Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Similar documents
Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic Risk and the Business Cycle: A Likelihood Perspective

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009.

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

On modelling of electricity spot price

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Kaplan, Moll and Violante: Unconventional Monetary Policy in HANK

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW MUCH CONSUMPTION INSURANCE BEYOND SELF-INSURANCE? Greg Kaplan Giovanni L. Violante

Notes on Estimating Earnings Processes

STUDIES ON EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF MA Title MODELS WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then

Time-Varying Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Consumption Dynamics

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Firm Dispersion and Business Cycles: Estimating Aggregate Shocks Using Panel Data

Excess Smoothness of Consumption in an Estimated Life Cycle Model

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/05

The Intertemporal Keynesian Cross. Auclert-Rognlie-Straub

Partial Insurance. ECON 34430: Topics in Labor Markets. T. Lamadon (U of Chicago) Fall 2017

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Firm Dispersion and Business Cycles: Estimating Aggregate Shocks Using Panel Data

Macroeconomic Cycle and Economic Policy

O PTIMAL M ONETARY P OLICY FOR

Informational Assumptions on Income Processes and Consumption Dynamics In the Buffer Stock Model of Savings

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

ARCH Models and Financial Applications

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Optimal Life-Cycle Investing with Flexible Labor Supply: A Welfare Analysis of Default Investment Choices in Defined-Contribution Pension Plans

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Balance Sheet Recessions

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Introduction to DSGE Models

Generalized Dynamic Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering the Market Volatility Shocks

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Market Risk Analysis Volume II. Practical Financial Econometrics

How Much Consumption Insurance in Bewley Models with Endogenous Family Labor Supply?

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Sources of Lifetime Inequality

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Nonlinear household earnings dynamics, self-insurance, and welfare

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Identifying Household Income Processes Using a Life Cycle Model of Consumption

Markov-Chain Approximations for Life-Cycle Models

What Can a Life-Cycle Model Tell Us About Household Responses to the Financial Crisis?

Romania s accession to the Eurozone a simulation using a simple DSGE model

The Buffer Stock Model and the Aggregate Propensity to Consume. A panel-data study of US States.

Excess Smoothness of Consumption in an Estimated Life Cycle Model

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

The Cross-Sectional Implications of Rising Wage Inequality in the United States

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

HARD VS. SOFT FINANCIAL CONSTRAINTS IMPLICATIONS FOR THE EFFECTS OF A CREDIT CRUNCH

Housing Prices and Growth

Dynamic Macroeconomics

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

The Marginal Propensity to Consume Out of Credit: Deniz Aydın

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management. > Teaching > Courses

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

MODELLING VOLATILITY SURFACES WITH GARCH

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Transcription:

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013

Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic income changes. - Consumption responds to anticipated income changes. - Large literature on models of incomplete markets. - Most incomplete markets models allow only self insurance. - Some aspects of data point to households having more insurance (Blundell et al., 2008; Heathcote et al., 2012). - Other aspects suggest households have less (Kaplan and Violante, 2011). - How do these issues relate to the aggregate consumption data? 2 / 28

Incomplete markets and the aggregate data - Incomplete markets models: Attractive micro-foundations given evidence above. But not in the standard toolkit of empirical macroeconomics. - Representative agent models: formal interpretation of time series data. Many aggregate shocks give rich covariance structure. Judge the model on full range of empirical implications (An and Schorfheide, 2007). This paper: take incomplete markets models to the data using same techniques as for rep. agent framework. 3 / 28

Results - Standard incomplete markets model fits the data much better than representative agent model. - Allowing for partial insurance against skill shocks leads to even better fit. - Extending the model to match the response of consumption to fiscal stimulus payments does not improve fit. 4 / 28

Model: preferences and insurance Unit mass of households with preferences: Budget constraint: E 0 t=0 β t c1 χ i,t 1 χ. a + c = y t (e, s) + (1 + r)a a 0. Income-pooling insurance scheme: [e + b u (1 e)]s 1 bs y t (e, s) = [ej,t + b u (1 e j,t )]s 1 bs j,t dj e j,t w t s j,t dj, b s = b u = 0: no insurance y t (e, s) = w t es. b s = b u = 1: full insurance y t (e, s) = aggregate income. 5 / 28

