Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

Similar documents
The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity

The Elasticity of Taxable Income in New Zealand

The Elasticity of Taxable Income in New Zealand

ECONOMIC SURVEY OF NEW ZEALAND 2007: TWO BROAD APPROACHES FOR TAX REFORM

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

The Marginal Cost of Public Funds in Closed and Small Open Economies

Deadweight Loss and the Cost of Public Funds in Australia

Tax (Non)-Compliance Research: A New Zealand Perspective

Measuring Revenue-Maximising Elasticities of Taxable Income: Evidence for the US Income Tax

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

Labour Supply and Taxes

Income Tax and Small Businesses in Scotland

The New Zealand tax system and how it compares internationally

Modelling the distributional aspects of KiwiSaver: methodology and results

Efficiency of the Tax System: a marginal excess burden analysis

SPECIAL REPORT. The Excess Burden of Taxes and the Economic Cost of High Tax Rates

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

Class 13 Question 2 Estimating Taxable Income Responses Using Danish Tax Reforms Kleven and Schultz (2014)

TAXABLE INCOME RESPONSES. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for MSc Public Economics (EC426): Lent Term 2014

pwc.co.nz Tax Tips October 2017 In this issue: What the election results mean from a tax perspective

WikiLeaks Document Release

Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes

Thinking Through the Economic Consequences of Higher Taxes

The CPI purpose and definition - the Australasian Debate

The theory of taxation/3 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.15 Rosen) Desirable characteristics of tax systems (optimal taxation)

COMMENTS ON SESSION I: TAXATION AND THE LABOUR MARKET. Lucio R. Pench *

Tax and Economic Growth

Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

THIS PAPER HAS TWO SECTIONS. THE FIRST

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

Labour Market Responses to the Abolition of Compulsory Superannuation

Cap deductions only for interest and depreciation, not for investment (inv) financed by retained earnings (earlier profit). Corp tax favors debt finan

THE VOODOO ECONOMICS OF PHASING OUT OKLAHOMA S PERSONAL INCOME TAX: Kent Olson, Professor of Economics Emeritus, Oklahoma State University

Taxable income elasticities and the deadweight cost of taxation in New Zealand* Alastair Thomas** Policy Advice Division, Inland Revenue Department

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency

Fiscal Drag and Trans-Tasman Income Differentials

Glossary. Average household savings ratio Proportion of disposable household income devoted to savings.

THE ELASTICITY OF TAXABLE INCOME Fall 2012

Analysis of capital gains tax changes

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

Submission to the Federal Tax Discussion Paper. Prepared by the Urban Development Institute of Australia (UDIA)

FISCAL FACT Top Marginal Effective Tax Rates By State under Rival Tax Plans from Congressional Democrats and Republicans

GPP 501 Microeconomic Analysis for Public Policy Fall 2017

Paper for New Agenda for Prosperity, the University of Melbourne, 28 March 2008 Reforming State Taxes John Freebairn The University of Melbourne

Environmental Policy in the Presence of an. Informal Sector

Modelling of the Federal Budget Personal Income Tax Measures

Comparison of the Coalition Federal Budget Income Tax Measures and the Labor Proposal

TRANSFER PRICING AND INTANGIBLES: SCOPE OF THE OECD PROJECT

BEPS, SPILLOVERS, ETC.: CURRENT ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE TAXATION

The tax status of credit unions

The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in Open Economies

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April Lower Personal Income Tax Rates. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne

Feldstein Proposal Increases Federal Revenues but the Devil s in the Details

The Economics of Public Policy 11. Tax Incidence and the Excess Burden of Taxation

Income Taxation and Stochastic Interest Rates

Review of the thin capitalisation rules

Coversheet: Business tax

Factors influencing the reliability of policy proposal costings. Technical note no. 01/2017 Date issued: 13 September 2017

Impact of removing stamp duties on insurance. Insurance Council of Australia

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Allowing for Endogeneity and Income Effects

MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL:

1 Excess burden of taxation

Topic# 3: General Theory of Taxation. Romanian tax system General theory of taxation PROF. ANDREEA STOIAN, PHD LECTURE 5

Session three: Revenue Raising and Base Broadening 16 September 2009

Annex: Alternative approaches to corporate taxation Ec426 Lecture 8 Taxation and companies 1

