FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC

Similar documents
Employer Responsibility in Health Care Reform:

Sanders-Khanna Bill Risks Unintended Side Effects That Could Hurt Lower-Income Workers and Spur Discriminatory Hiring Practices

October 13, Premium Credits to Help Families Afford Coverage

A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES ESCAPE POVERTY by Jason Furman and Sharon Parrott

Energy Refund Program through State Human Service Agencies

The Baucus Individual Health Insurance Mandate: Taxing Low-Income and Moderate-Income Workers

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

House-Passed Health Bill Would End Coverage for More Than Half a Million New Jerseyans

HOUSE LEGISLATION WOULD CAUSE 350,000 PEOPLE TO FORGO HEALTH COVERAGE AND COULD JEOPARDIZE HEALTH REFORM By Judith Solomon and Robert Greenstein

HEALTH INSURANCE DEDUCTION OF LITTLE HELP TO THE UNINSURED. by Joel Friedman and Iris J. Lav

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS OFFSET FOR REPEALING AFFORDABLE CARE ACT S TAX REPORTING REQUIREMENT WOULD WEAKEN HEALTH REFORM

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

Marketplace Grace Periods Working as Intended

March 12, 2009 KEY FINDINGS

H.R Better Care Reconciliation Act of 2017

PAYING MORE FOR LESS Healthy Indiana Plan Would Cost More Than Medicaid While Providing Inferior Coverage By Judith Solomon

Health Insurance Data

HEALTH OPPORTUNITY ACCOUNTS FOR LOW-INCOME MEDICAID BENEFICIARIES: A Risky Approach By Edwin Park and Judith Solomon

And Jobs Act, November 14, 2017, %20chairman's%20modified%20mark.pdf.

HEALTH INSURANCE PROPOSALS IN ADMINISTRATION S BUDGET COULD WEAKEN THE EMPLOYER-BASED HEALTH INSURANCE SYSTEM. by Edwin Park

July 23, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

PROPOSAL FOR NEW HSA TAX DEDUCTION FOUND LIKELY TO INCREASE THE RANKS OF THE UNINSURED. by Edwin Park and Robert Greenstein

FUTURE MEDICAID GROWTH IS NOT DUE TO FLAWS IN THE PROGRAM S DESIGN, BUT TO DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS AND GENERAL INCREASES IN HEALTH CARE COSTS

LaDonna Pavetti, Ph. D.: How to Improve TANF

Medicare in Ryan s 2014 Budget By Paul N. Van de Water

Trump Budget Gets Two-Thirds of Its Cuts From Programs for Low- and Moderate-Income People

Ryan Plan Gets 69 Percent of Its Budget Cuts From Programs for People With Low or Moderate Incomes By Richard Kogan and Joel Friedman

Census Data Show Robust Progress Across the Board in 2016 in Income, Poverty, and Health Coverage

If Senate Republican Health Bill Weakens Essential Health Benefits Standards, It Would Harm People with Pre-Existing Conditions

Cassidy-Graham Would Deeply Cut and Drastically Redistribute Health Coverage Funding Among States

March 31, In fact, the Tax Foundation s calculation

Chart Book: TANF at 20

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina s Earned Income

July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Quantifying Tax Credits for People Now Buying Insurance on Their Own

THE DEMINT SOCIAL SECURITY PLAN by Jason Furman and Robert Greenstein

Chairman Currie, Vice-Chairman Hogan, and members of the committee:

May 4, Washington, DC Washington, DC House Energy and Commerce Committee. Washington, DC Washington, DC 20515

H.R American Health Care Act of 2017

The key differences between the Cooper-LaTourette plan and the Simpson-Bowles commission plan are:

Tax Foundation s Average Far More Than What Most Americans Pay in Federal Taxes FIGURE 1: April 2, 2012

Senate Tax Bill Has Same Basic Flaws as House Bill

medicaid a n d t h e Aging Out of Medicaid: What Is the Risk of Becoming Uninsured?

Understanding the Affordable Care Act s State Innovation ( 1332 ) Waivers

HOW MANY LOW-INCOME MEDICARE BENEFICIARIES IN EACH STATE WOULD BE DENIED THE MEDICARE PRESCRIPTION DRUG BENEFIT UNDER THE SENATE DRUG BILL?

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

REPUBLICAN PROPOSAL TO PAY FOR PAYROLL TAX EXTENSION WOULD INCREASE ALREADY SEVERE CUTS IN DISCRETIONARY PROGRAMS by James R.

Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes

The Ins and Outs of Delinking: Promoting Medicaid Enrollment of Children Who are Moving In and Out of the TANF System. March 1999.

