Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

Similar documents
Game Theory. Important Instructions

Simon Fraser University Fall Econ 302 D200 Final Exam Solution Instructor: Songzi Du Wednesday December 16, 2015, 8:30 11:30 AM

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

Spring 2017 Final Exam

Economics 502 April 3, 2008

Economics 171: Final Exam

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Answers to Problem Set 4

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

HW Consider the following game:

Game Theory: Additional Exercises

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Repeated Games. EC202 Lectures IX & X. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures IX & X Jan / 16

Eco AS , J. Sandford, spring 2019 March 9, Midterm answers

w E(Q w) w/100 E(Q w) w/

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

Today. Applications of NE and SPNE Auctions English Auction Second-Price Sealed-Bid Auction First-Price Sealed-Bid Auction

Markets with Intermediaries

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium

Markets with Intermediaries

In reality; some cases of prisoner s dilemma end in cooperation. Game Theory Dr. F. Fatemi Page 219

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Finitely repeated simultaneous move game.

Solution to Assignment 3

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

14.12 Game Theory Midterm II 11/15/ Compute all the subgame perfect equilibria in pure strategies for the following game:

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

(a) (5 points) Suppose p = 1. Calculate all the Nash Equilibria of the game. Do/es the equilibrium/a that you have found maximize social utility?

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies:

Strategy -1- Strategy

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

University at Albany, State University of New York Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Examination in Microeconomics, June 20, 2017

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Repeated Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Repeated Games 1 / 48

Not 0,4 2,1. i. Show there is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium where player A chooses to play, player A chooses L, and player B chooses L.

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22)

ECON/MGEC 333 Game Theory And Strategy Problem Set 9 Solutions. Levent Koçkesen January 6, 2011

Out of equilibrium beliefs and Refinements of PBE

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

1 Solutions to Homework 4

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Extensive-Form Games with Imperfect Information

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY. Department of Economics. January Written Portion of the Comprehensive Examination for

Insurance, Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard

Name. Answers Discussion Final Exam, Econ 171, March, 2012

CS711 Game Theory and Mechanism Design

Extensive form games - contd

Player 2 L R M H a,a 7,1 5,0 T 0,5 5,3 6,6

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Games with incomplete information about players. be symmetric or asymmetric.

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

ECO303: Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Benjamin Balak, Spring 2008

Warm Up Finitely Repeated Games Infinitely Repeated Games Bayesian Games. Repeated Games

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

University of Hong Kong ECON6036 Stephen Chiu. Extensive Games with Perfect Information II. Outline

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Chapter 8. Repeated Games. Strategies and payoffs for games played twice

Repeated Games with Perfect Monitoring

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Microeconomic Theory II Spring 2016 Final Exam Solutions

Notes for Section: Week 7

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding

We examine the impact of risk aversion on bidding behavior in first-price auctions.

Econ 414 Midterm Exam

EconS Games with Incomplete Information II and Auction Theory

Name. FINAL EXAM, Econ 171, March, 2015

Transcription:

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014 Econ 302 D200 Final Exam Solution This brief solution guide does not have the explanations necessary for full marks. NE = Nash equilibrium, SPE = subgame perfect equilibrium, PBE = perfect Bayesian equilibrium 1. (10 points) Consider the following simultaneous-move game (Table 1). W X Y Z A 1, 7 4, 3 1, 2 6, 2 B 8, 6 4, 6 2, 5 5, 5 C 4, 1 5, 2 3, 3 4, 2 D 5, 5 4, 3 2, 4 9, 3 Table 1 Part i: Find the strategies that survive iterative deletion of strictly dominated strategies (ISD). For each strategy that you delete, write down the strategy that strictly dominates it. Part ii: Find all NE (pure and mixed) in this game, and for each NE that you find, calculate the two players expected payoffs in the equilibrium. Solution: Part i, ISD: Round 1: Z is strictly dominated by 1/2X + 1/2Y. Delete Z. Round 2: both A and D are strictly dominated by 1/2B + 1/2C. Delete A and D. The strategies that survive: B, C for player 1, and W, X, Y for player 2. Part ii, NE: For NE we can look at the smaller game given by ISD. Clearly, the pure-strategy NE are (B, W ) and (C, Y ). The payoffs in these pure-strategy NE can be read off the table. If player 1 plays pb + (1 p)c, where 0 < p < 1, then W cannot be a best response of player 2, because W is weakly dominated by X among the ISD strategies; if player 1 does 1

