Q2. Time Series Analysis: Capital Gains Realizations and the Average Effective Tax Rates Q2.

Similar documents
TAX EXPENDITURES Fall 2012

Case Study: Predicting U.S. Saving Behavior after the 2008 Financial Crisis (proposed solution)

CHAPTER III METHODOLOGY

Capital Gains Tax Realizations and Tax Rates: New Evidence From Time Series. March 1, 2000

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated

Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

On the Measurement of the Government Spending Multiplier in the United States An ARDL Cointegration Approach

Financial Liberalization and Money Demand in Mauritius

Weak Policy in an Open Economy: The US with a Floating Exchange Rate, Henry Thompson

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

A SEARCH FOR A STABLE LONG RUN MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION FOR THE US

How can saving deposit rate and Hang Seng Index affect housing prices : an empirical study in Hong Kong market

An Empirical Study on the Determinants of Dollarization in Cambodia *

Long Run Money Neutrality: The Case of Guatemala

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Capital Gains Tax Options: Behavioral Responses and Revenues

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

The Demand for Money in Mexico i

CROWDING-IN EFFECT OF BUDGET DEFICIT EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN ( )

Alexander O. Baranov

Determinants of Stock Prices in Ghana

Employment growth and Unemployment rate reduction: Historical experiences and future labour market outcomes

DATA CHOICE IN CAPITAL GAINS REALISATION RESPONSE STUDIES - A REVIEW JOHN MINAS*

Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology

competition for a country s exports at the global scene. Thus, in this situation, a successful real devaluation 2 can improve and enhance export earni

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

CHAPTER V RELATION BETWEEN FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH DURING PRE AND POST LIBERALISATION PERIOD

Linkage between Gold and Crude Oil Spot Markets in India-A Cointegration and Causality Analysis

Empirical Analysis of Private Investments: The Case of Pakistan

The Impact of Currency Fluctuations on Palm Oil Exports

Thi-Thanh Phan, Int. Eco. Res, 2016, v7i6, 39 48

Supplementary Appendix. July 22, 2016

Capital Gains Taxes and Realizations: Evidence from a Long Panel of State-Level Data

Openness and Inflation

The estimation of money demand in the Slovak Republic Ing. Viera Kollárová, Ing. Rastislav âársky National Bank of Slovakia

The Economic Consequences of Dollar Appreciation for US Manufacturing Investment: A Time-Series Analysis

Economics 413: Economic Forecast and Analysis Department of Economics, Finance and Legal Studies University of Alabama

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN REALIZED CAPITAL GAINS AND THEIR MARGINAL RATE OF TAXATION,

THE DESIGN OF THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Estimating Egypt s Potential Output: A Production Function Approach

Graduated from Glasgow University in 2009: BSc with Honours in Mathematics and Statistics.

Incorporation of Fixed-Flexible Exchange Rates in Econometric Trade Models: A Grafted Polynomial Approach

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

Swedish Lessons: How Important are ICT and R&D to Economic Growth? Paper prepared for the 34 th IARIW General Conference, Dresden, Aug 21-27, 2016

Growth 2. Chapter 6 (continued)

HOW DOES CHARITABLE GIVING RESPOND TO INCENTIVES AND INCOME? NEW ESTIMATES FROM PANEL DATA. Jon Bakija and Bradley T. Heim

What variables have historically impacted Kentucky and Iowa farmland values? John Barnhart

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract

Contribution of transport to economic growth and productivity in New Zealand

Market Integration, Price Discovery, and Volatility in Agricultural Commodity Futures P.Ramasundaram* and Sendhil R**

Market Reforms in the Time of Imbalance: Online Appendix

IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC VARIABLE ON STOCK MARKET RETURN AND ITS VOLATILITY

ESTIMATING INFLATION TAX REVENUE FOR THE DEVELOPING NATIONS: A CASE STUDY IN BANGLADESH [ FY FY ] H.

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

CAN MONEY SUPPLY PREDICT STOCK PRICES?

