John Hills, Francesca Bastagli, Frank Cowell, Howard Glennerster, Eleni Karagiannaki and Abigail McKnight

Similar documents
Wealth inequality and accumulation. John Hills, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of Economics

Wealth accumulation in Great Britain : The role of house prices and the life cycle

Report of the National Equality Panel: Executive summary

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Briefing Paper BP1/2015. New survey research on public attitudes to wealth taxes. Karen Rowlingson, Andy Lymer and Rajiv Prabhakar.

The impact of inheritance on the distribution of wealth: Evidence from the UK

The Relative Role of Socio- Economic Factors in Explaining the Changing Distribution of Wealth in

Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament

Broad shoulders and tight belts: Options for taxing the better-off

RECENT TRENDS IN THE SIZE AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF INHERITED WEALTH IN THE UK

Inequality and Social Mobility. Econ 101

BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE INEQUALITY IN LATER LIFE. The superannuation effect. Helen Hodgson, Alan Tapper and Ha Nguyen

Poverty and Income Inequality in Scotland: 2013/14 A National Statistics publication for Scotland

Estimating the Cost to Government of Providing Undergraduate and Postgraduate Education

STRUCTURAL REFORM REFORMING THE PENSION SYSTEM IN KOREA. Table 1: Speed of Aging in Selected OECD Countries. by Randall S. Jones

ROYAL LONDON POLICY PAPER Will we ever summit the pension mountain? ROYAL LONDON POLICY PAPER 21. Will we ever summit the pension mountain?

United Kingdom. Qualifying conditions. Key indicators. United Kingdom: Pension system in 2012

STATE PENSIONS AND THE WELL-BEING OF

Income tax cuts in 2018 Budget will largely benefit men

PENSIONS POLICY INSTITUTE. Comparison of pension outcomes under EET and TEE tax treatment

THE MILLION DOLLAR BE-QUESTION

The study expands and delves deeper into an earlier presentation in Ekonomisk Debatt 2015, nos. 7 and 8. 7

Changes to work and income around state pension age

IFS Green Budget Press Release

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2009: RETIREMENT INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES NORWAY

The new state of donation: Three decades of household giving to charity

PENSIONS POLICY INSTITUTE. Automatic enrolment changes

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Working Paper No Changes in Household Wealth in the 1980s and 1990s in the U.S.

Tax policy and inequality

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada:

The Magnitude and Correlates of Inter-vivos Transfers in the UK

Tax By Design: The Mirrlees Review

Poverty, inequality and policy since 1997

LECTURE 14: THE INEQUALITY OF CAPITAL OWNERSHIP IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Economic Standard of Living

Women s pay and employment update: a public/private sector comparison

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Russian Federation

Trends in Income Inequality in Ireland

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Brazil

Economic standard of living

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Costa Rica

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Switzerland

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Congo

European Commission Directorate-General "Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities" Unit E1 - Social and Demographic Analysis

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Argentina

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Turkey

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Belgium

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Peru

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Uzbekistan

The 2008 Statistics on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

DEMOGRAPHIC DRIVERS. Household growth is picking up pace. With more. than a million young foreign-born adults arriving

Martina Lawless and Donal Lynch Scenarios and Distributional Implications of a Household Wealth Tax in Ireland 1

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION 2013

Income and Poverty Among Older Americans in 2008

Eswatini (Kingdom of)

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Paraguay

GERMANY REVIEW OF PROGRESS ON POLICY MEASURES RELEVANT FOR THE

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Nigeria

The Changing Distribution of Wealth. in the pre-crisis US and UK

The distribution of wealth in the United States and implications for a net worth tax

THE CHANCELLOR S CHOICES

Regressing Towards Proportionality: Personal Income Tax Reform in New Brunswick

FIGURE I.1. Income inequality in the United States,

* We wish to thank Jim Smith for useful comments on a previous draft and Tim Veenstra for excellent computer assistance.

Employment of older people in England:

Poverty and income inequality

Household debt inequalities

High income families. The characteristics of families with low incomes are often studied in detail in order to assist in the

Distribution of Wealth In Ireland

Investing for Children

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

The cost of a child in Donald Hirsch

Real Britain Index RBI explained

Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Ontario August Losing Ground. Income Inequality in Ontario, Sheila Block

Fiscal policy and inequality

Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England

Retirement Savings and Household Wealth in 2007

Women Leading UK Employment Boom

Care and State Pension Reform Interactions between state pension and long-term care reforms: a summary of findings

Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: Jonathan Cribb Agnes Norris Keiller Tom Waters

Are you prepared for retirement?

A3.02: CAPITAL GAINS TAX (CGT)

FEATURES AND BENEFITS OF ONSHORE INVESTMENT BONDS.

