Volume 29, Issue 4. A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level: Some Empirical Evidence

Similar documents
Volume 29, Issue 2. A note on finance, inflation, and economic growth

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Does External Debt Increase Net Private Wealth? The Relative Impact of Domestic versus External Debt on the US Demand for Money

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

NOTES and COMMENTS. Ricardian Equivalence and the Irish Consumption Function: The Evidence Re-examined I INTRODUCTION

GOVERNMENT BORROWING AND THE LONG- TERM INTEREST RATE: APPLICATION OF AN EXTENDED LOANABLE FUNDS MODEL TO THE SLOVAK REPUBLIC

Sticky Expectations and Consumption Dynamics

The Short and Long-Run Implications of Budget Deficit on Economic Growth in Nigeria ( )

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Foreign Direct Investment and Islamic Banking: A Granger Causality Test

Does Trade Liberalization Increase the Labor Demand Elasticities? Evidence from Pakistan

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Volume. 3, No. 2 July - December 2016 sijmb.iba-suk.edu.pk. Financing the Fiscal Deficit in Pakistan: Evidence on Ricardian Equivalence

Does government spending boost economic growth in Europe?

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Ricardo-Barro Equivalence Theorem and the Positive Fiscal Policy in China Xiao-huan LIU 1,a,*, Su-yu LV 2,b

The Demand for Money in China: Evidence from Half a Century

Contract Pricing and Market Efficiency: Can Peer-to-Peer Internet Credit Markets Improve Allocative Efficiency?

Government Consumption Spending Inhibits Economic Growth in the OECD Countries

How Are Interest Rates Affecting Household Consumption and Savings?

An Empirical Examination of Traditional Equity Valuation Models: The case of the Athens Stock Exchange

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Ricardian Equivalence: Further Evidence

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND PUBLIC DEBT: A SURVEY OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE

DISCUSSION OF CARDIA S PAPER. LI Xiaoxi LIU Xingyi WANG Yonglei

Commodity Price Changes and Economic Growth in Developing Countries

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Working Paper No. 2032

This article sets out to empirically determine whether the ratio

Commentary. Thomas MaCurdy. Description of the Proposed Earnings-Supplement Program

Misallocation and Trade Policy

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Taxes, Government Expenditures, and State Economic Growth: The Role of Nonlinearities

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect

The index of consumer sentiment is one of the most watched economic

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

The Effectiveness of Non-traditional Monetary Policy and the Inflation Target Policy : The Case of Japan in Comparison with the US

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Public Economics. Contact Information

Deregulation and Firm Investment

The Fiscal Impact of Population Aging in the United States by Henry J. Aaron

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Differential Impact of Uncertainty on Exporting Decision in Risk-averse and Risk-taking Firms: Evidence from Korean Firms 1

Macroeconomics and finance

The January Effect: Evidence from Four Arabic Market Indices

Lecture 12 Ricardian Equivalence Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

ESTIMATING INFLATION TAX REVENUE FOR THE DEVELOPING NATIONS: A CASE STUDY IN BANGLADESH [ FY FY ] H.

Institute of Economic Research Working Papers. No. 63/2017. Short-Run Elasticity of Substitution Error Correction Model

Uncertainty Determinants of Firm Investment

An Empirical Analysis on the Management Strategy of the Growth in Dividend Payout Signal Transmission Based on Event Study Methodology

Okun s Law: An Empirical

Does health capital have differential effects on economic growth?

MONEY, PRICES, INCOME AND CAUSALITY: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

The purpose of this paper is to examine the determinants of U.S. foreign

Nonprofit organizations are becoming a large and important

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

RE-EXAMINE THE INTER-LINKAGE BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INFLATION:EVIDENCE FROM INDIA

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Revista Economică 69:3 (2017) CAPITAL STRUCTURE ON ROMANIAN LISTED COMPANIES A POST CRISIS INSIGHT

Estimating a Fiscal Reaction Function for Greece

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Interest rate uncertainty, Investment and their relationship on different industries; Evidence from Jiangsu, China

What determines government spending multipliers?