not play W with positive probability, then the only best response of player 2 is C, which means that pb + (1 p)c is not a best response. So pb + (1 p)c, where 0 < p < 1, cannot be a part of a NE. If player 1 plays C, then the best response of player 2 is Y, so we are back to the pure-strategy NE. If player 1 plays B, then the best responses of player 2 are W and X. For mixed-strategy qw + (1 q)x, we want B to be a best response, i.e., 8q + 4(1 q) 4q + 5(1 q), i.e., q 1/5. Thus, the non-trivial mixed-strategy NE are (B, qw + (1 q)x), where 1/5 q < 1. In these mixed-strategy NE player 1 gets 8q + 4(1 q) and player 2 gets 6. 2. (10 points) There are two players each with a wealth w = $3. An object that the two players each value at v = $3 is sold at an auction. In the auction, the two players alternatively have the opportunity to bid; a bid must be a positive integer greater than the previous bid and less than or equal to w. On his turn, a player may pass rather than bid, in which case the game ends and the other player receives the object; both players pay their last bids (if any). Player 1 moves initially. If player 1 passes initially, for example, player 2 receives the object and makes no payment (net payoff v 0 = 3) while player 1 receives nothing and pays nothing (net payoff 0 0 = 0); if player 1 bids 1, player 2 bids 3, and then player 1 passes, player 2 obtains the object and pays 3 (net payoff v 3 = 0) while player 1 receives nothing and pays 1 (net payoff 0 1 = 1). Part i: draw the game tree. Part ii: find and completely describe a pure-strategy SPE. Solution: Part i: see Figure 1. Part ii: A SPE is: Player 1: Bid $3 whenever there is an opportunity (i.e., initially, and when the previous bid of bidder 2 is less than $3), and pass when the previous bid of bidder 2 is $3. Player 2: Bid $3 whenever there is an opportunity (i.e., when the previous bid of bidder 1 is less than $3), and pass when the previous bid of bidder 1 is $3. 3. (10 points) Part i: suppose that you have an utility over money u(m) = m = m 0.5 2

Figure 1 and start with $10000. Consider a risky project with probability 0.25 of gaining $1000, probability 0.25 of gaining $2000, probability 0.25 of gaining $10000, and probability 0.25 of losing $10000. Find the expected value of this project (on the total wealth). Find your expected utility if you take this project, and find your certainty equivalent and risk premium for this project. Would you take the project, and why? Part ii: repeat part i with u(m) = m 0.9. Are you more or less risk averse with u(m) = m 0.9 compared to u(m) = m, and why? In your calculations keep two decimal places. Solution: Part i: Expected wealth of taking the project: 0.25 11000+0.25 12000+0.25 20000+0.25 0 = $10750. Expected utility of taking the project: EU = 0.25 11000 + 0.25 12000 + 0.25 20000 + 0.25 0 88.96. Certainty equivalent: CE = EU, so CE $7914.18. Risk premium = 10750 7914.18 = $2835.82. You would not take this project, because the certainty equivalent $7914.18 < $10000. 3

Part ii: Expected wealth of taking the project: 0.25 11000+0.25 12000+0.25 20000+0.25 0 = $10750. Expected utility of taking the project: EU = 0.25 (11000) 0.9 +0.25 (12000) 0.9 +0.25 (20000) 0.9 + 0.25 (0) 0.9 4114.39. Certainty equivalent: (CE) 0.9 = EU, so CE $10372.77. Risk premium = 10750 10372.77 = $377.23. You would take this project, because the certainty equivalent $10372.77 > $10000. You are less risk averse with u(m) = m 0.9 compared to u(m) = m, because the certainty equivalent of u(m) = m 0.9 is larger than that of u(m) = m. 4. (10 points) Two firms (firm 1 and 2) compete in quantity of production and face a market demand function of P = 9 Q. Each firm has a marginal cost of 3 per unit of production. Part i: Find the monopolist quantity, price, and payoff when the two firms merge into one monopoly firm. Part ii: Find the NE quantity, price, and payoff when the two firms compete by simultaneously choosing quantities. Part iii: Suppose that the competition is infinitely repeated, and each firm has a discount factor of δ. So firm i s payoff is t=0 δt (P t 3)q i,t, where q i,t is firm i s production quantity in period t, and P t = 9 (q 1,t + q 2,t ) is the market price in period t. In each period, the two firms set their quantities simultaneously, and observe the quantities from the previous periods. Describe a grim trigger strategy, and find the range of δ such that both firm playing the grim-trigger strategy is a SPE of the infinitely repeated game. What is the total payoff of each firm when both firms follow the grim-trigger strategy? Solution: Part i: The monopolist solves: the first order condition is max(9 Q 3)Q, Q 6 2Q = 0, so the monopolist s quantity Q m = 3, price is 9 3 = 6, and payoff is (9 3 3) 3 = 9. 4