POLYTECHNIC OF NAMIBIA SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF ACCOUNTING, ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ECONOMETRICS. Mr.

IMPACT OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT ON SELECTED MACRO ECONOMIC PARAMETERS OF INDIA AND CHINA

An Investigation into the Sensitivity of Money Demand to Interest Rates in the Philippines

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE OF THE TRANSITION COUNTRY THE CASE OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC

D6.3 Policy Brief: The role of debt for fiscal effectiveness during crisis and normal times

Impact of Commercial Banks Lending to Small and Medium Scale Enterprises on Economic Growth of Nepal

Class 13 Question 2 Estimating Taxable Income Responses Using Danish Tax Reforms Kleven and Schultz (2014)

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Determinants of Merchandise Export Performance in Sri Lanka

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

A case study of Cointegration relationship between Tax Revenue and Foreign Direct Investment: Evidence from Sri Lanka

On the Importance of Labour Productivity Growth: Portugal vs. Ireland

CFA Level 2 - LOS Changes

Taxable Income Responses to 1990s Tax Acts: Further Explorations

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Aggregate Supply and Demand

Journal of the Australasian Tax Teachers Association 2014 Vol. 9 No. 1 JOHN MINAS*

DYNAMIC CORRELATIONS AND FORECASTING OF TERM STRUCTURE SLOPES IN EUROCURRENCY MARKETS

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Online Appendices for

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion

Brief Sketch of Solutions: Tutorial 1. 2) descriptive statistics and correlogram. Series: LGCSI Sample 12/31/ /11/2009 Observations 2596

Composite Coincident and Leading Economic Indexes

Applications of Exponential Functions Group Activity 7 Business Project Week #10

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Brief Sketch of Solutions: Tutorial 2. 2) graphs. 3) unit root tests

The Elasticity of Taxable Income During the 1990s: A Sensitivity Analysis

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

AN INVESTIGATION ON THE TRANSACTION MOTIVATION AND THE SPECULATIVE MOTIVATION OF THE DEMAND FOR MONEY IN SRI LANKA

Determinants of Launch Spreads on EM USD-Denominated Corporate Bonds

Transcription:

Econ 74 Public Economics Assignment #3 Q. Time Series Analysis: Capital Gains Realizations and the Average Effective Tax Rates Q. a) The time series of realizations of capital gains as a percentage of GDP (PGDP) and the average effective tax rates (MTR) is plotted in the graphs below. The first graph shows the returns with positive net capital gains, including returns with positive total net capital gains, both short and long term, as a percentage of nominal GDP and the average effective rates from 1954 to 005; the second graph shows the long term capital gains, including returns with positive long term gains in excess of any short term losses, as a percentage of nominal GDP. I also add four reference lines of Year 1981, 1986.5, 1997, and 003, when the maximum tax rate on long term capital gains went through significant changes. In 1981, the maximum tax rate reduced from 8% to 0%; later on, the rate jumped back to 8% in 1987. The maximum tax rate increases gradually up to 9.19% in 1997 and then reduced to 1.19% in the same year. Finally in 003, the maximum tax rate decreased from 1.05% to 16.05% Eyeballing the data with the focus on the four major time reference points, it appears that the realization of capital gains moves at an opposite direction of the average effective tax rates. Returns with Positive Net Capital Gains 1954-005 Long Term Capital Gains 1977-005 0 5 10 15 0 5 % 0 5 10 15 0 5 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 000 005 Yr 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 000 005 Yr PGDP MTR PGDP MTR b) Time series analysis: Most of prior research using time series analysis used the long term capital gains as the dependent variable, and my analysis below will also focuses on the long term capital gains using the data from 1977 to 005 in order to determine the permanent effect of the change in average effective tax rates on the realizations of capital gains. Using the specifications of CBO (1988) 1, Auerback (1989) and my own adjustments, I obtained the stimates of coefficients of different specifications in Table A below: 1 Congressional Budget Office, 1988, How Capital Gains Tax Rates Affect Revenues: the Historical Evidence, March. Alan J. Auerbach, 1989, Capital Gains Taxation and Tax Reform, National Tax Journal, 4, 3, P. 391 401.

