Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017

Similar documents
Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

The Dornbusch overshooting model. The short run and long run together

Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto SB Spring 2017

1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach Assume uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), which is implied by perfect capital substitutability 1.

Lecture 5: Flexible prices - the monetary model of the exchange rate. Lecture 6: Fixed-prices - the Mundell- Fleming model

14.02 Quiz 3. Time Allowed: 90 minutes. Fall 2012

Notes on the Monetary Model of Exchange Rates

Intermediate Macroeconomics-ECO 3203

1) Real and Nominal exchange rates are highly positively correlated. 2) Real and nominal exchange rates are well approximated by a random walk.

3. OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS

Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto Universtiy SB, Spring 2016, Solution to Problem Set 4

7.1 Assumptions: prices sticky in SR, but flex in MR, endogenous expectations

6. The Aggregate Demand and Supply Model

EC202 Macroeconomics

University of Toronto July 21, 2010 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Winter 2009 Solutions to Problem Set 2.

Lecture 9: Exchange rates

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Faculty of Arts and Science. April Examination 2016 ECO 209Y. Duration: 2 hours

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

1 Figure 1 (A) shows what the IS LM model looks like for the case in which the Fed holds the

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Problem Set 5

Kevin Clinton October 2005 Open-economy monetary and fiscal policy

University of Toronto December 3, 2010 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2 L0101 L0301 L0401 M 2-4 W 2-4 R 2-4

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Topic 7: The Mundell-Fleming Model

Chapter 22 THE MUNDELL-FLEMING MODEL WITH PARTIAL INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY

Chapter 9 Chapter 10

University of Toronto July 27, 2006 ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2 DO NOT WRITE IN THIS SPACE. Part I /30.

Y t )+υ t. +φ ( Y t. Y t ) Y t. α ( r t. + ρ +θ π ( π t. + ρ

Economics 302 Intermediate Macroeconomic

Part B (Long Questions)

EC 205 Lecture 20 04/05/15

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

6 The Open Economy. This chapter:

Outline The basic set-up Fixed exchange rates Flexible exchange rates Transitional dynamics and overshooting in a sticky price model

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 222 A&B Macroeconomic Theory I. Final Examination 20 April 2009

Lectures 24 & 25: Determination of exchange rates

Overshooting of Exchange Rate and New Open Economy Macroeconomics : Some Implications for Japanese Yen and Korean Won

Foreign Trade and the Exchange Rate

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

Exchange rateovershooting-the Dornbuschmodel

Economics Final Examination December, Part A: Multiple Choice. Choose the best alternative that answer or completes the sentence.

ECM134 International Money and Finance 2012/13 Exam Paper Model Answers

Chapter 18 Exchange Rate Theories (modified version)

Textbook Media Press. CH 27 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

1 No capital mobility

The Mundell-Fleming Dornbush Model

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

University of Toronto July 27, 2012 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #3

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Dynamics of the Swiss Franc Appreciation Explained by the Dornbusch Model an Approach

Portfolio Balance Models of Exchange

International Finance

PART ONE INTRODUCTION

= C + I + G + NX = Y 80r

Lecture 22. Aggregate demand and aggregate supply

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Fall 2006 Solutions to Problem Set 4 (35 points)

Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy

The Open Economy. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

ANSWER: We can find consumption and saving by solving:

TEACHING OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS WITH IMPLICIT AGGREGATE SUPPLY ON A SINGLE DIAGRAM *

EC202 Macroeconomics

University of Toronto July 15, 2016 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Macroeconomics. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Zoltán Bartha, PhD Associate Professor. Andrea S. Gubik, PhD Associate Professor

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Spring 2016

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

The Mundell-Fleming-Tobin Model

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Answers to Questions: Chapter 7

4 MONEY MARKET EQUILIBRIUM: DERIVING THE LM CURVE

Chapter 19 Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Chapter 7 Fixed Exchange Rate Regimes and Short Run Macroeconomic Policy

Business Fluctuations. Notes 05. Preface. IS Relation. LM Relation. The IS and the LM Together. Does the IS-LM Model Fit the Facts?