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Using the Armey Curve to Measure the Size of Government. J. Corey Miller

UNOBSERVABLE EFFECTS AND SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO TARGET CAPITAL STRUCTURE

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Inflation and Stock Market Returns in US: An Empirical Study

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

Test of the bank lending channel: The case of Hungary

Investment in Physical Capital, Investment in Health and Economic Growth in China

Federal Tax Policy and Charitable Giving: Revisiting the 1985 Study by Charles T. Clotfelter

Transcription:

Volume 29, Issue 4 A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level: Some Empirical Evidence Tito B.S. Moreira Catholic University of Brasilia Geraldo Silva Souza University of Brasilia Abstract This paper aims to investigate the impact of the bond/money ratio on the nominal interest rate. The econometric model chosen fits a dynamic panel data for Canada, Japan and US over the period 1980-2006. We found empirical evidence that Ricardian Equivalence does not hold. The analysis indicates, for the three countries, that the bond/money ratio affects the nominal interest rate. We thank CNPq for financial support. Citation: Tito B.S. Moreira and Geraldo Silva Souza, (2009) ''A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level: Some Empirical Evidence'', Economics Bulletin, Vol. 29 no.4 pp. 3120-3125. Submitted: Jul 08 2009. Published: December 18, 2009.

1. Introduction Roughly fifty years ago, Bowen, Davis and Kopf (1960) wrote a note presenting a case for the classic view that bond financing of public expenditures unlike pay-as-you-go financing places a burden on future generations. Robert Barro (1974), dealing with an intimately related issue, cast a model in which government debt does not affect the perceived net wealth of households (Martins, 1979). David Ricardo pointed out that they might conceivably treat the future taxes servicing the government debt as exactly offsetting it. Barro (1974) has shown that maximizing households will actually do so if they accurately anticipate future taxes, if they face perfect capital markets, and if they have effectively infinite horizons. The Ricardian equivalence proposition (REP), clearly stated in Barro (1974), is said to hold if households do treat future servicing taxes as an exact offset to the government debt (Evans, 1993). Both publications stimulated much debate about the rule of government bonds in macroeconomics (Martins, 1979). The empirical evidence for REP is usually investigated following two approaches. The first seeks effects of government deficits on interest rates, while the second analyses the impact of a fiscal policy variable, e.g. public debt, on the behavior of an aggregated macroeconomic variable, which could be either consumption or savings, for example (Rodrigues, 2006). The empirical evidence presented by Hoelscher (1986) confirms the theoretical prediction that deficits cause long-term interest rates to rise. The regression results indicate that this deficit-interest rate connection is strong, robust and very significant for the postwar period and for sub periods within the larger period under analysis. The author explains that since long term rates are more closely related to many consumer and business spending decisions than are short-term rates, the crowding-out effects of deficits spending are potentially serious. Conversely, Evans (1987) contests the belief that larger budget deficits whether occurring in the past or present or expected to occur in the future means higher interest rates. His paper presents empirical evidence inconsistent with this belief. In this context, other authors such as Correia-Nunes and Stemitsiotis (1995) and Lindé (1998) confirm the theoretical prediction that larger budget deficits cause higher interest rates. Correia-Nunes and Stemitsiotis (1995) investigate a possible association between larger budget deficits and high nominal and real long term interest rates. Their regression results show that the linkage between large deficits and high interest rates is statistically strong during the 1970-93 period for ten major industrial countries and at the world level. Lindé (1998) studies the empirical relation between nominal interest rates and government budget deficits. The strategy employed is similar to that of Evans (1985, 1987a, 1987b, 1988) in the sense that he uses a conventional macro model as his point of departure for the empirical investigation. According to the empirical results, larger budget deficits spell higher interest rates, as posited by conventional macroeconomic theory. Here we investigate a possible association between public debt and nominal interest rate, although the main evidence about REP is focused on consumption models rather than on interest rate models. Martins (1980) develops a theory of nominal income and interest determination under the assumption that the only relevant distinction between money and bonds lies in their holding periods. Individuals take full account of the government budget constraint and do not concern themselves with discounting future tax liabilities associated with the issue of government bonds. According to this theory, the price of bonds is analogous to the price 1