BUDGET Québec and the Fight Against Poverty. Social Solidarity

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Dominica

Download the full paper»

BRIEFING. Housing pinched. Understanding which households spend the most on housing costs. Laura Gardiner

WOMEN'S CURRENT PENSION ARRANGEMENTS: INFORMATION FROM THE GENERAL HOUSEHOLD SURVEY. Sandra Hutton Julie Williams Steven Kennedy

housing Assessment of the impact of Warm Front on decent homes for private sector vulnerable households Housing Research Summary Introduction

Small Self-Administered Scheme (SSAS)

Reference Guide TESTAMENTARY TRUSTS

Optimum Financial Solutions. Spring Brighter Future for the economy. 2 billion extra for social care and tax rise for self-employed

INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT

In this summary, we include planning suggestions for: Income Tax. Capital Gains Tax. Inheritance Tax. Pensions. Offshore matters

Inequality in China: Recent Trends. Terry Sicular (University of Western Ontario)

THE TAX AND BENEFIT SYSTEM AND THE DECISION TO INVEST IN A STAKEHOLDER PENSION

Transcription:

CASEbrief 33 May 2013 Wealth distribution, accumulation, and policy John Hills, Francesca Bastagli, Frank Cowell, Howard Glennerster, Eleni Karagiannaki and Abigail McKnight Household wealth in Great Britain amounted to 5.5 trillion in 2008-10 on Office for National Statistics estimates, excluding private pension rights (or 10 trillion including them). Wealth (excluding pension rights) was four times national income by the mid-2000s, compared with only twice national income in the 1960s and 1970s. Wealth is far more unequally distributed than incomes or earnings. In all, the top tenth of households owned 850 times the total wealth of the bottom tenth in 2008-10. The least wealthy household in the top tenth had 967,200, seventy-seven times that of the household at the top of the bottom tenth. The top 1 per cent had 14 per cent of the total, with an average of more than 5 million. Household survey-based estimates suggest that wealth inequality fell between 1995 and 2005, as the wealth of moderately wealthy grew proportionately faster as a result of the house price boom than did the financial wealth of those at the very top. However, absolute differences widened considerably between 1995 and 2005 in real terms it would now take many more years of saving for someone with a middle income to move up the distribution from the middle towards the top. By the mid-2000s, estates left to others (excluding to spouses) had an annual value of around 35 billion, about 4 per cent of national income. Each year around one adult in forty receives an inheritance, but these are very unequally distributed. Over the ten years from 1996 to 2005, one in five individuals reported receiving inheritances, but half of the total went to the top tenth of inheritors, just 2 per cent of all individuals. There appear to be long-lasting advantages for education, employment, earnings, health, and well-being for children from wealthier family backgrounds and for those with assets early in adulthood, even after controlling for other factors. Looking across tax and social policies such as social security, housing, education, and care, it is hard to discern a consistent pattern for the treatment of wealth and saving. Despite the growing value of personal wealth relative to incomes, its taxation has become much less important as proportions of overall tax revenue and of national income over the last fifty years. The present combination of policies results in sharp differences in treatment between people. Some are strongly encouraged to accumulate particular kinds of wealth, while others face strong disincentives to do so. These features often reinforce wealth inequalities, rather than narrow them. Further information This CASEbrief summarises findings from Wealth in the UK: Distribution, accumulation, and policy, published by Oxford University Press (ISBN 978-0-19-976830-3). The book is available from booksellers or from Oxford University Press (24 hour hotline +44 (0) 1536 454534; e- mail bookorders@oup.co.uk, price 55 hardback).

A picture of wealth inequality Figure 1 draws on the Office for National Statistics Wealth and Assets Survey (WAS) carried out between July 2008 and June 2010. It shows the distribution of total wealth between households. This includes personal possessions, net financial assets, housing assets (net of mortgages) and the value of people s non-state pension rights. Each bar shows the level of total wealth at that percentile, from the poorest (with negative wealth) up to the point where the top one per cent of households begins. Median wealth was 232,400 (with half of households having more and half less). The cut-off for the wealthiest tenth of households, 967,200, was seventy-seven times the cut-off for the bottom tenth, 12,600. The top one per cent of households each have total assets worth more than 2.8 million. Figure 1: Distribution of total wealth between households, 2008-10, GB Source: Derived from ONS analysis of July 2008 to June 2010 wave of Wealth and Assets Survey. Total wealth includes private pension rights as well as personal possessions, net financial assets, and housing (net of mortgages). Each column represents the wealth of one per cent of households. Wealth inequalities are, of course, strongly linked to the life cycle. Most people start their working careers with little by way of assets, but build them up through their working lives, and run down their savings through retirement. Those in their late 50s and early 60s are the wealthiest. But there are large inequalities within each age group as well for instance with a ratio of fifty to one between the cut-offs for the wealthiest and poorest tenths of 55-64 year-old households. Considerable wealth inequalities remain even after allowing for life-cycle differences. In international terms wealth inequality in the UK does not appear exceptionally large. Indeed, household wealth inequality measures are lower for the UK than in Sweden and Canada, as well as in the USA, even when one corrects the surveys used for under-reporting at the very top. Wealth plays a different role in these