International Economics Fall 2011 Exchange Rate and Macro Policies. Paul Deng Oct. 4, 2011

2/10/2011 PREDICTING EXCHANGE RATES: THE LONG-RUN MONETARY APPROACH and the The SHORT-RUN ASSET APPROACH

Macroeconomic Analysis Econ 6022

Key Idea: We consider labor market, goods market and money market simultaneously.

FETP/MPP8/Macroeconomics/Riedel. Money, Interest Rates and the Exchange Rate

Print last name: Solution Given name: Student number: Section number

Macroeconomics II The Small Open Economy IS-LM - Mundell-Fleming Model

14.02 PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS QUIZ 3 05/10/2012

Review: Markets of Goods and Money

Chapter 4 Theories of Business Cycle

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 5, Questions

A Small Open Economy under Fixed

EC3115 Monetary Economics

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY

Learning objectives. Macroeconomics I International Group Course Topic 8: AGGREGATE DEMAND IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2018

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

macro macroeconomics Aggregate Demand in the Open Economy N. Gregory Mankiw CHAPTER TWELVE PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich fifth edition

Chapter 13. Introduction. Goods Market Equilibrium. Modeling Strategy. Nominal Exchange Rate: A Convention. The Nominal Exchange Rate

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework

Transcription:

Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 Sticky Prices: The Dornbusch Model Jouko Vilmunen 08.03.2017 Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 1 / 27

The failure of the monetary model The simple monetary model is incapable of explaining basic facts on international prices PPP is the critical assumption Observed exchange rate volatility far greater than the simple model implies The Mundell-Fleming model, by assuming fixed or sticky prices, is relevant for the very shortest horizons Dornbusch s model, introduced in 1976, is a hybrid short-run price stickiness Keynesian features long-run characteristics like in the monetary model Key idea: differential adjustment speed in goods and financial markets goods markets: slow financial markets: fast Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 2 / 27

The overshooting model Implication: the burden of short-run adjustment falls on financial markets which overreact to different shocks, monetary shocks in particular financial markets overshoot relative to long-run equilibrium Why? Price level initially fixed, a change in the nominal money stock is a change in the real money stock an instantaneous change in the money demand has to result only possible, if the interest rate changes appropriately, if, in particular, output is assumed fixed In the short-run, monetary policy changes have what is nowadays known as the liquidity effect Change in interest rates only temporary and the price level will start its delayed response real money stock will starts to revert itself back to the original level driving interest rates, aggregate demand and the real exchange rate back to their original level Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 3 / 27

The overshooting model Hence, over the long-run all real variables have reverted back to their original values a flavour from the monetary model! Change in the nominal exchange rate in the long-run equilibrium reflects the proportionate change in the nominal money supply We will next outline the overshooting model, with two conventions focus on a small open economy takes intl prices and quantities as given, ie. does not affect them comparative statics: we will start from an initial equilibrium position and consider what happens to the level of the exchange rate once we change the level of the money supply Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 4 / 27

The overshooting model: assumptions We need the following assumptions 1 Aggregate demand is determined by the standard IS-LM mechanism/model 2 Financial markets adjust instantaneously. In particular, investors are risk neutral, so that UIRP holds at all times Hence, perfect capital mobility ensures that expected depreciation/appreciation is just enough to offset any interest rate differential between the domestic and foreign economy r r f = s e But: how are expectations actually determined? suppose there is a long-run equilibrium real exchange rate Q (and nominal exchange rate S), which determined by the domestic money stock, national income and interest rates relative to those of the rest of the world (ROW), ie. by the monetary model Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 5 / 27

