Money illusion under test

Similar documents
The Social Costs of Unemployment: Accounting for Unemployment Duration

The Relative Income Hypothesis: A comparison of methods.


Inter-ethnic Marriage and Partner Satisfaction

Nominal or Real? The Impact of Regional Price Levels on Satisfaction with Life

Explaining procyclical male female wage gaps B

Employment protection: Do firms perceptions match with legislation?

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

JALAL EL OUARDIGHI & FRANCIS MUNIER FACULTÉ DES SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES ET DE GESTION UNIVERSITÉ DE STRASBOURG

The Happiness Gains From Sorting and Matching in the Labor Market

An Empirical Examination of Traditional Equity Valuation Models: The case of the Athens Stock Exchange

Comparison Income Effect on Subjective Well-Being

The Happiness Gains from Sorting and Matching in the Labor Market

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

Inflation and inflation uncertainty in Argentina,

Explaining the Easterlin paradox

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

RE EXAMINING THE HOTELLING VALUATION PRINCIPLE: Empirical Evidence from Canadian Oil and Gas Royalty Trusts. Michael Shumlich Craig A Wilson


Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Van Praag, B. M. S. and Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A.: Happiness Quantified. A Satisfaction Calculus Approach

Happy Voters. Exploring the Intersections between Economics and Psychology. Federica Liberini 1, Eugenio Proto 2 Michela Redoano 2.

On the urbanization of poverty

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

Chinese Firms Political Connection, Ownership, and Financing Constraints

FS January, A CROSS-COUNTRY COMPARISON OF EFFICIENCY OF FIRMS IN THE FOOD INDUSTRY. Yvonne J. Acheampong Michael E.

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE

Day of the Week Effect of Stock Returns: Empirical Evidence from Bombay Stock Exchange

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE

Bank Loan Officers Expectations for Credit Standards: evidence from the European Bank Lending Survey

A note on pro-poor growth

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

THRESHOLD EFFECT OF INFLATION ON MONEY DEMAND IN MALAYSIA

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Management Science Letters

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

Unemployment and Happiness

Econometrics and Economic Data

REXAMINING THE HOTELLING VALUATION PRINCIPLE: Empirical Evidence from Canadian Oil and Gas Royalty Trusts

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data

Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Reference Income Effects in the Determination of Equivalence Scales Using Income Satisfaction Data Melanie Baroh Andreas Knabe Carina Kuhställer

Macroeconomic Preferences by Income and Education Level: Evidence from Subjective Well-Being Data

Income Convergence in the South: Myth or Reality?

Analysis of Microdata

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION

ARE EUROPEAN BANKS IN ECONOMIC HARMONY? AN HLM APPROACH. James P. Gander

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Inflation and Stock Market Returns in US: An Empirical Study

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry

The Simple Regression Model

Subjective Financial Situation and Overall Life Satisfaction: A Joint Modelling Approach

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

The Finance-Growth Nexus and Public-Private Ownership of. Banks: Evidence for Brazil since 1870

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

CHAPTER 2. A TOUR OF THE BOOK

Does Income Inequality Impact Individual Happiness? Evidence from Canada

The Stochastic Approach for Estimating Technical Efficiency: The Case of the Greek Public Power Corporation ( )

Household Finances and Well-Being: An Empirical Analysis of Comparison Effects

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Censored Quantile Instrumental Variable

HYPERTENSION AND LIFE SATISFACTION: A COMMENT AND REPLICATION OF BLANCHFLOWER AND OSWALD (2007)

Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise

THE IMPACT OF BANKING RISKS ON THE CAPITAL OF COMMERCIAL BANKS IN LIBYA

Commodity convenience yield and risk premium determination: The case of the U.S. natural gas market

Do people adapt to changes in income and other circumstances? The discussion is not finished yet.

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

Household Finances and Well-Being: An Empirical Analysis of Comparison Effects. Sarah Brown Daniel Gray ISSN

Impact of Weekdays on the Return Rate of Stock Price Index: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of Thailand

Does Trade Liberalization Increase the Labor Demand Elasticities? Evidence from Pakistan

Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

DOES RELATIVE INCOME MATTER? ARE THE CRITICS RIGHT?