Econ 74 Public Economics Assignment #3 Q. Time Series Analysis Table A. Time Series Regressions of Long Term Capital Gains Realizations [1] [] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10] VARIABLES lnncg lnncg lnrcg lnrcg dlnncg dlnncg dlnncg dlnrcg dlnrcg dlnrcg dlnprice 1.739 0.879 1.906 [3.035] [3.9] [.537] dlnrce_d 0.007 0.635 0.041 0.08 0.607 0.003 [0.363] [0.480] [0.366] [0.58] [0.411] [0.37] dlnrgdp 9.719** 9.513** 6.367 7.803* 6.185* 6.335 8.098** 6.119 [.759] [.459] [3.654] [3.47] [.978] [3.865] [3.077] [3.63] dlnnyse 1.185 1.47 1.196* 1.15 1.43 1.46* [0.79] [0.947] [0.597] [0.66] [0.834] [0.514] dmtr 0.0889* 0.187** 0.09** 0.0888* 0.186** 0.0948** [0.0369] [0.057] [0.034] [0.0354] [0.0508] [0.0310] dmtr 0.046 0.138* 0.06 0.046 0.139** 0.08 [0.046] [0.0548] [0.0474] [0.0443] [0.055] [0.0458] L.dlnNCG 0.347 0.488* 0.309 [0.18] [0.47] [0.183] lnprice 0.769 0.894 [1.188] [1.65] lnrce_d 0.45 0.468* 0.463 0.541** [0.77] [0.181] [0.64] [0.178] lnrgdp 0.673 1.863 0.44 0.18 [1.36] [1.486] [0.660] [0.451] MTR 0.0507* 0.0471* 0.055** 0.0581** [0.0181] [0.0166] [0.0154] [0.0143] L.dlnRCG 0.361 0.485* 0.38* [0.195] [0.34] [0.166] Constant 0.477 11.05.416 3.886 0.56 0.58 0.6 0.45 0.84* 0.45 [10.47] [1.88] [.564] [.164] [0.168] [0.183] [0.136] [0.167] [0.140] [0.141] Observations 7 6 7 6 4 4 4 4 4 4 R squared 0.793 0.854 0.641 0.744 0.567 0. 0.553 0.574 0.1 0.56 Robust standard errors in brackets ** p<0.01, * p<0.05 D.W. 0.719 1.83 0.77 1.119.075.049 AIC 0.958 1.3 18.991 11.785 7.917 5.73 BIC 7.437 19.778 4.175 18.076 17.34 13.977

Econ 74 Public Economics Assignment #3 In specifications 1 through 4, I use CBO specifications by taking log of the values of variables before running the regression. The estimations are as follows: (1) Ln( NCG) = 0.477 0.769Ln Pr ice + 0.45LnRCE + 0.673LnRGDP 0.0507MTR, DW.. = 0.719 (0.0166) (10.47) (1.188) (0.77) (1.36) (0.0181) () Ln( NCG) = 11.05 + 0.894Ln Price + 0.468LnRCE + 1.863LnRGDP + 9.719dLnRGDP 0.0471MTR, DW.. = 1.83 (1.88) (1.65) (0.181) (1.486) (.759) (3) Ln( RCG) =.416 + 0.463LnRCE + 0.44LnRGDP 0.055MTR, DW.. = 0.77 (.564) (0.64) (0.66) (0.0154) (4) Ln( RCG) = 3.886 + 0.541LnRCE + 0.18LnRGDP + 9.513dLnRGDP 0.0581MTR, DW.. = 1.119 (.164) (0.178) (0.451) (.459) (0.0143) Variable Definitions: Ln(NCG) = logarithm of nominal net long term capital gains, in excess of net short term losses; LnPRICE = logarithm of the GDP deflator using Year 000 as the base year; LnRCE = logarithm of the real value of corporate equities directly held by households and nonprofit organizations GDP (using Year 000 as the base year); LnRGDP = logarithm of real GDP (using Year 000 as the base year); dlnrgdp = change in the logarithm of GDP (using Year 000 as the base year) MTR = average effective tax rate on capital gains; and Ln(RCG) = logarithm of real net long term gains, in excess of net short term losses (using Year 000 as the base year). The Durban Watson d statistics of CBO specifications indicate that the regressions may have positively serial correlation issues. After running the augmented Dickey Fuller test, it also indicated the level logarithm value of the realization of capital gains, in both nominal and real terms, is not stationary. In order to address the non stationary and serial correlation issue, specification 5 followed Auerback s original specification by taking the first difference of the logarithm of the values of most variables, except of the average effective tax rates. After taking the first difference, the data available for the analysis is from 1979 to 005. Auerbach s specification is as follows:

Econ 74 Public Economics Assignment #3 (0.168) (3.035) (0.363) (3.654) (0.79) 0.0889dMTR 0.046( 1) 0.347dLnCG( 1), (0.0369) (0.046) (0.18) (5) dln( NCG) = 0.56 1.739dLn Pr ice 0.007LnRCE + 6.367dLnRGDP + 1.185dLnNYSE + + R = 0.567, DW.. =.075, AIC = 7.917, BIC = 17.34 dln(ncg) = change of the logarithm of nominal net long term capital gains, in excess of net short term losses; dlnprice = change of the logarithm of the GDP deflator using Year 000 as the base year; dlnrce = change of the logarithm of the real value of corporate equities directly held by households and nonprofit organizations GDP (using Year 000 as the base year); dlnrgdp = change of the logarithm of real GDP (using Year 000 as the base year); dlnnyse = change of the logarithm of the New York Stock Exchange Index; dmtr = change of the average effective tax rate on capital gains; d MTR(+1) = change in the average effective tax rate one year ahead; dlncg( 1) = change of the lagged value of capital gains realizations. In this original specification, since realizations of capital gain is in nominal term, we need a price index to control for inflation and therefore GDP deflator using 000 as the base year is included in the right hand side. Further, the corporate equity held directly by individual and non profit organization is added since the realization could fluctuates with the shares these people holds. Real GDP is included to control the economic growth as a benchmark of capital gains realization, and the NYSE index is included since stock price is the key determinant in terms of selling decision of stocks. Auerbach also includes a lead variable of the change of future tax rate to gauge the issue of forward looking nature in stock market; i.e. if people expect the future tax rate to rise, they may act before the timing of its realization. Last, the lagged of capital gains realizations is also included since it may affect the current capital gains realization (if people sold majority shares in last period without replacing the portfolio with new purchases of other stocks, the capital gains realizations may hence reduce.) One particular concern with Auerbach s initial specification is the endogeneity issue. Since capital gains realizations affect the average effective tax rate, we may need to consider using instrumental variables to get around with this issue. I suggest using the maximum tax rate on long term capital gain as our IVs for the estimates. As the maximum tax rate changes may happen in the middle of a year, I used either the old tax rate as the IV in equation 6, or the new tax rate as the IV in equation 7 when such scenario occurs. (6) dln( NCG) = 0.58 0.879dLn Price 0.635LnRCE + 7.803dLnRGDP + 1.47dLnNYSE 0.187dMTR R (0.183) (3.9) (0.48) (3.47) (0.947) (0.057) 0.138( 1) (0.057) 0.488dLnCG( 1), (0.47) + + = 0. (7) dln( NCG) = 0.6 1.906dLn Price 0.041LnRCE + 6.185dLnRGDP + 1.196dLnNYSE 0.09dMTR (0.0474) (0.183) (0.136) (.537) (0.366) (.978) (0.597) (0.034) + 0.06 ( + 1) 0.309dLnCG( 1), R = 0.553