Hybrid and branch mismatch rules

Working paper No.14. Devolved income tax: forecasting by tax bands

HC 486 SesSIon October HM Revenue & Customs. Engaging with tax agents

ECON 4624 Income taxation 1/24

CHANGING THE TAXATION REGIME FOR INVESTORS IN THE HOUSING MARKET

Recent GST Reforms and Proposals in New Zealand

Corporate Taxation. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

The Effects of Ageing on the Financing of Social Health Provision. Chris Heady 26 th March 2013

Introduction and Literature Model and Results An Application: VAT. Malas Notches. Ben Lockwood 1. University of Warwick and CEPR. ASSA, 6 January 2018

Diverted Profits Tax. Key points

STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAXES GENERALLY

Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel

CGT AND COMPLIANCE COSTS ARE A DOUBLE TAX ON NZ BUSINESSES

CHAPTER 17: PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION

Coversheet: Company tax rate issues further information

Saving, wealth and consumption

GST: A Review. A Government discussion document

The international mobility of tax bases: An introduction

Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low

The Danish Experience With A Financial Activities Tax

REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013

Labour Supply Elasticities in New Zealand

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley PE Handbook Conference, Berkeley December 2011

Università degli Studi di Roma Tor Vergata Facoltà di Economia Area Comunicazione, Stampa, Orientamento. Laudatio.

Lecture 4: Taxation and income distribution

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

Results are preliminary. Comments welcome.

The Elasticity of Taxable Income During the 1990s: A Sensitivity Analysis

Transcription:

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand Background paper for Session 5 of the Victoria University of Wellington Tax Working Group October 2009 Prepared by the New Zealand Treasury 0

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand A Summary for the Tax Working Group Background In two non technical papers (and a further two more extensive, technical papers) prepared as background for the Tax Working Group, 1 Professor John Creedy summarises two areas of literature. These are (i) the distortionary costs of taxation; and (ii) recent approaches to estimating the responsiveness of taxpayers taxable incomes to changes in marginal rates of taxation. The latter can be used directly as an input into calculations of the distortionary or deadweight costs of income taxation. The discussion below extracts some material from these papers and provides a range of possible estimates of the distortionary costs of income taxes in New Zealand (Tables 1 & 2). Introduction Direct and indirect taxes distort individuals' behaviour. This means that there is an intangible efficiency cost, or distortionary cost, imposed on individuals in addition to the direct burden of a tax. The direct burden is measured simply by the amount of tax paid. The excess burden, or distortionary cost, of a tax is the extent to which the total money measure of the welfare loss to individuals and groups in society from the tax exceeds the tax paid. These distortionary costs reflect the fact that taxpayers rearrange their affairs in ways that are different and less desirable than they would in the absence of taxation. They may often (but need not) be associated with reduced output, or reduced tax revenue (compared to when there are no distortions), or increased administrative costs. To the extent that taxpayers also engage in rent seeking activity as they try to influence government to set taxes in ways that minimise their personal tax liabilities, there can be additional deadweight costs. The benefits thought to arise from taxation (and the government expenditure it funds) therefore need to be compared with this `excess burden' created by the distortion. In proposing tax cuts or increases, it would be useful to have information on the expected excess burden from the change in relation to the extra revenue to be collected. This gives rise to the concept of the marginal excess burden per dollar of extra revenue: it is referred to as the `marginal welfare cost' (MWC) of the tax change. Despite the central importance of the MWC concept there have been relatively few empirical studies, perhaps in part because these efficiency costs are not directly observable. They are also often neglected in policy debates. Given difficulties in estimating these welfare costs of taxes a commonly discussed approximation is that the excess burden of a tax change increases approximately in proportion to the square of the tax rate. That is, as the tax rate doubles, the excess burden quadruples. This approximation is too crude to be useful as a measure of the consequences of specific, more detailed tax policy changes but it serves to highlight the fact that, in general, as tax rates are increased, the distortionary impacts will worsen more than proportionately. 1 See Creedy (2009a, b). The two more technical papers are Creedy (2009c, d). All four papers were commissioned by the New Zealand Treasury in 2009. 1

