Wealth Distribution. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. Econ821. February 9, / 25

Similar documents
Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings FESAMES 2009

HOW IMPORTANT IS DISCOUNT RATE HETEROGENEITY FOR WEALTH INEQUALITY?

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Entrepreneurship, Frictions and Wealth

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Accounting for the Heterogeneity in Retirement Wealth

Bequests and Retirement Wealth in the United States

Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth (p. 2) Summer 2002

Luxury Consumption, Precautionary Savings and Wealth Inequality

Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Limited Participation and Wealth Distribution

Bequests and Heterogeneity in Retirement Wealth

Saving During Retirement

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Lecture Notes on Financial Market Incompleteness and Inequality c

Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper No On the Distribution of Income in Five Countries. Mariacristina De Nardi Liqian Ren Chao Wei

Taxation, Entrepreneurship and Wealth

The implications of richer earnings dynamics. for consumption, wealth, and welfare

2013 Update on the U.S. Earnings, Income, and Wealth Distributional Facts: A View from Macroeconomics

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper.

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Wealth - why do we care and what do we know?

Distribution of Wealth: Mechanisms

The Luxembourg Wealth Study (LWS) Database Introduction and Selected Demonstrations

Summary The distribution of wealth or net worth across households may have been an underlying consideration in congressional deliberations on various

Financial Market Incompleteness and Inequality c. Dean Corbae

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

1 Income Inequality in the US

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE IMPLICATIONS OF RICHER EARNINGS DYNAMICS FOR CONSUMPTION AND WEALTH

Accounting for the Heterogeneity in Retirement. Wealth

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

Economic Inequality and Possible Policy Responses

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

Accounting for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth Inequality

Age, Luck, and Inheritance

Poverty and Income Distribution

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings

Estate Taxation, Social Security and Annuity: the Trinity and Unity?

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Entrepreneurship, Business Wealth, and Social Mobility

NH Handbook of Income Distribution, volume 2B A.B. Atkinson and F.J. Bourguignon (Eds.) Chapter 15. Inequality in Macroeconomics

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Marginal Tax Rates and the Tax Reform Act of 1986: the long-run effect on the U.S. wealth distribution

Accounting for the determinants of wealth concentration in the US

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WEALTH DISTRIBUTION AND SOCIAL MOBILITY IN THE US: A QUANTITATIVE APPROACH. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo

Macroeconomic Models of Consumption, Saving, and Labor Supply

Macroeconomic Implications of Tax Cuts for the Top Income Groups:

Retirement Saving, Annuity Markets, and Lifecycle Modeling. James Poterba 10 July 2008

CIE Economics A-level

Higher Taxes at the Top: The Role of Entrepreneurs

Earnings Inequality and Taxes on the Rich

Cahier de recherche/working Paper Inequality and Debt in a Model with Heterogeneous Agents. Federico Ravenna Nicolas Vincent.

A Dynamic Model of Entrepreneurship with Borrowing Constraints: Theory and Evidence

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WEALTH INEQUALITY, FAMILY BACKGROUND, AND ESTATE TAXATION. Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang

Nonlinear household earnings dynamics, self-insurance, and welfare

WEEK 7 INCOME DISTRIBUTION & QUALITY OF LIFE

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours?

Five Years Older: Much Richer or Deeper in Debt? 1

Examining the Bequest Motive using Micro-data

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Bequests and Heterogeneity in Retirement Wealth

Income inequality an insufficient consumption in China. Li Gan Southwestern University of Finance and Economics Texas A&M University

Wealth Inequality, Family Background, and Estate Taxation

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Understanding the U.S. Distribution of Wealth

LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE 2017 CORPORATE TAX CUTS. Jorge Barro, Ph.D. Fellow in Public Finance

Income distribution and redistribution

Notes: Based on Hurd and Smith (1999, table 1). Estate sizes are expressed as multiples of mean earnings per civilian employee.

A dynamic model of entrepreneurship with borrowing constraints: theory and evidence

Personal Bankruptcy Law and Entrepreneurship A Quantitative Assessment

Retirement Security: What s Working and What s Not? James Poterba MIT, NBER, & TIAA-CREF. Bipartisan Policy Center 30 July 2014

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth* Marco Cagetti. Federal Reserve Board. Mariacristina De Nardi

Taha Choukhmane. November Department of Economics Yale University New Haven, CT Telephone: +1 (203)

Macroeconomics and Inequality (Macro III)

A Comprehensive Quantitative Theory of the U.S. Wealth Distribution

A Long-Run, Short-Run and Politico-Economic Analysis of the Welfare Costs of In ation

Wealth Returns Dynamics and Heterogeneity

Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of. Wealth Inequality

Wealth Accumulation Over the Life Cycle and Precautionary Savings

Wealth at the End of Life: Evidence on Estate Planning and Bequests

2016 Adequacy. Bureau of Legislative Research Policy Analysis & Research Section

Sources of Lifetime Inequality

Medicaid Insurance and Redistribution in Old Age

Do credit shocks matter for aggregate consumption?