Econ 74 Public Economics Assignment #3 To make the model more parsimonious, I revised Auerback s specification and replaced the dependent variable by replacing the nominal value of the realization of capital gains with the real value of the realization of capital gains using the GDP deflator of base year 000. (8) dln( RCG) = 0.45 0.08LnRCE + 6.335dLnRGDP + 1.15dLnNYSE 0.0888dMTR (0.0443) (0.195) (0.167) (0.58) (3.865) (0.66) (0.0354) + 0.046 ( + 1) 0.361dLnCG( 1), R DW AIC BIC = 0.574,.. =.049, = 5.73, = 13.977 (9) dln( RCG) = 0.84 0.607LnRCE + 8.098dLnRGDP + 1.43dLnNYSE 0.186dMTR (0.055) (0.34) (0.14) (0.411) (3.077) (0.834) (0.0508) + 0.139 ( + 1) 0.485dLnCG( 1), R = 0.1 (10) dln( RCG) = 0.45 0.003LnRCE + 6.119dLnRGDP + 1.46dLnNYSE 0.0948dMTR (0.0458) (0.166) (0.141) (0.37) (3.63) (0.514) (0.031) + 0.08 ( + 1) 0.38dLnCG( 1), R = 0.56 dln(rcg) = change of the logarithm of real net long term gains, in excess of net short term losses (using Year 000 as the base year). All other variables are defined in the same way in Equation 5. Using the same IV strategy, we have equation 9 and 10 as the counterpart to equation 6 and 7 when the change of tax rate took place in the middle of a particular year. Using the change of the old maximum tax rates (equation 6 and equation 9) when the tax rate change occurred in the middle of a year as the IV significantly reduced the R, but in contrast, using the new maximum tax rates as the IV does not substantially change the R and it addressed the endogeneity issue since the maximum tax rate is truly exogenous to the realization of capital gains. Therefore, my final model would be equation 10.

Econ 74 Public Economics Assignment #3 Using Auerbach s elasticity calculations method, the estimated elasticity of realizations with respect to effective tax rates would be as follow 3 : MTR = 15% MTR = 0% MTR = 5% Elasticity using Equation 5 -.99-1.3-1.64 Elasticity using Equation 7-1.05-1.40-1.76 Elasticity using Equation 8-0.97-1.30-1.63 Elasticity using Equation 10-1.07-1.43-1.78 c) The optimal tax rate would be 15.3% using the specification in equation 8, and 14% using equation 10; compared with 15.15% using equation 5 (estimates without IVs) and 14.3% using equation 7 (estimate using IVs). If the current MTR is 15%, it is very close to the optimal tax rate and therefore the government shall keep the tax rate no lower than 14%. Any further adjustment of the tax rate will cause a reduction in the capital gains realizations and hence might reduce the total tax revenues. d) The elasticity estimates from the time series analysis above is between Burman and Randolph s estimate of the elasticity of the permanent tax effect, approximately 0.18, and the elasticity of transitory effect, approximately 6.4. Burman and Randolph s results may be more reliable than my estimates since they separate the effects into permanent and transitory effects that may capture some short term responses in individuals behaviors to the change of tax policies and explain the inverse relationship we observed in the graphs in part a). Second, Burman and Randolph s model overcomes the shortcoming of aggregation bias that my model may have via using an aggregated data. Last, Burman and Randolph s model is less sensitive to sample period that time series models typically does. On the other hand, my results will be more reliable than the results of Burman and Randolph s in terms of the following perspectives: first of all, time series analysis estimates long run realization elasticities better. In Burman and Randolph s paper, their data sets do not encompass a long enough time period (they had the data of tax returns from 1979 1983) to be able to reliably separate out long run from transitory elasticities. Furthermore, the cross state differences in tax rates that they use as an IV for permanent tax effect may not affect taxpayers' behavior in the same way as a change in the tax rate, especially if the state taxes are correlated with other characteristics of the state residents or if capital gains realizations are not in equilibrium. Last but not least, in the time series model, we are able to allow the elasticities to vary depending on the current tax rate would provide a better indictor in policy decision. 3 Follow Auerbach s method to calculate the elasticity as the dmtr coefficient divided by 1 plus the coefficient of lagged capital gains, all multiplied by the MTR rate itself.