Model: aggregate shocks Aggregate wage process: Log wage: log w t = z t + A t + ɛ T t, Trend growth: z t = z t 1 + g, Persistent shock: A t = ρ A A t 1 + ɛ A t, Transitory shock: ɛ T t. Aggregate employment conditions: Job finding rate: λ t = (1 ρ λ ) λ + ρ q λ t 1 + ɛ λ t. Job separation rate: ζ t = (1 ρ ζ ) ζ + ρ ζ ζ t 1 + ɛ ζ t. All aggregate shocks are Gaussian with mean zero. 6 / 28

Model: idiosyncratic shocks - Constant transition matrix across three skill levels. - Income process calibrated to match (Domeij and Heathcote, 2004): autocorrelation and dispersion of wages in PSID realistic distribution of wealth: Gini and Lorenz(0.4). - Unemployment risk correlated with skill: ζ t,s = ζ t + ζ s. - Dispersion in unemployment risk calibrated using unemployment by education. 7 / 28

Methods: overview - Solve the model using Reiter (2009) algorithm large-scale linear state-space representation of aggregate economy. - Reduce model dimension using balanced truncation medium-scale linear state-space representation of aggregate economy. - Proceed with standard techniques used on representative agent models: Kalman filter computes likelihood of data. Easily calculate moments, impulse responses, spectral density matrices. 8 / 28

Methods: solving the model Solve the model using Reiter (2009) algorithm: - discretize distribution of wealth with a histogram with many bins, - discretize savings policy rules with splines with many knots, - express equilibrium conditions as a system of equations (> 3, 600 in all), F (X t, X t+1, η t+1, ɛ t+1 ) = 0, - linearize around stationary equilibrium using automatic differentiation (normalized by trend, no aggregate shocks), - solve linear rational expectations model with standard methods X t+1 = Ψ X X t + Ψ ɛ ɛ t+1. - X contains aggregate variables of interest: use an observation matrix, H, to select them. 9 / 28

Methods: reducing the model Reduce model dimension using balanced truncation: - most of X t is not needed for calculating the dynamics of our objects of interest with high accuracy dimensions in which X t varies little. dimensions in which variation has small effect on HX t t. - Balanced truncation eliminates states that are not needed for these reasons. - Large literature on reduction of linear systems (Antoulas, 2009). - Explicit bounds on accuracy of reduced system. - Steps above can be implemented easily with Matlab Control System Toolbox. 10 / 28

Methods: taking model to data Proceed with standard techniques used on representative agent models: - Likelihood function shape of the likelihood is the basis for maximum likelihood and Bayesian estimation. computed with the Kalman filter. - Watson s (1993) measure of fit find the smallest measurement error to reconcile model and data autocovariances report measurement error variance relative to data variance similar to 1 R 2 from linear regression computed frequency by frequency from spectral density matrices. 11 / 28

Methods: advantages and disadvantages Advantages: - Reiter method easily extends to many aggregate states. Allows for many persistent aggregate shocks as is common in empirical DSGEs. - Reiter method easily extends to rich aggregate features. General equilibrium. Nominal rigidities (McKay and Reis, 2013). - Resulting linear state-space representation facilitates statistical analysis. Disadvantages: - Solution may not be accurate if shocks move the economy far from steady state. - Will discuss accuracy checks after results. 12 / 28

Data Aggregate data from 1966:I to 2012:III: - consumption of non-durables and services, - labor income net of taxes and government transfers, - a measure of short-term unemployment, - a measure of long-term unemployment. Consumption and income are real, per capita, 100 log( ). 13 / 28