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Higher Taxes at the Top: The Role of Entrepreneurs

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND

The Theory of Taxation and Public Economics

Topic 11: Measuring Inequality and Poverty

Reverse Mortgage Design

Transcription:

Wealth Distribution Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ821 February 9, 2016 1 / 25

Contents Introduction 3 Data Sources 4 Key features of the data 9 Quantitative Theory 12 Who Holds the Wealth? 20 Conclusion 23 Papers for Student Presentations 24 2 / 25

Introduction We study research on the wealth distribution (and later the earnings distribution) 1. The facts to be explained main fact: the top 1% hold 1/3 of all wealth 2. Basic models 3. Recent research 4. Possible projects 3 / 25

Data Sources What is Wealth? Financial: stocks, bonds, mutual funds net of debt Non-financial: homes, cars, furnishings Retirement wealth: present value of defined benefit pensions present value of social security claims 4 / 25

SCF: Survey of consumer finances. Detailed wealth data. Oversamples the rich. One cross-section every 3 years. Covers about 3,500 households. 5 / 25

PSID: Panel Study of Income Dynamics Panel starting in 1968. 50,000 individuals. Wealth data since 1984 at 5 year intervals. Fails to oversample the rich. Painful to work with (very poorly organized dataset) 6 / 25

rom es to gh. arnlth. the ed. ed ge the s in ely nt ith ge ple, e.) the sets. meonre- Popular measures of inequality Chart 5 The Lorenz Curves for the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth Lorenz curve: shows the fraction of y held by the poorest x% of households. What straight % of All line Households represents Have completely equal distribution. What the % more of All Earnings, "bowed" Income, the Lorenz Wealth curve, the higher inequality. % bu- g is alth tive zed les, ept nd Source: 1998 Survey of Consumer Finances Source: Rodríguez et al. (2002) income in their entire domains. The comparison between earnings and income is not so clean because the two Lorenz curves intersect. The Lorenz curve for earnings lies below the Lorenz curve for income in the bottom part of the distribution, and these roles are reversed after approxi- 7 / 25

Gini coefficient Definition: Area between 45-degree line and Lorenz curve Area below the 45-degree line. Gini is between 0 and 1 for variables that are positive. Equal distribution has Gini of 0. 8 / 25

Key features of the data Wealth is more concentrated than earnings and income. Wealth Gini: 0.8. Top 1% hold 35% of wealth Bottom 10% hold negative wealth Bottom 40% hold negligible wealth. 9 / 25

Chart 10 Averages Partitioning the Sample by Age Does age account for a large part of inequality? Gini coefficients within age classes are not much lower that Gini coefficients for all ages combined. Full sample Within age classes Earnings: 0.61 ca. 0.5 Income: 0.55 ca. 0.5 Wealth: 0.80 ca. 0.8 25 and 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 under 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Over 65 Gini Coefficients Within Age Classes Chart 11 Gini Indexes 25 and 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Over 65 under Source: Chart Rodríguez 12 Sources et al. (2002) Wealth is more unequally distributed that income in all age classes. Labor Capital Business Transfers 25 and 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Over 65 under by the sample averages. mer Finances 10 / 25

of Inequality Households Partitioned by Age... Age Profiles Chart 10 Averages 25 and 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Over 65 under Source: Chart Rodríguez 11 Gini Indexes et al. (2002) The figure shows mean wealth / income / earnings by age. Wealth peaks much later than earnings. 25 and 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Over 65 under Chart 12 Sources Labor Capital Business Transfers ing by the sample averages. sumer Finances 25 and 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Over 65 under 11 / 25

Quantitative Theory Can the standard life-cycle model account for wealth concentration? Starting point: Huggett (1996) This is the same as our model, except for uncertain lifespans. 12 / 25

Wealth Distribution in the Model Economy Fraction held by top 1% 5% 20% Gini Fraction neg. wealth Model 9.9 31.0 73.2 0.67 17% Huggett (1996) 10.8 32.4 68.9 0.70 19% U.S. data 34.7 57.8 81.7 0.80 11% The model has too many households without wealth. Still, wealth inequality is lower than in the data. Excercise: compute these stats from our model. 13 / 25