This means that any erosion of the tax base, which requires a higher tax rate than otherwise if revenue is to remain unchanged, creates higher burdens. This is one important reason why the oftencited rule of thumb, that a special case needs to be made when departing from a `broad base and low rate', receives so much support. The square of the tax rates approximation may also suggest a generalisation regarding comparisons between income taxation and consumption taxes. A broad based goods and services tax (like the GST in New Zealand) which has very few exemptions, and has a relatively low rate, may be expected to give rise to lower efficiency costs than income taxation, which is imposed at higher rates and is not as broad based. The Elasticity of Taxable Income (ETI) In recent years a method has been proposed to estimate the way in which overall taxable income responds to incentive effects created by income taxation. This involves the concept of the elasticity of taxable income with respect to the net of tax rate (ETI), defined as the proportional change in declared taxable income (for a specified population group) resulting from a proportional change in the `net of tax' rate (one minus the marginal tax rate). This elasticity aims to capture all potential responses to income taxation in a single measure, without the need to specify the nature of the various different types of response such as labour supply changes, income shifting between sources which are taxed at different rates, and tax evasion through non declaration of income. The ETI has the added attraction that, under certain assumptions, it can be used to obtain a measure of the efficiency or deadweight costs of income taxation, such as the marginal welfare cost (the marginal excess burden per extra dollar of revenue raised). The ETI is defined by: ETI percentage change in taxable income percentage change in 'net of tax' rate 1 In a complex income tax system with many rates and thresholds, this elasticity may be very different for different individuals at various income levels. However the approach of recent literature has been to estimate the ETI for a specified group of individuals (e.g. those on, or close to, the top tax rate) and examine observed change in taxable income in association with changes in this rate. The methodologies used are subject to several criticisms and should be interpreted cautiously. This may also explain why results for apparently similar groups of (mainly US) taxpayers can be very different. The ETI depends in part on the details of the tax legislation in place (e.g. the ease of switching legally between personal and corporate tax regimes), so that the elasticity may itself be a policy variable. One implication of this is that a suitable policy response to a high elasticity could be lower tax rates or modifications to tax legislation to reduce incentives to shift income. Further, the ETI may not remain constant over time if regulations are changed, and values estimated for one country and tax regime cannot simply be expected to hold in other countries. Estimating the Elasticity of Taxable Income Many empirical estimates of the ETI have been produced for a large range of countries. The values vary considerably, depending on the method of estimation used, the particular reform examined, and the country. After mentioning that a number of authors suggest a `consensus value of about 0.4', Giertz (2004, pp. 14, 37) warns that this `masks considerable variation in the estimates'. A value of 0.4 means 2

that if the relevant tax rate rises by 10% (e.g. from 30% to 33%) the decline in taxable income for the taxpayer group examined is 4%. With personal income taxes, where effective average tax rates tend to rise with income levels, the decline in revenues would be expected to exceed 4%. Another feature of many estimates is that they have wide confidence intervals. After reviewing elasticities, Meghir and Phillips (2007, p. 19) comment that `the estimates of the effect of taxes on taxable income, whose purpose is to identify the impact of taxation on other dimensions of effort, should be regarded with caution'. Furthermore, Saez et al. (2009, p. 59) suggest that, `there are no convincing estimates of the long run elasticity'. Some `short run' elasticity estimates obtained from tax reforms may perhaps capture changes in the timing of declarations. Faced with the difficulty of obtaining data in New Zealand, it is perhaps not surprising that there is only one study containing estimates of the elasticity of taxable income for New Zealand. Using a variety of methods, covering a number of tax structure changes, Thomas (2007, p. 22) obtained estimates which `ranged from 0.35 to 1.10, with a preferred estimate of 0.52'; see also Thomas (2007, p. 18). Further work (by Treasury and Inland Revenue) to improve estimates of the ETI response to the 2000 top tax rate increase is currently underway, but will not be available until 2010 or 2011. Deadweight Costs Saez et al. (2009) propose method of calculating the deadweight costs of income tax changes, using the ETI estimates described above. They show that the marginal welfare cost (MWC) arising from an increase in the top income tax rate ca n be measured as: MWC α. ETI. tax rate 1 tax rate α. ETI. tax rate where ETI is the elasticity of taxable income and α is the ratio of the average income above the tax threshold to the threshold income level. For example if average income for those with incomes above $70,000 is $120,00 then α = 120/70 = 1.71. The above expression is relevant only when the marginal tax rate is below the revenue maximising rate. If it is, then given an estimated value of the ETI, it is a straightforward matter to obtain these MWC measures. Note that the MWC captures the costs of setting the tax rate in question different from zero; so that this effectively measures the deadweight cost of levying tax compared to no tax. 2 If it is thought that income which escapes the relevant income tax rate would be taxed at some different rate (say, the corporate or trust tax rates) then the formula above can be adapted to accommodate this. Suppose we are interested in the marginal welfare costs of changes in the top tax rate, and that the value of α is equal to 1.6, which is approximately the case for the top rate in New Zealand. If the top tax rate is 0.4 and the ETI = 0.4 (a value that is suggested from studies of other countries, bearing in mind the caveat mentioned above), the formula above gives a marginal welfare cost of 74 cents. This represents substantial inefficiency in raising tax revenue: for an extra dollar of tax revenue, obtained by raising the top tax rate, there would be an efficiency loss of 74 cents (representing the welfare loss over and above the extra revenue). 2 These measures are often best thought of as capturing the impact of introducing a small change in tax rates, so that they may not be accurate when comparing the deadweight cost of a top marginal tax rate versus a zero rate. 3