Symbol Parameter Value Target/Prior Panel A. Objects of interest b u Unemployment insurance 0.3 b s Skill insurance 0 Panel B. Calibrated for each specification β Discount factor 0.971 Aggregate assets 5 annual income. Panel C. Calibrated on balanced growth path χ Risk aversion 2 r Interest rate 0.0075 3% annual interest rate. λ Avg. job finding rate 0.679 Mean long-term unemployment. ζ Avg. high-skill job separation rate 0.037 Mean short-term unemployment. Panel D. Estimated driving processes g Trend income growth 0.004 Uniform[0,1]. ρ A Autoregressive coefficient of A 0.951 Beta: mn. = 0.5, var. = 0.04 ρ λ Autoregressive coefficient of λ 0.920 Beta: mn. = 0.5, var. = 0.04 ρ ζ Autoregressive coefficient of ζ 0.924 Beta: mn. = 0.5, var. = 0.04 σ A Standard deviation of ɛ A 1.040 Inverse Gamma: mn. = 1, var. = 4 σ λ Standard deviation of ɛ λ 2.591 Inverse Gamma: mn. = 1, var. = 4 σ ζ Standard deviation of ɛ ζ 0.432 Inverse Gamma: mn. = 1, var. = 4 σ T Standard deviation of ɛ T 0.290 Inverse Gamma: mn. = 1, var. = 4 Table: Parameter values, targets and priors for the low-insurance economy. 14 / 28

0.06 λ job-finding 0.2 ζ job-separation 0.05 0.04 0.15 0.03 0.1 0.02 0.01 0.05 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 0.4 0.3 A wage (pers.) 0.025 0.02 T wage (trans.) Low insurance Full insurance 0.2 0.015 0.01 0.1 0.005 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 Notes: 100 log change in response to one standard deviation shock. The plot for ζ shows a negative shock to ζ. 15 / 28

A. Standard deviation C t Y t u short t u long t Data 0.535 1.029 0.921 1.143 Low-insurance 0.262 1.231 0.939 0.948 Full-insurance 0.066 1.231 0.939 0.948 B. Correlation of C t with Y t u short u long Data 0.271-0.339 0.064 Low-insurance 0.800-0.038-0.012 Full-insurance 0.789 0.001-0.001 C. Autocorrelation of C t Lags 1 2 3 4 Data 0.407 0.199 0.130 0.062 Low-insurance 0.096 0.083 0.073 0.066 Full-insurance -0.001 0.000 0.001 0.005 16 / 28

Model and data spectral densities 17 / 28

Watson s measure of fit Ratio of residual variance to data variance: C t Y t u short t u long t Low-insurance 0.591 0.127 0.225 0.266 Full-insurance 0.882 0.118 0.218 0.264 18 / 28

Likelihood of the data: stochastic singularity - Stochastic singularity occurs when the model-implied covariance matrix for observables is singular. - Not obviously the case here because four shocks and four observables. - But no shock directly explains independent movements in consumption growth. - Add i.i.d. measurement error to consumption growth. 19 / 28

Likelihood of the data σ v Low-insurance Full-insurance Difference 0.1-2324.1-2639.9 315.8 0.2-875.6-894.7 19.1 0.3-612.7-614.8 2.1 0.4-543.1-542.7-0.4 0.5-526.8-526.1-0.7 0.52714-526.3 0.52722-525.6 20 / 28

Partial insurance Watson s measure of fit Std. dev. log L b s b u C t Y t u short t u long t C t (σ v = 0.1) 0 0.3 0.591 0.127 0.225 0.266 0.262-2324 0 0.6 0.606 0.127 0.224 0.266 0.258-2335 0.5 0.3 0.548 0.128 0.227 0.265 0.305-2180 0.5 0.6 0.574 0.128 0.226 0.265 0.297-2230 0.9 0.3 0.761 0.120 0.220 0.265 0.133-2474 0.9 0.6 0.783 0.120 0.220 0.265 0.124-2515 1 1 0.882 0.118 0.218 0.264 0.066-2640 21 / 28

Matching evidence on response to fiscal stimulus payments - Kaplan and Violante (2011) criticize the standard incomplete markets model for failing to match the way consumption responds to fiscal stimulus payments. - Their solution: illiquid assets are less useful for smoothing consumption. - Incorporate their idea with a quadratic adjustment cost on household asset positions. - Calibrate the adjustment cost to match regression estimates from Johnson et al. (2006) in simulated data. Rebate coefficient = 0.25; Johnson et al. find 0.2 to 0.4. MPC out of unanticipated transitory income fluctuations = 0.20. 22 / 28