Country Fixed Effects and Unit Roots: A Comment on Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

THE SOCIOECONOMIC GRADIENT IN HEALTH: THE ROLE OF INTRA-HOUSEHOLD RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND DECISION-MAKER S GENDER

Quantitative Techniques Term 2

Shirking and Employment Protection Legislation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

3rd International Conference on Science and Social Research (ICSSR 2014)

Reference Income Effects in the Determination of Equivalence Scales Using Income Satisfaction Data

Bank Switching and Interest Rates: Examining Annual Transfers Between Savings Accounts

Weighted Country Product Dummy Variable Regressions and Index Number Formulae

Transcription:

Economics Letters 94 (2007) 332 337 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Money illusion under test Stefan Boes, Markus Lipp, Rainer Winkelmann University of Zurich, Socioeconomic Institute, Zürichbergstr. 14, CH-8032 Zürich, Switzerland Received 31 October 2005; received in revised form 2 June 2006; accepted 28 June 2006 Available online 13 December 2006 Abstract We propose a test for the presence of money illusion based on subjective survey information on individual satisfaction with income. Using data from the German Socio-Economic Panel for the period 1993 2003, we cannot reject the null hypothesis of no money illusion. 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Cost of living; Subjective well-being; Fixed effects JEL classification: I31; D12 1. Introduction This paper proposes a novel test for the existence of money illusion. It is based on people's self-reported satisfaction with their income, as elicited in a large household panel survey for Germany. In the absence of money illusion, reported income satisfaction should be unchanged if commodity prices and nominal income increase or decrease by the same proportion. In other words, satisfaction then depends on real rather than on nominal income. If, on the other hand, a proportional increase in prices and nominal income increases subjective well-being, then we have evidence for money illusion. This proposition can be tested. Formally, suppose that an indirect utility function v(y, p) can be approximated as vð y; pþcb 0 þ b 1 lny þ b 2 lnp ð1þ where y is income and p is an appropriately defined price level. Then the absence of money illusion means that β 1 = β 2. In order to test this restriction, we follow the recent literature in empirical welfare Corresponding author. Tel.: +41 44 634 2292; fax: +41 44 634 4996. E-mail address: winkelmann@sts.unizh.ch (R. Winkelmann). 0165-1765/$ - see front matter 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2006.06.043

S. Boes et al. / Economics Letters 94 (2007) 332 337 333 economics (Frey and Stutzer, 2001) and take survey responses to a question such as How satisfied are you with your income at present (on a scale from 0 to 10) as proxies for v(y, p). The regression of v i on individual log income ln y i and the relevant log price level ln p i yields unbiased estimators for β 1 and β 2 only if ln y i and ln p i are uncorrelated with the approximation error. With panel data, a better estimator can be based on a two-way fixed effects model. Because the dependent variable is discrete and ordinal, we apply the Probit adjusted least squares method (POLS) suggested by van Praag and Ferrer-i- Carbonell (2004). The analysis is based on data from a large, representative household panel survey, the German Socio- Economic Panel (GSOEP), for the years 1993 to 2003, incorporating information on income, satisfaction with household income, and regional cost of living indices provided by Roos (2006). Satisfaction with household income serves as a proxy for individual utility in order to assess money illusion, which is a new approach. The results show that people's satisfaction with their financial situation indeed responds to changes in the relevant price level as postulated by standard economic theory. Moreover, the hypothesis of no money illusion cannot be rejected. 2. Background The term money illusion was coined by Keynes. Irving Fisher (1928) devoted an entire monograph to it. Money illusion provides a basis for explaining involuntary unemployment and cyclical developments in the economy, but direct empirical evidence is rare. In the 1970s, it became unfashionable to build models around money illusion, because it was not in line with the prevailing theory of the utilitymaximizing decision making that should be based on real rather than nominal quantities. 1 In the wake of the emergence of behavioral economics the topic has attracted renewed attention lately. Money illusion counts among one of the many potential anomalies in human decision making. Whether it exists or not is an empirical matter, and Shafir, Diamond and Tversky (1997) and Fehr and Tyran (2001) are among the recent contributions. Fehr and Tyran (2001) conclude, from experimental evidence, that there is only a small amount of money illusion at the individual level, as expected, but beyond that there is no individual irrationality (p. 1251). In contrast, Shafir et al. (1997) find ample evidence for money illusion from surveys where participants had to evaluate different (hypothetical) income and price scenarios. In addition, they found that framing matters: [ ] when the emphasis is not purely economic, however, the attribution of well-being is driven primarily by a nominal rather than a real evaluation. (p. 352). The question whether and to what extent money illusion at the individual level is empirically relevant is not yet settled, and therefore warrants further investigation. We approach the issue with a methodology that is completely different from and in some respects superior to that of the previous studies. We use evidence from a large, representative household survey rather than an experimental student population. We avoid hypothetical questions and framing effects. The information we use refers to the real current situation of the respondent, and it has been collected from the respondent's point of view in a context unrelated to the issue of nominal versus real assessment. 1 James Tobin (1972, p. 3) characterized the situation in the following way: an economic theorist can, of course commit no greater crime than to assume money illusion.