Wealth Distribution By Age Wealth / mean earnings 12 10 8 6 4 10.0-th percentile 25.0-th percentile 50.0-th percentile Mean 2 0 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Age in years Almost no model households enter into retirement without assets. Most young households have very little wealth. 14 / 25

486 Huggett (1996) M. Huggett / Journal of Monetary Economics 38 (1996) 469-494 Wealth 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 j -2 20 J J J I I I I I I J I ~ I 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 66 70 75 80 85 90 AGE Mean ~ 50% Quantlle ~ 26% Quantlle ~- 10% Quantlle The fraction of householdsuncertain without retirement Lifetimes assets is much larger with uncertain lifetimes. Fig. 2. Wealth profiles. discount factor due to their decreased survival probability. This means that agents eventually prefer a decreasing consumption profile and therefore run their assets down to low levels, x4 Second, this effect is strengthened further because agents receive a social security annuity that cannot be sold in the market. This means that agents reduce their nonsocial security wealth first. Finally, these agents no longer have a precautionary savings motive as they do not receive labor income and are not subject to health uncertainty or other shocks that could motivate precautionary asset holdings in old age. The age-wealth distribution in the model economy can be compared to the cross-sectional distribution in the US economy. The data for the US economy is presented in Fig. 3. The data is from Radner (1989) and is based on the 1984 Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP). Figs. 2 and 3 are similar in a number of respects. First, the fact that the median lies below the mean indicates that the wealth distribution within each age group is skewed to the right in both the model economy and the US economy. Second, a high fraction of young agents hold zero and negative wealth in both economies. Finally, a high fraction of agents in all age groups hold either very little or zero wealth in both economies. Diamond and Hausman (1984) describe the low wealth-holding of households in their prime earnings years. They calculate that 7 percent of their sample of 14Leung (1994) argues that in continuous time models agents will run down assets to zero before the terminal period. 15 / 25

U.S. Data M. Huggett / Journal of Monetary Economics 38 (1996) 469 494 487 120 Wealth ($ Thousands) oo t :........................................... -20 0~ _ I I I k I I 20 30 40 60 60 70 80 90 AGE Mean ---4-- 50% Quantlle ~ 30% Quantlle -~- 10% Quantlle US Economy Households decumulate wealth Fig. 3. more Wealth slowly. profiles. Almost 10% enter into retirement without wealth. 10% of households hold no wealth at all ages. men aged Young45 households 59 held negative hold much net wealth. more wealth Diamond than and in the Hausman data. (1980, p. 84) state: 'The presence of so little wealth accumulation is, itself, a reflection on the limitations of at least the strongest versions of the life-cycle theory'. It is therefore interesting to note that the life-cycle economies considered here introduce earnings variation as the sole source of heterogeneity within an age group. Nevertheless, the model economies generate a surprising amount of low wealth-holdings even among agents aged 45-59. In Fig. 2 the peak wealth level for the 10 percent quantile occurs at age 55 at a wealth level of 1.2. Since the output per person in the model economy is 1.63, this level corresponds to a maximum wealth level of about 70 percent of average annual income in the economy. Thus, it seems that even relatively simple modifications of the basic life-cycle model can come close to these low wealth-holding observations. One of the main reasons why agents aged 45-59 hold so little wealth in this model is that social security benefits are independent of earnings history. Thus, agents with low earnings are anticipating very generous benefits and therefore carry low asset levels into retirement. The opposite occurs for agents with very high earnings. They realize that social security benefits will be a small fraction of current earnings and therefore carry high asset levels into retirement. It would be interesting to see how sensitive the low asset holding results of this paper are to over estimating the redistribution that goes on within an age group through the social security system. This could be done by modeling more carefully the 16 / 25

Wealth Ginis by Age: Data igures Wealth inequality is declining with age in the data. Figure 1: Gini coe cients of wealth by age. PSID data. Source: Hendricks (2007) 17 / 25

Wealth Ginis by Age: Model 1 0.9 0.8 Wealth Gini 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Age in years Wealth inequality declines far too much in the model. 18 / 25

An Accounting Problem Given the estimated earnings process, it is not feasible for Huggett s households to accumulate the highest SCF wealth observations. The earnings process is estimated from the PSID. Wealth is estimated from the SCF. The SCF over-samples the rich; the PSID does not. The model cannot account for the highest wealth observations by construction. The highest PSID incomes are simply not large enough. Problem: There is no publicly available U.S. dataset from which an untruncated earnings process could be estimated. Tax data would solve the problem, but are not publicly available. One solution: Castaneda et al. (2003) Invent an earnings process that is consistent with the cross-sectional distribution of earnings from the SCF Project: How could one combine the cross-sectional information from SCF and tax data with the longitudinal information from the PSID to estimate the earnings process? 19 / 25