0.06 λ job-finding 0.15 ζ job-separation 0.05 0.04 0.1 0.03 0.02 0.05 0.01 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 0.3 0.25 A wage (pers.) 0.04 0.03 T wage (trans.) Adjustment cost Baseline 0.2 0.15 0.02 0.1 0.05 0.01 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 23 / 28

Matching evidence on response to fiscal stimulus payments Watson s measure of fit Std. dev. log L C t Y t u short t u long t C t (σ v = 0.1) Baseline low-insurance 0.591 0.127 0.225 0.266 0.262-2324 Asset adjustment cost 0.589 0.130 0.227 0.266 0.309-2466 Log-likelihood disagrees with other metrics here. 24 / 28

Accuracy - Compare solution from Reiter method (with and without model reduction) to fully non-linear solution. - To apply standard non-linear methods: assume λ t and ζ t are perfectly negatively correlated, ignore transitory wage shock, simplify the income process. - Approximate aggregate shocks with Rouwenhorst (1995) algorithm. - Find policy rules with endogenous grid method (Carroll, 2006). - Simulate all three solutions with same shock sequence. 25 / 28

A. Mean relative to trend ( 100) C t Y t u short t u long t Non-linear 0.000-0.001 6.293 3.180 Reiter 0.000-0.001 6.325 3.003 Reiter-reduced 0.000-0.001 6.325 3.003 B. Standard deviation ( 100) C t Y t u short t u long t Non-linear 0.233 1.229 0.867 1.312 Reiter 0.263 1.223 0.869 1.272 Reiter-reduced 0.263 1.223 0.869 1.272 C. Correlation of C t with Y t u short u long Non-linear 0.764-0.059-0.050 Reiter 0.773-0.037-0.028 Reiter-reduced 0.773-0.037-0.028 D. First-order autocorrelation C t Y t u short t u long t Non-linear 0.133 0.033 0.893 0.968 Reiter 0.096 0.028 0.893 0.969 Reiter-reduced 0.096 0.028 0.893 0.969 26 / 28

Summary - Full-information analysis of incomplete markets models now possible. - Incomplete markets fit data much better than complete markets. - Partial insurance against skill shocks fit the aggregate data best as has found in panel data. - Micro evidence on consumption response to transitory income shocks need not invalidate standard incomplete markets model as a model of consumption dynamics in general but this evidence is important for how aggregate consumption responds to transitory shocks. 27 / 28

An, S. and Schorfheide, F. (2007). Bayesian analysis of dsge models. Econometric Reviews, 26(2-4):113 172. Antoulas, A. C. (2009). Approximation of large-scale dynamical systems, volume 6. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics. Blundell, R., Pistaferri, L., and Preston, I. (2008). Consumption inequality and partial insurance. American Economic Review, 98(5):1887 1921. Carroll, C. D. (2006). The method of endogenous gridpoints for solving dynamic stochastic optimization problems. Economics Letters, 91(3):312 320. Domeij, D. and Heathcote, J. (2004). On the distributional effects of reducing capital taxes. International economic review, 45(2):523 554. Heathcote, J., Storesletten, K., and Violante, G. L. (2012). Consumption and labor supply with partial insurance: An analytical framework. Research Department Staff Report 432, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Johnson, D. S., Parker, J. A., and Souleles, N. S. (2006). Household expenditure and the income tax rebates of 2001. American Economic Review, 96(5):1589 1610. Kaplan, G. and Violante, G. L. (2011). A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments. Working Paper 17338, National Bureau of Economic Research. McKay, A. and Reis, R. (2013). The role of automatic stabilizers in the u.s. business cycle. Working Paper 19000, National Bureau of Economic Research. Reiter, M. (2009). Solving heterogeneous-agent models by projection and perturbation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33(3):649 665. Rouwenhorst, K. G. (1995). Asset Pricing Implications of Equilibrium Business Cycle Models., chapter 10, pages 294 330. Princeton:. Watson, M. W. (1993). Measures of fit for calibrated models. Journal of Political Economy, 101(61). 28 / 28