific Rim" Andrew Mason. University of Hawaii - Manoa and East-West Center.

Economic Development: Theory and Policy

Retirement, Pension Reform, and Pension Transfer Wealth: An International Comparison

ECONorthwest ECONOMICS FINANCE PLANNING

Consequences of the Demographic Transition. Econ/Demog c175 Prof. Goldstein Week 6, Lecture B UC Berkeley Spring 2019

Inter-individual variation in lifetime accumulation of income, consumption, and transfers in aging countries

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

The Fiscal Impact of Population Aging: Accounting for the Role of Demography NTA Working Paper WP

Intergenerational transfer systems and cohort-crowding

Who will support the elderly? Changing economic lifecycle reallocation in an Asian economy

Depopulation and importance of agriculture in Japan: implications from the overlapping generations and general equilibrium growth accounting model

NATIONAL (TIME) TRANSFER ACCOUNTS WORKSHOP

Aging, Family Support Systems, Saving and Wealth: Is Decline on the Horizon for Japan?

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Field guide to available DD models

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts

The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility

Life Cycle Saving and the Demographic Transition in East Asia

New perspectives from NTA: Fiscal policy, social programs, and family transfers

Mr. Chairman, Senator Conrad, and other distinguished members of the Committee,

MEASURES TO DEAL WITH AN AGING POPULATION: INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCES AND LESSONS FOR CUBA

Rotorua Lakes District Population Projections

Age Distribution of Taxes and Social Benefits by Income Deciles: Evidence from Mexico

The impact of the demographic bonus in the pension systems of social security ACT. DANIELA ALEJANDRA GONZÁLEZ RAMÍREZ ACT. CARLOS CONTRERAS CRUZ

Fertility, Human Capital, and Economic Growth over the Demographic Transition

Dr Agnieszka Chłoń-Domińczak Institute of Statistics and Demography Warsaw School of Economics

The Euro Area s Long-Term Growth Prospects: With and Without Structural Reforms

Influence of demographic factors on the public pension spending

Who Gains from the Demographic Dividend? Forecasting Income by Age. Sang-Hyop Lee and Andrew Mason

National Transfer Accounts

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

The World Bank FPD Note No. 9 June 1994

Growth Accounting: A European Comparison

Demographics and Macroeconomics: Opportunities and Risks in Dividend-Era Argentina

Average real family incomes rose in Costa Rica in the late 1990s

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Population Dynamics and Household Saving: Evidence from the Philippines

Population Ageing and Changes in the Role of Public and Private Transfers

REPUBLIC OF BULGARIA. Country fiche on pension projections

Health Insurance Coverage in 2013: Gains in Public Coverage Continue to Offset Loss of Private Insurance

Transcription:

Demographic Transition, Consumption and Capital Accumulation in Mexico Iván Mejía-Guevara, Virgilio Partida, and Félix Vélez Fernández-Varela Extended abstract submitted for EPC 2012 October 14, 2011 As age distribution of the population change, the ratio of income to consumption, the support ratio, varies along the demographic transition period. A transitory gain results when the proportion of prime-age adult population increases more rapidly than both young and elderly groups. A sustained period of high consumption, a second dividend, could be maintained even after the period of favorable support ratio vanishes, provided the consumption of elderly relies on capital deepening rather than on transfers. The decision on which mechanism followed to sustain consumption of the elderly is a matter of public policy. We analyze these hypotheses for the case of Mexico, based on estimates obtained from an interdependent altruistic sharing theoretical approach. We report evidence for a second demographic dividend, its timing and magnitude when we assume changes in current and future policy decisions. Introduction Changes in age population structure along the demographic transition opens a window of opportunity because there is a period when the effective number of producers increases more rapidly than the effective number of consumers. However, this phenomenon, also known as the first demographic dividend, is transitory because reduced fertility rates and increments in life expectancy, that lead to population aging, will contribute in the extinction of the window of opportunity. A second demographic dividend would appear if adequate policy is followed, where accumulation of assets is privileged upon familial or governmental transfers as a mechanism for supporting the elderly. When this condition holds, the second dividend will not have the transitory condition of the first dividend in that sustained consumption would be possible for a long period of time (Mason and Lee, 2006b). Recent evidence shows that only few countries have taken advantage of the demographic transition period and they have translate it into sustained economic growth rates. Investment in human capital, proper policies to incentive employment and technological progress have made this possible. The most prominent cases reported in the literature are countries within the southeast Asia (Bloom y Williamson, 1998; Mason, Merrick y Shaw, 1999; Mason, 2001). For the Latin America region, the evidence suggests that, although its demographics resembled those of east Asia, its economic performance lagged well behind (Bloom and Canning, 2004). The authors argue that the lack of proper economic and political conditions have prevented many countries of the region from exploiting its demographic window of opportunity. The Mexican case is a good example, since the first dividend has been substantial but, low productivity, 1