It is important to recognise that the results of using the expression above are highly sensitive to the terms involved. For example, if the elasticity of taxable income were 0.6 instead of 0.4, the MWC would increase to $1.78. But for ETI = 0.2, the MWC falls to 27 cents. If the top marginal tax rate is 0.5, the marginal welfare costs for elasticities of 0.2, 0.4 and 0.6 respectively are found to be 47 cents, $1.78 and $24.00. Given this kind of sensitivity, much care needs to be used in applying empirical estimates of the elasticity which are, in the best of circumstances, subject to some uncertainty. Table 1 provides some estimates using current tax rate values in New Zealand, and allowing for the possibility that income which escapes being taxed at this rate is instead taxed at 0% (completely escapes tax), 30% (e.g. taxed as corporate income), or 33% (taxed as trustee income). For each case, three values of the ETI of 0.2, 0.4, and 0.6 are again used. Table 1 Estimating Marginal Welfare Costs (per $ of additional tax revenue) for New Zealand Case tax rate For 1st $ taxed Elasticity of = 38% at 38% (α = 1.0) α = 1.6 α = 1.8 Comment taxable Alternative MWC MWC MWC MWC MWC income Shift to: tax rate (per $ of rev.) (1/3 each) (1/3 each) 1 0% 14.0c 24c 28c zero rate 2 0.2 30% 2.6c 4c 10c 5c 12c corporate 3 33% 1.6c 3c 3c trust 4 0% 32.0c 65c 79c zero rate 5 0.4 30% 5.4c 9c 26c 10c 31c corporate 6 33% 3.3c 5c 6c trust 7 0% 58.2c $1.43 $1.96 zero rate 8 0.6 30% 8.4c 14c 55c 16c 73c corporate 9 33% 5.1c 8c 10c trust Note: α = the ratio of average income above the 38% threshold income ($70,000) to threshold income; e.g. $112k/$70k = 1.6. Column 4 shows the distortionary impact of the first few dollars taxed at 38% that is, the first dollar of tax revenue raised on income above $70,000 (where α 1.0). With an ETI = 0.4 (Cases 4, 5 & 6), if the taxpayer s response to this higher tax rate were to seek to avoid tax completely on the additional income, the marginal welfare cost of the additional $1 of tax revenue would be 32 cents. But if this income were diverted into corporate or trust income the MWC is much lower at around 5c or 3c respectively. These small values are not surprising since in this example very little income is being diverted from the top rate. The columns further to the right show possible MWC values for different values of α = 1.6 and 1.8, (for New Zealand, 2007 aggregate taxpayer data suggest a value of α close to 1.6). 3 For illustration, MWC averages are also shown on the assumption that the reduction in taxable income (that would otherwise have been taxed at 38%) is instead taxed at 0%, 30% and 33%, split 1/3 rd at each rate. It can be seen that the MWC values are sensitive to the values of the ETI and α chosen, and range from $0.10 to $0.73, but can be as high as nearly $2 if the additional income is diverted to avoid tax completely and α is larger. As well as estimating elasticities of taxable income for New Zealand, Thomas s (2007) study calculated deadweight costs and found that the tax rate reductions in the mid 1980s produced 3 Note that the value of α should really be measured in the absence of taxation, since the existence of the top rate is likely to reduce the value of average income at which this top rate is applicable. Hence the relevant value of α is likely to exceed the value of 1.6 observed in the data. 4