The overshooting model: assumptions Dornbusch model: Q in equilibrium only in the long-run, deviations in the short-run Dornbusch assumes that the expected rate of depreciation of the domestic currency S e S S is proportional to the percentage deviation of the actual exchange rate from its long-run equilibrium value S, S S S We can formalize this idea by saying that there is a positive parameter Θ such that S e ( ) S S S = Θ S S Since X Y Y ln(1 + X Y Y ) = ln(x ) ln(y ) = x y, we can rewrite the above as s e = Θ (s s) We can represent this relationship graphically in the next figure (slope Θ) Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 6 / 27

The force of the UIP Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 7 / 27

Overshooting: adjustment Initially the economy is in point A with an exchange rate of s0 and nominal interest rate at rf If the domestic interest rate falls to r2, continuous validity of the UIRP implies that the domestic currency is expected to appreciate Given Dornbusch s model for exchange rate expectations, this means that the value of the domestic currency (euro) is currently below its equilibrium value, ie. S > S, so as to generate the expectation of a future euro appreciation Euro will appreciate towards its long run value as long as it is currently below the equilibrium value The arrows in the figure indicate the direction of adjustment that the exchange rate takes once off its long-run equilibrium The same analysis holds for any long-run equilibrium value of the domestic currency, eg. point B Note that the UIRP holds at any point along the RP line in the figure! Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 8 / 27

Goods market Deviations from the equilibrium exchange rate result from the following assumption 3. The price level is sticky. That is aggregate supply curve is flat in the immediate impact phase, increasingly steep in the adjustment phase and, ultimately, vertical in the long-run equilibrium In the long-run the exchange rate is at its equilibrium level, ie. the market clearing real value, given the domestic and foreign price levels In the short-run, the price level is fixed, so shocks move the nominal exchange rate and, hence, the real exchange rate current account surpluses and deficits will follow With the passage of time and without any further shocks, the economy moves back to its long-run real exchange rate as a result of movements in both the nominal exchange rate and the price level Let us look at the next figure to see what the Dornbusch model implies Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 201708.03.2017 9 / 27

Overshooting in graphics Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 10 / 27

Long-run equilibrium In the figure: top rhs figure is the IS-LM diagram, showing the determination of aggregate demand top lhs figure is the RP diagram (initial S at s0, the corresponding UIRP line not drawn) bottom rhs figure AD-AS curves, AS for both long-run and short-run (AS(SR)) bottom lhs figure shows the PPP line and deviations from the PPP level Long-run equilibrium: aggregate demand is equal to aggregate supply: no upward or downward pressure on the price level domestic and foreign interest rates are equal: static exchange rate, no expected change the real exchange rate is at its long-run level: no imbalances in the current account satisfied at points A, C, F, H in the figure Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 11 / 27

Monetary expansion Suppose ECB decides to increase the domestic money supply from M0 to M1 Long-run effects as in the monetary model: vertical long-run AS curve means that the price level has to increase as much as the money supply leaving the real money stock unchanged for fixed government expenditure, the IS-curve will not shift if the real exchange rate returns back to its original level Short-run effects: LM curves shifts down and to the right giving rise, at fixed real income, to an excess supply of domestic money domestic interest would have to fall (to r1) to bring about the absorption of the temporarily higher real money stock (liquidity effect) lower domestic interest rate, ie. negative interest rate differential induce expectations of a stronger domestic currency domestic currecy depreciates immediately to generate these expectations S immediately jumps to s2 Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 12 / 27

Monetary expansion domestic and foreign price level fixed in the short-run, hence the real exchange rate weakens to Q1, boosting net exports and domestic demand IS curve shifts up and to the right (point b) this increase in demand represents, given the flat short-run AS curve, also an increase in output produced with a given interest rate at r1 the temporary equilibrium is at point k in the top lhs figure subsequent adjustment takes place along the RP curve But note that the short-run exchange rate S at s2 is above the long-run equilibrium level of s1 this is the essence of the Dornbusch model: after the monetary expansion, the domestic currency weakens more than its new long-run equilibrium value, ie. it overshoots its long-run equilibrium level Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 13 / 27