recurrent economic crisis, and the proliferation of the informal economy in recent years, have impeded the country to take proper advantage of it (Mejia-Guevara et al., 2010). Concerning the second dividend, Mason and Lee(2006a) present evidence showing that changes in the population age structure can lead to a substantial and permanent increase in assets per capita and, for a closed economy, in capital per worker, leading to higher per capita income and higher consumption than otherwise, although differences among countries might have different impacts depending on several factors. The authors support these findings using evidence from Nigeria, Taiwan and the United States, three countries that represent different degrees of development. In this article, we elaborate on Mason and Lee (2006a) to find evidence about how present conditions and prospectives for Mexico would be favorable for the arise of a second demographic dividend. We estimate the future accumulation of capital relative to expected income levels and the conditions for which a long period of sustained consumption is possible when population aging accelerates in Mexico. The analysis is based mainly on the results of an interdependent altruistic sharing approach, as well as inputs and estimates derived from a National Transfer Account (NTA) analysis for Mexico. Methodology Labor income and consumption In the methodology for estimating the first and second dividends, labor income and consumption age profiles are the key elements. We take estimates of these profiles from Mejía-Guevara (2001), which follows the methodology of the NTA project (http://www.ntaccounts.org). Trajectories of labor income and consumption are constructed for simulations where, in the trajectory of labor income, the model assumes that income will be increased at a rate of technological progress; whereas, the trajectory of consumption is consider endogenous. Labor income: In the NTA framework, labor income represents a comprehensive measure of output attributed to labor, which is defined as all compensation to workers, including earnings, the portion of entrepreneurial income which is a return to labor (assumed to be two-thirds), fringe benefits, and taxes paid to the government by employers on behalf of employees. Consumption: Under the same framework, household consumption is allocated by each member of the household and distributed by age over the lifecycle. The consumption by an individual is defined as the sum of private and public consumption, each of which is further disaggregated into education, health care and other consumption. The model Using labor income and consumption age profiles we can compute the effective number of producers and the effective number of consumers. The effective number of producers 2

(consumers) result from the sum of the labor income (consumption), weighted by the age structure of the population. The first dividend arises when the number of producers is growing faster than the effective number of consumers. A second dividend arises when changes in age structure and the increase in life expectancy lead to a more rapid accumulation of assets. However, the central condition for the realization of the second dividend consist on sacrificing consumption in the present in order to increase wealth and consumption in the future. In this model, a trajectory of labor income and consumption is constructed, where an index of consumption, c(t), is defined as the ratio of the consumption to labor income. The support ratio is defined as well as the number of effective producers per effective consumer. Then, the first dividend is defined as follows: an increase in the support ratio would lead to higher consumption during the demographic transition period, but population aging would lower the support ratio and, consequently, reduce the consumption. Mason and Lee (2004a) argue that if the index of consumption declines as the support ratio increases, [c]urrent per capita consumption would rise by less than the support ratio, but saving rates would increase, assets held by future generations would rise, and, if assets were domestically invested, labor productivity and wages would increase... But whether assets were invested domestically or abroad higher levels of consumption could be sustained in the future. In this response rests the possibility for a second demographic dividend.... We elaborate under this hypothesis for the case of Mexico. The central idea is that future consumption is not possible without the creation of wealth, defined as net claim of future consumption, which can be generated in the form of assets (e.g. private savings, funded pensions, etc.) or transfer wealth (present value of net transfers received from familial support systems and public programs). The lifecycle wealth of adults can be disaggregated into child wealth (present value of the net cost to supporting children) and pension wealth (wealth used to fund consumption at older ages). Pension wealth consists of assets and pension transfer wealth. The key assumption is, then, to keep the ratio of assets and pension wealth constant throughout the period of prospective (a constant tau), since it is not possible to know exactly how the consumption needs of the aged population will be financed in the future: through transfers or through contributory systems or private savings?. This will depend on how policies and institutions develop over coming decades. Therefore, for an exogenous transfer policy (assuming a constant tau) and for each endogenous path of consumption, the model will find a trajectory of assets. The rate of return on assets will determine the feasibility of the trajectory of consumption (Mason and Lee, 2004a). Preliminary results Preliminary results are shown in Figures 1 to 4 below. A baseline consists on assuming that the consumption of elderly will rely 50% on assets and 50% on transfers (tau=0.5). Under this 3