countries, though, with mean per capita wealth values that are twice as high in the UK as in Sweden and Canada (although they are only 60 per cent of the US figure). Wealth holdings are therefore lower and absolute differences smaller in Sweden and Canada. Trends in wealth distribution Inequalities of wealth between individuals fell considerably between the 1920s and the 1970s. The pattern since then has been more stable, but our study suggests that overall wealth inequality between households fell between 1995 and 2005, as the wealth of moderately wealthy households grew proportionately faster with the house price boom than did the financial wealth of those at the very top. However, absolute differences between the more and less wealthy widened considerably between 1995 and 2005 in real terms and in relation to annual earnings. It would now take many more years of saving for someone with a middle income to increase their wealth from near the bottom to the middle, or from the middle to near the top of the wealth distribution than it would have done in the early 1990s. Wealth accumulation between 1995 and 2005 Data from the British Household Panel Study suggests that household wealth inequality fell between 1995 and 2005, but nearly all of the reduction in relative household wealth inequality was driven by the house price boom: without it the pattern would have looked very similar in the two years. Over this period what mattered most was whether people were able to gain from the house price boom. The house price boom favoured mortgagors, those in middle age, and the more highly qualified. Those who were owner-occupiers by 2005 were both the most wealthy and had the largest wealth increases. Increases in net wealth averaged 186,000 (at 2005 prices) for mortgagors who became outright owners, for instance. Following the same households between 1995 and 2005, the absolute gains in wealth were largest for groups who started as the most wealthy, but the proportionate gains were largest for the least wealthy groups. Inheritance By the mid-2000s, around 200,000 estates each year (excluding those passing to spouses) had a value of around 35 billion, or about 4 per cent of national income. The average of 175,000 was divided between 4-5 inheritors. Each year around one adult in forty receives an inheritance, averaging 28,000 (at 2005 prices) between 2000 and 2005. But inheritances are very unequally distributed. Over the ten years from 1996 to 2005, one in five individuals reported receiving inheritances, with a mean total of 35,000, but a median of only 7,600. Half the total went to the top 10 per cent of these inheritors, just 2 per cent of all individuals. Both the chances of receiving an inheritance and its average size are greater for those who are already more advantaged in other ways such as through educational attainment, home-ownership and pre-existing wealth. In that way, inheritance tends

to reinforce advantage and widen differences in wealth. But some inheritors start with little or no wealth and are moved up the distribution by an inheritance, which has an equalising effect. Inheritance therefore has mixed effects on wealth inequality. Overall, partly because the pre-inheritance distribution of wealth is so unequal already, inheritance in recent years tended to maintain the inequality of wealth, rather than to change it hugely in either direction. Impacts of parental wealth and of early wealth-holding Evidence from different surveys suggests long-lasting advantages for children from wealthier family backgrounds and for those who are able to accumulate assets early in adulthood: Controlling for other factors, greater parental wealth is associated with greater degree level educational attainment, with the largest effects coming from housing wealth. Differences are largest between those with low and with middle wealth. Parental asset-poverty (debt) has a significant negative association with children s probability of being in work at age 25, while parental wealth has a positive and significant association with children s earnings at age 25, again with greater effects for lower wealth families. Early holding of financial assets (at age 23), and the size of the asset held, are associated with greater employment and earnings (at 33 and 42), even controlling for a wide range of other characteristics, although patterns vary between men and women. There is also a positive relationship between early asset-holding and subsequent general health and psychological well-being ten and even twenty years later, again with variation in the effects between men and women at different ages. Overall, both having wealthier parents and having more of one s own financial assets early in adulthood are associated with improved outcomes in education, employment and health outcomes which can themselves lead to further accumulations of wealth, increasing the gaps still further, as well as directly improving quality of life. Policies towards wealth Contrasting traditions for the appropriate role of policy towards wealth can be traced back for more than two centuries. Conservative traditions emphasise freedom to save and use wealth as individuals choose, and avoidance of disincentives to accumulate it. Radical traditions stress the ways in which unequal wealth holdings lead to imbalances in power and in life opportunities. Yet both traditions see virtue in the spread of personal wealth and the chances it brings to make informed life choices. The exclusion of a large section of the population from access to any kind of wealth conforms to neither tradition.