334 S. Boes et al. / Economics Letters 94 (2007) 332 337 3. Data and methods Our primary data source is the GSOEP, a large representative longitudinal study of private households in Germany. The GSOEP surveys the same households annually since 1984. In 1990, it was expanded to include households from the former German Democratic Republic. As the GSOEP does not contain information about prices, another source is consulted. Roos (2006) calculates a cross-sectional cost of living index for the federal states of Germany in 1993 and extrapolates it over time using information on regional inflation rates. Since the available cost of living series only starts in 1993, we use the period 1993 to 2003 as our observation span. The regression equation can be written as v ijt ¼ hðb 0 þ b 1 lny ijt þ b 2 lnp jt þ b 3 lnn ijt þ d t þ h j þ a i þ e ijt Þ ð2þ where j=1,, 12 is the index for the federal state and t=93,, 03 is the index for the survey year. v ijt is the response to the financial satisfaction question, measured on an eleven point response scale. The model postulates that individual satisfaction with income is a function of nominal income, price level, household size, all in logs, as well as time (δ t ), regional (θ j ) and individual (α i ) fixed effects. The control for regional fixed effects is particularly important, as regions with attractive local amenities will also tend to have high cost of living. In Eq. (2), h( ) denotes a step-function that provides a mapping from the set of real numbers to the discrete responses {0, 10}. It is common to base this step function on an ordered probit (or ordered logit) formulation, and estimate the model parameters by maximum likelihood. Recently, van Praag and Ferreri-Carbonell (2004) have proposed a considerable simplification, the Probit adjusted ordinary least squares (POLS), whereby a linear model is estimated for a transformed regressand, namely the expectation of a double truncated standard normal variate, where the truncation points are derived from the marginal distribution of v ijt (see van Praag and Ferreri-i-Carbonell, 2004, for further details). This estimator has the virtue of being easily extendable to panel data modelling, an important advantage in our application. Ideally we would like to measure prices at the individual level, i.e., for a basket of goods that is typically consumed by that household. However, such a price index is not available, and the next best alternative is to use regional cost of living indices p jt. Such indices are available for 13 out of the 16 states (Roos, 2006). 2 Moreover, there is no separate coding in the GSOEP for the federal states Rhineland- Palatinate and Saarland, so that the cost of living index for these two states had to be combined, leaving us with 132 distinct price observations (12 regional indices over 11 years). There is substantial variation in regional prices. The difference in the 1993 cost of living index between the most expensive (Hessen) and the least expensive (Sachsen-Anhalt) state amounts to 23.4%. The average annual growth rates range from a low of 1.1% in Berlin to a high of 1.9% in Sachsen-Anhalt. Income is measured as current monthly household net income. 3 Rather than using a pre-defined equivalence scale, we include the log of the household size n ijt as an additional regressor. Economies of scale exist as long as β 3 bβ 1. The data form an unbalanced panel. After restricting the sample to those aged 25 to 64, there is a total of 116,169 observations on 23,073 distinct persons. In principle, the panel dimension can be incorporated 2 Bremen, Hamburg and Schleswig-Holstein do not report inflation rates. 3 This is the total monthly income of all household members, after the deduction of tax and social security contributions, and including regular transfer payments such as rent subsidy, child benefit, government grants and subsistence allowances.