What is important? The extent of the overshoot depends on two factors: interest rate elasticity of money demand; our formalism is M P dr dy = ky lr = k l so that a fall in the interest elasticity of money demand, l, will make the LM curve steeper and the greater will the fall in the interest rate have to be from any given increase in the real money stock the slope of the RP curve; the flatter it is the more the exchange rate must overshoot its long-run equilibrium, for any given change in the interes rate the slope of the RP line is determined by the expectations parameter Θ r r f = Θ (s s) r s = Θ so lower Θ implies larger overshooting Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 14 / 27

What is important? The intuition for the last result is that when Θ is small, a larger gap between the current exchange rate and the corresponding long-run level is required to generate any given interest rate differential If Θ falls to zero no interest rate differential would be possible, because no matter how large the gap between current and long-run equilibrium exchange rate, no expected currency appreciation would be generated by the gap Note that along the adjustment path to the long-run equilibrium in the Dornbusch model, rising interest rates coincides with an appreciating domestic currency, an implication often observed in actual data However, it should be noted that it is wrong to conclude from this that the rising domestic interest rate causes the domestic exchange rate to appreciate; rather, both phenomena result from the same cause, namely expansionary domestic monetary policy and the concomitant, albeit temporary, undervaluation of the domestic currency Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 15 / 27

Formal model Dornbusch s overshooting model can be represented formally as follows r r f = s e (UIRP) s e = Θ (s s) (S expectations) m p = ky lr (MM equilibrium) y d = h(s p) = h(q), q = s p (AD) ( ) p = π y d y (Inflation adjustment) Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 16 / 27

Formal model where y is constant and p = d ln p (inflation rate) dt Note that we have set the foreign price level to unity, P f = 1, so that the log of it ln P f = ln 1 = 0 Note also that inflation responds to excess demand y d y: inflation rate will increase if aggregate demand exceed aggregate long-run output This system can be reduced to two equations: p = m ky + lr f + lθ (s s) }{{} L = L lθ (s s) p = π [h(s p) y] that is one equation for the price level and another for the rate of inflation Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 17 / 27

Formal model: long-run equilibrium Long-run equilibrium: y d y = 0, so the price level is stable, ie. rate of inflation is zero p = 0 Hence, from the inflation adjustment equation we have h(s p) y = 0 s p = q = y h There is strong implication here, reflecting the classical monetary aspects of the Dornbusch model: in the long-run, only the (growth of the) capacity output will affect the real exchange rate; any change in the nominal exchange rate S is matched by a change in the price level The expected rate of depreciation s e is in the long-run zero, since S is in equilibrium; hence p = L = m ky + lr f hence in the long-run equilibrium the price level is equal to the ratio of the money stock to the level of demand when it is at its long-run level or when the domestic and foreign interest rates are equal Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 18 / 27

Formal model: long-run equilibrium Finally, the long-run equilbrium for the nominal exchange rate can be obtained by combining the two last equations s = ( h 1 k ) y + m + lr f Now, all of our previous analysis is vindicated by the last two equations: an increase in the domestic money stock pushes up the long-run values of the domestic price level and exchange rate in the same proportion and hence leaves the real exchange rate and, by implication, aggregate output untouched Short-run dynamics (disequilibrium): inflation adjustment can now, given the long-run solution, written conveniently as p = πh(q q) so that the larger deviations of the real exchange rate from its long-run equilibrium level will generate higher rates of inflation Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 19 / 27

Formal model: short-run dynamics (disequilibrium) Money market equilibrium implies, on the other hand, that deviations of the price level from its long-run level are given by p p = lθ (s s) (SRMM) (Note! In Copelands book, ch 7 p. 207 the sign is not correct) This is a necessary condition for the short-run equilibrium in the money market Hence, the system adjust so as to preserve this relationship at all times, which means that the economy lies somewhere along a downward sloping line in the (p, s) -space (with slope 1 lθ ) See next figure, where we have drawn the long-run condition p = 0 together with (SRMM) Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 20 / 27