level, and the nominal rate of interest is determined by the bond/money ratio and bears no close relationship to the rate of expansion of the price level. Based on Martins (1980) we can rewrite his fundamental equation as R t = B t /M t wherer t = (1 + i t ). The subscript t represents the time, i represents the nominal interest rate, B represents the stock of bonds and M represents the stock of money. Applying logs in both sides of the equation one obtains the differential equation dlog(r t ) = dlog(b t ) dlog(m t ) (1) Notice that the interest rate elasticities with respect to bonds and money supply are unitary. In this context, an increase of bond/money ratio always results in an increment of interest rate. However, if we consider a stochastic model, under estimation, it is possible that both elasticities fail to be unitary. In this sense the elasticity of money could be higher or lower than the elasticity of public bonds. Therefore a general statistical model would note impose any direction for the difference. The actual relation would be statistically tested. The most important implication of the Martins model is that in a world which the decisions to accumulate wealth are associated with spending decisions, and in which the only difference between money ( M ) and bonds ( B ) lies in their holding periods, the nominal interest rate ( i ) is basically determined by the bonds/money ratio. In this sense, the nominal rate of interest is determined by the relative supply of bonds with respect to money, and bears no relationship to the rate of inflation. This result implies that the Fisherian theory of nominal interest rate (Fisher [1930], chaps. 2 and 19) does not hold. This article tests REP using Martins (1980) model fitting the statistical model R lt = f ( Blt, B lt 1,..., B ) lt p, zlt 1 M lt M lt 1 M,..., zk lt + u lt (2) lt p Here (1 + i lt ) = R lt. The subscript l represents Canada, Japan and US and tis year. The analyses cover the period 1980-2006. The z j are contextual variables. 2. Empirical Results As a proxy for the nominal interest rate we use the lending interest rate. This information and the stock of money are available in Word Bank (2008). Lending interest rate is the rate charged by banks on loans to prime customers. We use as a proxy for money M1. Data are in current local currency. As a proxy for the government debt or bonds we use the general government gross debt. General government gross debt (national currency) comprises the stock (at year-end) of all government gross liabilities (both to residents and nonresidents). To avoid double counting, the data are based on a consolidated account (eliminating liabilities and assets between components of the government, such as budgetary units and social security funds). General government should reflect a consolidated account of central government plus state, provincial, or local governments. The source of data is the IMF (2008). The contextual variables are all dummy variables to differentiate the countries. The basis is the US. All variables are measured in natural logs. Our choice of countries was dictated by data availability. Only Canada, Japan and the US provided a long enough time series for the analysis on public debt. 2