S. Boes et al. / Economics Letters 94 (2007) 332 337 335 Table 1 Regression results for satisfaction with income (N = 116,169) (1) (2) (3) Log income 0.922 (0.010) 0.658 (0.009) 0.611 (0.008) Log price 0.707 (0.051) 0.809 (0.0486) 0.871 (0.477) Log household size 0.338 (0.011) 0.230 (0.011) 0.206 (0.011) Age 0.016 (0.014) Age squared/100 0.003 (0.004) Good health 0.257 (0.005) Unemployed 0.311 (0.009) Fixed effects a No Yes Yes p-value (β 1 = β 2 ) 0.757 0.585 Source: German Socio-Economic Panel 1993 2003. a Time, region and individual effects. in the estimation procedure in a number of ways. At a minimum, the standard errors should be corrected to account for clustering at the individual level. Alternatively, the model can be estimated conditional on the fixed effects (using the within estimator) or by GLS, treating the individual specific error component as random. 4. Results Table 1 presents three sets of regression results. The simple POLS estimates of model (2), without fixed time, region and individual effects, is shown in the first column. The second column shows the results for the model with fixed effects. In the third column, the fixed effects model is extended by including additional regressors. Random effects versions of models (2) and (3) were estimated as well. They are not displayed, however, since Hausman tests rejected the exogeneity hypothesis. The number of observations is 116,169 in each case. The estimated income and size effects are similar to those found in the previous literature (e.g., van Praag and Ferrer-i-Carbonell, 2004, Table 2.8). For example, a 10% increase in income is predicted to lead to a movement up by 0.09 points on the transformed response scale. Keeping income constant, satisfaction with income is a decreasing function of household size. What is puzzling, though, is a positive price level effect. This spurious effect arises since the model ignores an important determinant of satisfaction. It is well-documented that East Germans report substantially lower satisfaction levels than West Germans in all satisfaction domains, including income satisfaction. At the same time, the cost of living is much lower in the East than in the West. To account for this effect, we include in the second column a set of regional dummy variables, in addition to fixed time and individual specific effects. 4 The price effect now turns negative, i.e., a higher price level is associated with a lower income satisfaction. The effect is statistically significant at the 10% level. The point estimate ( 0.809) is even larger in absolute value than the income effect (+0.658). Such a result would be consistent with other evidence that people in Germany actually overestimate the inflation during and following the introduction of the Euro in January 2002 (Brachinger, 2005). Another 4 Regional effects can be identified separately from individual fixed effects since people move between regions.

336 S. Boes et al. / Economics Letters 94 (2007) 332 337 explanation might be that people dislike inflation per-se, in accordance with the results by Di Tella, MacCuloch and Oswald (2001). However, a formal test of the hypothesis that β 1 = β 2 cannot be rejected (p-value = 0.757). The absolute values of the two coefficients are not statistically significantly different from each other, and therefore, we do not find evidence for money illusion. This conclusion is confirmed in an extended specification, where we include in addition a second order polynomial in age and two indicator variables for self-reported good health and unemployment. These are important variables in life satisfaction models (Frey and Stutzer, 2001). Their inclusion in a model for income satisfaction may be less obvious. In fact, health (positive) and unemployment (negative) are found to be important explanatory factors of financial satisfaction. Either the answers in the various satisfaction domains are interdependent, or health and unemployment have indeed direct effects on financial satisfaction. For example, the expenditures associated with bad health may reduce income satisfaction for a given income. Similarly, a given income may lead to lower satisfaction when it comes from government transfers in the case of unemployment rather than own earnings. Whatever the explanation, the effect of this alternative specification on the estimated income and price coefficients is minimal, and we find again, that the hypothesis of no money illusion cannot be rejected. 5. Conclusions The primary objective of this paper was to investigate the phenomenon of money illusion at the individual level, using GSOEP data drawn from the survey years 1993 to 2003. Satisfaction with household income serves as a proxy for individual utility in order to test for money illusion. The results do not support the presence of money illusion. In two models with fixed effects, the null hypothesis that the sum of the coefficient of logarithmic nominal income and the coefficient of the logarithmic price index is 0 cannot be rejected at any conventional significance levels. We are aware that not rejecting a null-hypothesis is not the same as proving it. But the evidence is at least compatible with the notion that a proportional increase of nominal income and of prices leaves the income satisfaction of people unaffected. Acknowledgements Our special thanks go to the German Socio-Economic Panel Study (GSOEP) at the German Institute for Economic Research (DIW), Berlin, and to Michael Roos, University of Dortmund, for providing us with the data required for the analysis. An anonymous referee provided valuable suggestions for improvement. References Brachinger, H.W., 2005. Theory and Index of Perceived Inflation, Working Paper, Seminar for Statistics, University of Fribourg. Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R., Oswald, A., 2001. Preferences over inflation and unemployment: evidence from surveys of happiness. American Economic Review 91, 335 341. Fehr, E., Tyran, J.R., 2001. Does money illusion matter? American Economic Review 91, 1239 1262. Fisher, I., 1928. Money Illusion. Adelphi Company, New York. Frey, B.S., Stutzer, A., 2001. Happiness and Economics. Princeton University Press.

S. Boes et al. / Economics Letters 94 (2007) 332 337 337 Roos, M.W.M., 2006. Regional price levels in Germany. Applied Economics 38, 1553 1566. Shafir, E., Diamond, P., Tversky, A., 1997. Money illusion. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (2), 341 374. Tobin, J., 1972. Inflation and unemployment. American Economic Review 62 (1), 1 18. van Praag, B., Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A., 2004. Happiness Quantified A Satisfaction Calculus Approach. Oxford University Press.