substantial reductions in the excess burden from income taxation. He then examined the impact of the increase in the top tax rate from 33% to 39% in 2000, though he acknowledged that his results are subject to several caveats, mainly due to limited data availability. Thomas estimated that the 39% tax rate again raised excess burdens, though to levels below those of the 1980s. However, he found marginal welfare costs as high as $8 per extra dollar of revenue raised (i.e. 800%!). A similar exercise to that shown in Table 1 can be carried out for the lower rates of income tax using a formula for the MWC that differs slightly from that used in Table 1 see Creedy (2009d). This is relevant, for example, where fiscal drag causes taxpayers to move into higher tax brackets. It also provides a measure of the deadweight costs associated with levying the 12.5%, 21% and 33% tax rates on lower income taxpayers. Using the same methods as described above, Table 2 shows estimates of the MWC for these lower income tax rates (for an ETI = 0.4). Table 2 MWC of Lower Tax Rates (a) (b) Case ETI α k (a) Tax rate MWC Comment 1 0.4 1.25 33% 8.2c Shift from 33% to zero rate 2 0.4 1.25 33% 0.7c Shift from 33% to corporate rate 3 0.4 1.71 21% 5.9c Shift from 21% to zero rate 4 0.4 7.71 (b) 12.5% 15.6c Shift from 12.5% to zero rate The value of α k in this case uses the average income of taxpayers in the k th tax bracket and the value of the (lower) threshold for that bracket. The MWC calculation differs slightly from that used in Table 1 because higher income taxpayers (above the relevant tax bracket) also experience an income change; see Creedy (2009d). This value is obtained by assuming a lower threshold of $1000 of income; i.e. the 12.5% rate applies from the first thousand dollars of taxable income. The marginal welfare costs can be seen to be much lower in Table 2 than those in Table 1 (even though shifts to no tax are shown). This serves to highlight the point made earlier that the distortionary costs of raising tax rates are disproportionately greater if the tax rates in question are already high. Conversely reducing these high tax rates has a disproportionately large beneficial effect on tax induced distortions. Conclusions Until more reliable estimates of the elasticity of taxable income (ETI) are available for New Zealand, the estimates presented above are speculative. As argued earlier, the ETI of a tax of tax system is likely to be specific to the country and time period being considered. Most of the estimates that have been obtained around ETI = 0.4 are for the US and for the top 10%, or even top 1%, of taxpayers. In New Zealand the top tax rate is relatively modest by OECD standards but it applies from relatively low incomes. In addition the ability to switch between different forms of income for tax purposes, including the minimal taxation of capital gains, in New Zealand probably tends towards a higher ETI here. On the other hand, the limited number of tax rates and qualifying deductions in the New Zealand income tax system may contribute towards lower distortionary costs. Nevertheless, the distortionary cost estimates in Table 1 suggest that the marginal welfare costs of the 38% (formerly39%) top tax rate may be quite high such that lowering this rate, and/or raising the applicable threshold, and/or legislating to minimise the ability to re characterise income could reduce these significantly. 5

References Creedy, J. (2009a) The distortionary costs of taxation. Paper prepared for the New Zealand Treasury (October). Creedy, J. (2009b) The elasticity of taxable income: a non technical summary. Paper prepared for the New Zealand Treasury (October). Creedy, J. (2009c) Taxes, behavioural responses and excess burdens. Paper prepared for the New Zealand Treasury (October). Creedy, J. (2009d) The elasticity of taxable income: an introduction. Paper prepared for the New Zealand Treasury (October). Giertz, S.H. (2004) Recent literature on taxable income elasticities. Tax Analysis Division Congressional Budget Office, Washington D.C., paper 2004 16. Meghir, C. and Phillips, D. (2007) Labour supply and taxes. Institute for Fiscal Studies. Saez, E., Slemrod, J.B. and Giertz, S.H. (2009) The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: a critical review. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 15012. Thomas, A. (2007) Taxable income elasticities and the deadweight cost of taxation in New Zealand. Unpublished paper, Inland Revenue Department, Wellington. 6