Part ii: Suppose that firm 2 produces q, firm 1 solves max q 1 (9 (q 1 + q ) 3)q 1, the first order condition is 6 2q 1 q = 0. In the symmetric NE, firm 1 and 2 produce the same amount, so q 1 = q. Therefore, the NE quantity of each firm is q = 2, price is 9 (2 + 2) = 5, and payoff is (9 (2 + 2) 3) 2 = 4. Part iii: The following is a grim trigger strategy: In each period, produce half of the monopolist quantity Q m /2 = 1.5 (collusion) if both firms had produced Q m /2 in all past periods; produce the stage-game NE quantity q = 2 (price war) if one of the firms had deviated from Q m /2 in any past period. Clearly, if grim quantity q is triggered, it is a subgame perfect equilibrium for both firms to produce q forever. When the other firm is producing Q m /2 = 1.5 in the current period, then the best possible deviation in the current period, q d, solves max(9 (q + 1.5) 3)q, q i.e., 4.5 2q d = 0, So q d = 2.25, which gives a profit of (9 (2.25 + 1.5) 3) 2.25 = 5.0625 in the current period. But playing q d will trigger the play of q and per-period payoff of 4 in the subsequent periods. If the firm does not deviate from grim trigger, then he gets half of the monopolist s profit 9/2 = 4.5 in every period. Therefore, for a firm to not have an incentive to deviate to q d given the grim trigger strategy, we must have: 5.0625 + 4δ + 4δ 2 + 4δ 3 + 4.5 + 4.5δ + 4.5δ 2 + 4.5δ 3 +, i.e., 5.0625 + 4 δ 1 δ 4.5 1 δ, 5

or δ 5.0625 4.5 5.0625 4 0.52. So when the above inequality on δ holds, both player playing the grim-trigger strategy is a SPE. In this SPE, each player gets 4.5/(1 δ) in total payoff. Write Question 5 7 on booklet #2 5. (10 points) There are two players. Player 1 is either strong or weak (those are his types), and chooses a meal: beer or quiche. Player 2 observes this food choice, and chooses to fight or retreat. Player 2 cannot tell if player 1 is strong or weak, and believes that player 1 is strong with probability 0.1 and weak with probability 0.9. (So Nature chooses player 1 to be strong with probability 0.1 and weak with probability 0.9.) Player 2 gets 1 if he fights the weak player, 1 if he fights the strong player, and 0 if he retreats. The strong player 1 prefers beer; the weak player 1 prefers quiche. Player 1, strong or weak, gets 2 if Player 2 doesn t fight him, 0 otherwise; player 1, strong or weak, gets an additional 1 if he eats his preferred meal. (i) Draw the game tree. (ii) Find all separating PBE (if any), and explain. (iii) Find all pooling PBE (if any), and explain. For part ii and iii, focus on pure-strategy PBE, and include conditional beliefs (such as P(strong beer) = 1 or P(strong beer) 1/2.) in your description of PBE. Solution: Part i: see Figure 2. Part ii: Player 2 s best response is to fight if his conditional probability (given either beer or quiche) on the strong type is less than 1/2, and to retreat if his conditional probability on the strong type is greater than 1/2. There is no separating PBE in pure strategies. If player 1 uses S-Beer and W-Quiche, then player 2 will use B-Retreat and Q-Fight in best response (since P(S Beer) = 1 and P(S Quiche) = 0), which means that player 1 is better off with W-Beer instead of W-Quiche. Hence S-Beer and W-Quiche cannot be a part of a PBE. If player 1 uses S-Quiche and W-Beer, then player 2 will use B-Fight and Q-Retreat in 6

Figure 2 best response (since P(S Beer) = 0 and P(S Quiche) = 1), which means that player 1 is better off with W-Quiche instead of W-Beer. Hence S-Quiche and W-Beer cannot be a part of a PBE. Part ii: There is no pooling PBE in pure strategies. If player 1 uses S-Beer and W-Beer, then player 2 will fight if he sees beer (B-Fight), because P(S Beer) = 0.1. Then whatever player 2 does after seeing quiche, player 1 is strictly better off with W-Quiche. Hence S-Beer and W-Beer cannot be a part of a PBE. If player 1 uses S-Quiche and W-Quiche, then player 2 will fight if he sees quiche (Q- Fight), because P(S Quiche) = 0.1. Then whatever player 2 does after seeing beer, player 1 is strictly better off with S-Beer. Hence S-Quiche and W-Quiche cannot be a part of a PBE. 7. (10 points) Consider a market for used cars with risk-neutral participants, like we did in Lecture 10. Suppose there are four qualities for cars: A, B, C and D. Let the sellers valuations for the four qualities be $10000 (quality A), $9000 (quality B), $5000 (quality C) and $3000 (quality D), and let the buyers valuations be $20000 (quality A), $15000 (quality B), $7000 (quality C) and $4000 (quality D). Assume that there is an equal number of cars 7

in each of the four categories. Suppose only sellers know the quality of each car. Is the sales of quality A cars feasible? If so what prices for quality A cars could you observe? What about quality B, C, and D (feasibility of sales and if so the price range)? Explain. Solution: Since a buyer does not know the quality, he is willing to pay at most (20000 + 15000 + 7000 + 4000)/4 = $11500 for a car, since there is an equal number of cars in each of the four quality categories. Since 11500 > 10000, the sales of quality A cars is feasible, and the possible prices range from $10000 to $11500. If the sales of quality A cars are feasible, so are the sales of quality B, C and D, because the buyers cannot distinguish these qualities. The prices for quality B cars range from $9000 to $11500. The prices for quality B cars range from $5000 to $11500. The prices for quality B cars range from $3000 to $11500. 8