assumption, the index of consumption will be always above the support ratio, which will start declining around 2026; in other words, the first demographic dividend would vanish around that time. The index of income also supports this evidence. The trajectory of consumption will start accelerating just before the declining of the support ratio and, after the declining in the consumption, it will maintain a constant difference with respect to the support ratio along the period of analysis (Figure 1). As aging process accelerates in Mexico, life-cycle wealth follows an increasing trajectory which reach its maximum around 2060, then declining steadily until the end of the period. The maximum value reached by the lifecycle wealth is around 3.5 times of labor income, which declines later on to stay at the level equivalent to 3 times of that figure. The trajectory of assets also increases during the transition process, but on an slower rate, to reach a level slightly above 1.5 times the labor income around 2060, to remain constant from there. The declining of fertility and the aging process will be the reason for a decrease in the demand for lifecycle wealth of children, which starts declining since the beginning of the XXI century to reach a minimum, just below 1 time the labor income, around the year 2100, keeping similar levels, with small variations, afterwards (see Figure 2). By measuring the rate of consumption to labor income during the period of analysis, we observe a steady increase until 2050, where consumption reaches levels 10% higher than labor income, a value that is held for 50 years and then decreased to a value of 5% above the same figure. When consumption is measured as a proportion of the GDP, we observe the same pattern of increment, where consumption will peak close to 100% of GDP, and then decreased slightly afterwards. National savings, in turn, will follow an opposite path, starting at levels around 6% of national output at the beginning of the XXI century, to systematically reduce until reaching values close to zero around the year 2075, rising again thereafter, to reach a steadily 2% of GDP over the next 100 years (Figure 3). Figure 4 shows three scenarios for how the consumption of the elderly could be supported. In the first scenario, 65% of this consumption relies on transfers (blue line). The baseline scenario represents the case where half of the consumption is financed by assets and the remaining half through transfers (green line). The third scenario represents the case in which 35% of consumption is financed through transfers (red line). It is clear in the graph that the policy in which the accumulation of assets is privileged over transfers leads to higher outcomes in the long run. Results are expected to be more refined in the final version of the article. We also expect to have a deeper analyses that consider specific conditions and better assumptions of the Mexican economy, mainly related to changes in productivity and labor markets from recent times and in the future. 4

Blibliography Bloom, David E., and J. G. Williamson (1998), Demographic transitions and economic miracles in emerging Asia, World Bank Economic Review, vol. 12, No 3. Bloom, David, and David Canning (2004). Global Demographic Change: dimensions and economic significance. Technical Report 10817, NBER. Available at: www.nber.org/papers/w10817. Mason, Andrew, Thomas Merrick, and R. Paul Shaw (eds.) (1999), Population economics, demographic transition, and development: research and policy implications, WBI Working Papers, Washington, D.C., World Bank Institute (WBI). Maso, A. (2001), Population Change and Economic Development in East Asia: Challenges Met, Opportunities Seized. Stanford, Stanford University Press. Mason, Andrew. 2005. Demographic Transition and Demographic Dividends in Developed and Developing Countries. United Nations Expert Group Meeting on Social and Economic Implications of Changing Population Age Structures. Mason, A., and Ronald Lee (2006a). Transfers, Capital, and Consumption over the Demographic Transition, in Robert Clark, Andrew Mason, and Naohiroo Ogawa (eds.). Population Aging, Intergenerational Transfers and the Macroeconomy, Pp. 128-162. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Mason, A., and Ronald Lee (2006b). "Reform and Support Systems for the Elderly in Developing Countries: Capturing the Second Demographic Dividend." GENUS LXII(2): 11-35. Mejía-Guevara, I. (2011). The Economic Lifecycle and Intergenerational Redistribution in Mexico. In Ronald Lee and Andrew Mason, leader authors and editors, Population aging and the generational economy: A global perspective. Edward Elgar Publishing, Oxford, UK. Mejía-Guevara, I., Félix Vélez Fernández Varela, and Juan Enrique García (2010). El Primer Dividendo Demográfico y los Sistemas de Protección Social en México. [The First Demographic Dividend and and the Social Support Systems in Mexico]. Notas de Población No. 90. CEPAL. 5

Figure 1. Support ratio, index of consumption, income in Mexico. 6

Figure 2. Simulated support ratio, index of consumption, income in Mexico 7

Figure 3. Simulated support ratio, index of consumption, income in Mexico 8

Figure 4. Simulated support ratio, index of consumption, income in Mexico 9