Table 1 : Range of potential reforms to policy towards wealth Annual taxes on wealth Council Tax: - Revaluation so valuations bear more relation to current relative values - More progressive banding so tax payable is more in proportion to relative values, with new bands introduced for most expensive property - Turn into housing services tax (to become the equivalent of VAT on housing consumption) Annual tax on the unimproved value of land Comprehensive annual wealth tax on total value of all assets Inheritance taxes Tighten up on avoidance Charge from above a lower threshold with progressive rate structure Replace with progressive lifetime accessions tax (so tax depends on receipts not size of estate) Taxes on returns on wealth End forgiveness of capital gains tax (CGT) on death Reintegrate CGT rates with income tax Reintroduce inflation indexation for CGT Apply equivalent of NICs (or surcharge) to investment income Integrate income tax and NIC and apply to investment income Take ordinary interest-bearing accounts out of tax Integrate income tax/cgt with Rate of Return Allowance system Tax imputed rents/capital gains of owneroccupiers (with or without roll-over relief) Means-tested benefits Automatic indexation of capital thresholds Higher capital thresholds Lower rates of tariff income Long-term care Raise capital threshold End cliff-edge liabilities (*) Cap lifetime liabilities (*) Finance from low level NICs above state pension age or inheritance tax on lower slice of estates Pensions Cap (and freeze) tax-free lump sum Abolish/phase out tax-free lump sum, turning into front-end matching Lower (and freeze) cap for annual contribution relief Abolish higher rate relief Turn flat rate relief into front-end matching Amalgamate means-tested benefit deductibility into matching system Asset accumulation Roll out national matched savings scheme for those on low incomes (Savings Gateway) Reintroduce Child Trust Funds, including for missing generation. Or automatic capital lump sum on reaching adulthood, financed by higher inheritance taxes Debt avoidance Extend financial inclusion agenda Reintroduce national (or mandatory local) equivalent of Social Fund More flexibility in Universal Credit payment periods Note: Recommendations from Mirrlees Review in italics. (*) Partly occurring in 2016 in response to Dilnot report.

Looking across current tax and social policies, it is hard to discern a consistent pattern for the treatment of wealth and savings. Despite the growing value of personal wealth relative to incomes, its taxation has become much less important as proportions both of overall tax revenue and of national income over the last fifty years. Inheritance taxes in particular fell from 1.5 per cent of GDP in 1948 to 0.2 per cent by 2010-11. Overall tax rates on the ownership and returns on personal wealth are on average lower than those on earnings. There is a wide range of treatments between different forms of saving where the state adds to people s saving (such as pension saving) and those where tax is levied on more than the real return on saving (such as conventional savings accounts). Most personal wealth is held in forms that minimise tax or are outside the tax system. However, both means-tested income support and assistance to pay for longterm care are withdrawn or sharply reduced for those with assets. The thresholds for eligibility are only infrequently adjusted for inflation or income growth, and over time have affected more people (although those applying to long-term care are now planned to be reformed in response to the Dilnot Commission report). The most important direct policy to encourage wealth ownership has been the Right to Buy for council tenants, with accumulated discounts on purchases now accounting for equity of 150-200 billion, 3-4 per cent of total wealth. Child Trust Funds and the Saving Gateway had positive effects on savings patterns, but both were discontinued after the 2010 election. Reforms to student finance mean that younger generations of graduates will have much higher levels of student debt, albeit of a kind where payment only needs to be made if income exceeds a threshold and is written off after 30 years The combination of these policies can mean very sharp differences in treatment between people, with some being strongly encouraged by the tax system to accumulate wealth in particular forms, while others face strong disincentives from means-testing to do so. These features often tend to reinforce wealth inequalities, rather than to narrow them. There is a very wide range of potential reforms to this structure (with a summary listing shown in Table 1 and discussed in more detail in the final chapter of the book). However, more or less forceful objections can be raised to most of them, and past experience such as with the proposed introduction of an annual wealth tax in the 1970s suggests that none would be politically easy. About the research The research reported here was supported by the Nuffield Foundation. The Nuffield Foundation is an endowed charitable trust that aims to improve social well-being in the widest sense. It funds research and innovation in education and social policy and also works to build capacity in education, science and social science research. The Nuffield Foundation has funded this project, but the views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Foundation. More information is available at www.nuffieldfoundation.org. Additional support was provided by the Economic and Social Research Council through its Professorial Fellowship to John Hills (RES-051-27-0234). We are very grateful to them and to the Office of National Statistics for analysis of the Wealth and Assets survey used here and in the book it summarises.