Formal model: Graphics Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 21 / 27

Formal model: Graphics Economy starts at (p0, s0), where the money supply is m0 Money supply increases to m1: MM curve shifts out and to the right (MM (m0) to MM(m1)) Price level fixed, nominal exchange rate jumps from s0 to s2 Post jump convergence along the MM(m1) curve from point C towards point B: new long-run equilibrium (p1, s1): that is the change in the price level equals the change in the nominal exchange rate dp = ds (d = ) Short-run overshooting: size s2 s1 Now, perfect foresight means expectations are fullfilled at any point in time: hence expected values equal realized values,ie s e = s = s p e = p = p Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 22 / 27

Formal model: Perfect foresight We have p = πh(q q) = πh(s p s + p) = πh(s s (p p)) = πh(1 + lθ)(s s) On the other hand, money market equilibrium implies p = L lθ (s s), ie p = lθ s = lθ 2 (s s) Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 23 / 27

Formal model: Perfect foresight So, along the perfect foresight path these two expressions for the inflation rate has to be consistent with each other: this can happen only if the the expectations parameter Θ satisfies lθ 2 = πh(1 + lθ) [ ( )] 1 Θ = πh 1 + lθ There s nothing magical about this particular parameter value or nothing particularly illuminating in computing this value: what may be interesting is to note that the model as presented includes a special case where the market s apparently rule of thumb (of forming expectations) is self-fulfilling, so that its anticipations always turn out to be correct in the short- as well as in the long-run (perfect foresight = rational expectations) How do we prove that overshooting takes place? Take the semi-reduced solution to the price level p = L lθ (s s) Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 24 / 27

Formal model: Overshooting In the long run: dm = ds and, importantly, at the time of the money supply changes, the price level is fixed, ie. dp = 0 0 = (1 + lθ)dm lθds [ ( )] 1 ds dp=0 = 1 + dm > dm lθ So that the nominal exchange rate indeed overshoots its long-run equilibrium level What about empirical testing of the overshooting hypothesis? The Dornbusch model is very diffi cult to test permanent increases in the money supply expectations formation lags in the response of the exchange rate to money supply changes etc Instead, use the approach proposed by Jeffrey Frankel: it is based on real interest rate differentials Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 25 / 27

Empirical testing: Frankel approach The starting point of the Frankel approach is a small addition to the Dornbusch expectations mechanisms: denote by a tilde above the variable x, x, the ratio of domestic x to foreign x f. so that s e = Θ (s s) + p e that is the difference between expected domestic and foreign inflation rates enters foreign exchange rate expectations Frankel extension amounts to a generalization of the Dornbusch mechanism to accommodate long-run inflation UIRP now gives r = Θ (s s) + p e or s = s + 1 Θ ( r pe ) Next, follow Dornbusch in assuming that the monetary model only determines the (long-run) equilibrium, not the actual exchange rate: s = m kỹ + l p e Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 26 / 27

Empirical testing: Frankel approach The above is a familiar formulation, apart from the last term If PPP does not hold, real exchange rates have to diverge: under UIRP real interest rates have to diverge too To get an estimable equation combine the above two equations s = m kỹ + l p e 1 Θ ( r pe ) which clearly shows the role of played by the real interest rate differential ( r p e ) If we can find a measure of inflation expectations, we can test the last equation Note that as a special case the above equation includes the basic monetary model: if Θ increases without bound (ie s = s at all times), then the coeffi cient on the real interest rate will be zero Frankel s evidence suggests that this equations works in the 1970 s (for DM/$ exchange rate) Since 1980 s in particular, the model fails on exchange rate data Jouko Vilmunen (BoF) Open Economy Macroeconomics, Aalto University SB, Spring 2017 08.03.2017 27 / 27