2.1 Panel Data Analysis The dynamic panel model we use follows Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). Table I shows the estimation results for the basic model R lt = β 0 + β 1 R l, t 1 + β 2 R l, t 2 + β 3 (B/M) lt + β 4 (B/M) l, t 1 + 2 δ l=1 ld l + 2 α =1 ld l (B/M) l, t + 2 γ l=1 ld l (B/M) l, t 1 + η l + ε lt (3) where η i is a random effect for country iand ε it is an error component not showing serial correlation of second order. The model imposes different intercepts and different bond/money coefficients for each country and common effects for the lagged interest rates. Table I Estimation Results (Stata 10 output) Variables Coefficients Robust Sd p-values R t 1 0.813 0.052 < 0.001 R t 2-0.197 0.044 < 0.001 (B/M) t 0.040 0.005 < 0.001 (B/M) t 1-0.047 0.001 < 0.001 D 1 (B/M) 1 t -0.023 0.012 0.048 D 1 (B/M) 1, t 1 0.038 0.004 < 0.001 D 2 (B/M) 2, t -0.032 0.004 < 0.001 D 2 (B/M) 2, t 1 0.021 0.003 < 0.001 D 1-0.020 0.014 0.145 D 2 0.002 0.008 0.807 Constant 0.286 0.071 < 0.001 The test for the presence of second order autocorrelation has a p-value of 19,8% and the model seems to be adequate. All variables are significant at the 5% level, except the dummies. We can see from Table II that the net effect of (B/M) is negative and statistically significant for Japan and US and it is positive and statistically significant for Canada. Table II Long Run Net Effects Countries β 3 + α l β 4 + γ l Long run net effect Sd p-value Canada 0.017-0.009 0.008 1.73E-14 < 0.001 Japan 0.008-0.026-0.018 6.36E-14 < 0.001 US 0.040-0.047-0.007 2.90E-14 < 0.001 Conclusions We found empirical evidence that the nominal interest rate is not independent of the bond/money ratio and therefore that the Ricardian Equivalence proposition is not valid for US, Japan and Canada for the period 1980-2006. We found the net effect between bond and money elasticities positive for Canada and negative for Japan and the US. Theoretically the net effect should be positive. We point out two major reasons to explain negative empirical result for Japan and the US. Firstly is that Martins (1980) model is valid only for closed economies and the IMF measurement of government debt comprises all government 3

gross liabilities for both residents and non residents. Finally the theoretical model assumes the debt formed exclusively by treasury bills. Furthermore, the theoretical model does not assume measurement of stock of debt by a discounted flow of government bonds. This, very likely, is the case with the IMF data. A suggestion for further investigation involves an extension of Martins (1980) model for an open economy. This line of research should take into account possible financial linkages among the countries that might transfer REP to the exchange rate. References: Arellano, M., and O. Bover (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29-51. Barro, R. J. (1974) Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?, Journal of Political Economy 82, 1095-1117. Blundell, R., and S.Bond (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel-data models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115-143. Bowen, W.G.; Davis, R.G.; and Kopf, D.H. (1960). The Public Debt: A Burden on Future Generations?. American Economic Review 50, no. 4, September, pp: 701-706. Correia-Nunes J. and Stemitsiotis L. (1995), Budget deficit an interest rates: Is there a link? International evidence, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 57, pp. 425-449. Evans, Paul (1993). Consumers are not Ricardian: Evidence from Nineteen Countries. Economic Inquiry, Vol. XXXI, October, pp: 534-548. Evans, Paul (1995). Do Large Deficits Produce High Interest Rates?, American Economic Review, Vol. 85, N 1, pp.68-87. Evans, Paul (1987a). Interest Rates and Expected Future Budget Deficits in the United States, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 95, N 1, Feb., pp.34-58. Evans, Paul (1987b). Do Budget Deficits Raise Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Six Countries, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 20, pp.281-300. Evans, Paul (1988). Are Government Bonds Net Wealth? Evidence for the United States, Economic Inquiry, Vol. XXVI, pp. 551-566. Fisher, Irving (1930). The Theory of Interest, Reprint. New York: Kelly, 1970. I.M.F. (2008). International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April. Hoelscher, Gregory, (1986). New Evidence on Deficits and Interest Rates, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 18, N 1, Feb., pp.1-17. Martins, Marco A. C. (1979). Theoretical Problems in the Theory of the Burden on the Debt. Working Paper in www.aeconomiadobrasil.com.br. Lindé, Jesper. (1998). Fiscal Policy and the Yield Curve in a Small Open Economy, 4

Working paper Series in Economics and Finance N 220, Revised Version, November 17. Martins, Marco A. C. (1980). A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, No. 1, Feb., pp. 174-185. Rodrigues, Pavel C. (2006). The Ricardian Equivalence Proposition in OCDE Countries: Does Government Debt Wight Down Growth?. Dissertation in Economics and International Economics in the School of Economics, University of Nottingham. W.D.I. (2008). World Development Indicators. World Bank Home Page. 5