Who Holds the Wealth? Which other observations can be used to test the model? Do the right agents hold the right amounts of wealth? Two potential challenges for life-cycle theory: Wealth inequality among households with similar lifetime incomes. Intergenerational persistence of wealth. 20 / 25

Wealth Inequality and Lifetime Incomes Life-cycle intuition: Differences in wealth are due to: - differences in lifetime incomes - differences in age - differences in timing of earnings over the life-cycle Therefore: Models should imply little wealth inequality among households of similar lifetime incomes near retirement. Evidence 0.8 0.7 Model Data Wealth Gini age 65 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 Data: 0.1 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Lifetime earnings percentile Wealth Ginis within lifetime income deciles average 0.55 (Venti and Wise, 2000) Life-cycle model implies Gini coefficients around 0.35. 21 / 25

Wealth Distribution Within Lifetime Income Deciles Data: Each lifetime income decile contains households with high and low wealth. Life-cycle model: Most households hold similar amounts of wealth. There are no wealth poor households with high incomes. 1400 1200 Model Data 1000 Wealth 800 600 400 200 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Cumulative fraction of persons Life-cycle model versus Venti and Wise (2000) data (5th lifetime income decile) Why is this important? This observation directly tests the basic life-cycle intuition that differences in income and age drive differences in wealth. Suggests that a large source of wealth inequality has not been identified. 22 / 25

Conclusion Huggett s model goes a long way towards accounting for wealth inequality. Main discrepancies: Model misses the very top of the distribution. This may be due to the truncated earnings process. Wealth is decumulated too slowly at old age. The model only accounts for the cross-sectional distribution How does it do with respect to other moments? 23 / 25

Papers for Student Presentations Rate of return heterogeneity: CAMPANALE (2007) Preference heterogeneity: Cozzi (2014), Druedahl (2015) Hyperbolic discounting: Tobacman (2009) Entrepreneurship: Cagetti and De Nardi (2009), Hurst and Lusardi (2004) Alternative earnings processes: Nardi et al. (2016) Bequests: Boserup et al. (2016) Evolution of the wealth distribution over time: Kaymak and Poschke (2015) If you find other interesting papers, feel free to present those. A recent survey is Nardi (2015). 24 / 25

References Boserup, S. H., W. Kopczuk, and C. T. Kreiner (2016): The Role of Bequests in Shaping Wealth Inequality: Evidence from Danish Wealth Records, Working Paper 21896, National Bureau of Economic Research. Cagetti, M. and M. De Nardi (2009): Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth, The American Economic Review, 99, 85 111. CAMPANALE, C. (2007): Increasing returns to savings and wealth inequality, Review of Economic Dynamics, 10, 646 675. Castaneda, A., J. Diaz-Gimenez, and J. V. Rios-Rull (2003): Accounting for the US earnings and wealth inequality, Journal of political economy, 111, 818 857. Cozzi, M. (2014): Risk Aversion Heterogeneity and Wealth Inequality,. Druedahl, J. (2015): Wealth Inequality and Preference Heterogeneity,. Hendricks, L. (2007): How important is discount rate heterogeneity for wealth inequality? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31, 3042 3068. Huggett, M. (1996): Wealth distribution in life-cycle economies, Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 469 494. Hurst, E. and A. Lusardi (2004): Liquidity Constraints, Household Wealth, and Entrepreneurship, Journal of Political Economy, 112, 319 347. Kaymak, B. and M. Poschke (2015): The evolution of wealth inequality over half a century: The role of taxes, transfers and technology, Journal of Monetary Economics. Nardi, M. D. (2015): Quantitative Models of Wealth Inequality: A Survey, Working Paper 21106, National Bureau of Economic Research. Nardi, M. D., G. Fella, and G. P. Pardo (2016): The Implications of Richer Earnings Dynamics for Consumption, Wealth, and Welfare, Working Paper 21917, National Bureau of Economic Research. Rodríguez, S. B., J. Díaz-Giménez, V. Quadrini, and J.-V. Ríos-Rull (2002): Updated Facts on the US Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 26, 2 35. Tobacman, J. (2009): Endogenous Effective Discounting, Credit Constraints, and Wealth Inequality, The American Economic Review, 99, 369 373. Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise (2000): Choice, Chance, and Wealth Dispersion at Retirement, Working Paper 7521, National Bureau of Economic Research. 25 / 25