Proposed Changes to Medicare in the Path to Prosperity Overview and Key Questions

GAO STUDY CONFIRMS HEALTH SAVINGS ACCOUNTS PRIMARILY BENEFIT HIGH-INCOME INDIVIDUALS By Edwin Park and Robert Greenstein Summary

THE WHITE HOUSE. Office of the Press Secretary. EMBARGOED FOR DELIVERY March 3, 2010

July 17, Summary

75-YEAR PAY-AS-YOU-GO PROPOSAL COULD ADVERSELY AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY, MEDICARE, SSI, VETERANS DISABILITY, AND OTHER PROGRAMS

More Cuts to Social Security Administration Funding Would Further Degrade Service By Kathleen Romig

October 31, Policy Priorities, October 28, 2011,

Address of Robert Greenstein To McCrery-Pomeroy SSDI Solutions Conference

TANF FUNDS MAY BE USED TO CREATE OR EXPAND REFUNDABLE STATE CHILD CARE TAX CREDITS

kaiser medicaid and the uninsured Short Term Options For Medicaid in a Recession commission on O L I C Y December 2008

REDUCING THE NUMBER OF UNINSURED The U.S. Census Bureau reports that, on a

Submitted to the Senate Finance Committee. The Graham-Cassidy-Heller-Johnson (GCHJ) Proposal

Summary of Healthy Indiana Plan: Key Facts and Issues

How The Chained Consumer Price Index Would Affect Social Security Benefits

PROPOSED SENATE TAX CUTS FOR SMALL BUSINESSES AND FARMERS NOT A TOP PRIORITY, GIVEN BUDGET OUTLOOK AND OTHER PRESSURES.

ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN. Chapter 6. Unemployment. October 23, Chapter 6: Unemployment. ECON204 (A01). Fall 2012

TANF at 20: Time to Create a Program that Supports Work and Helps Families Meet Their Basic Needs

The Center for Children and Families

Simplifying Insurance. ACA Update. Insurance Employee Benefits Risk Management Financial Strategies

820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Revised May 10, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

HUD Seeks Significant Improvements to Moving to Work Demonstration, But Additional Changes Needed

Cassidy-Graham Would Unravel Protections for People With Pre-Existing Conditions

THE DEMINT AND McCRERY SOCIAL SECURITY PLANS by Jason Furman and Robert Greenstein

THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM IS EFFECTIVE AND EFFICIENT Savings Cannot be Achieved by Targeting Waste, Fraud, and Abuse by Dorothy Rosenbaum

STATE INCOME TAX BURDENS ON LOW-INCOME FAMILIES IN By Bob Zahradnik and Joseph Llobrera 1

THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM Working Smarter for Working Families by Dorothy Rosenbaum and David Super

How Will Health Reform Help?

House GOP Budget Cuts Programs Aiding Low- and Moderate-Income People by $2.9 Trillion Over Decade

Verifying Incomes of All EITC Filers Would Delay Refunds, Raise Costs, Divert IRS Resources from More Effective Uses

National Survey of Small Businesses

MEMORANDUM IN OPPOSITION SB 2758 (Sen. Biss) in Executive Committee Today: March 20, 2014

House Bill to Expand Grandfathering of Individual-Market Plans Would Raise Premiums in Insurance Marketplaces and Undermine Market Reforms

Why TANF Is Not a Model for Other Safety Net Programs

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF THE FAMILY FAIRNESS AND OPPORTUNITY TAX REFORM ACT

Our Tax System Revealed. Lee R. Nackman, Ph.D. October 24, 2018

The Affordable Care Act s Employer Mandate: Guide to Advising Large Employers

Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes

Changes in TANF Work Requirements Could Make Them More Effective in Promoting Employment

Revised November 16, 2007

House Health Bill: Tax Cuts for Wealthy, Insurers, and Drug Companies Paid for by Low- and Middle-Income Families

Proposals for Insurance Options That Don t Comply with ACA Rules: Trade-offs In Cost and Regulation

kaiser medicaid commission on and the uninsured March 2013

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived

Ron Haskins is a Senior Fellow and the Cabot Family Chair in Economic Studies at the Brookings Institution, Washington, DC

Medicare Beneficiaries and Their Assets: Implications for Low-Income Programs

THE PRESIDENT S BUDGET: A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS

Affordable Care Act: Key Issues for Employers in 2014 and Beyond

Summary An issue in the development of the new health care reform plan is the effect on small business. One concern is the effect of a pay or play man

Transcription:

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org Revised October 21, 2009 FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC by Robert Greenstein and Judy Solomon The health reform bill that the Senate Finance Committee approved this week, while a major step forward as a whole, contains a requirement that could inhibit the hiring of individuals from lowincome families and would place cumbersome burdens on employers. The provision would require employers who do not offer health coverage to pay substantial amounts apparently up to $4,000 per worker or more for low- and moderate-income individuals employed at least 30 hours a week who receive subsidies to purchase coverage in a health insurance exchange. But firms would not pay anything for employees who do not receive subsidies because their family incomes are higher (or for other reasons). In essence, affected firms would pay a tax for hiring people from low- or moderateincome families. The provision also would require many employers who do offer coverage to pay these fees. Such firms would be charged for full-time workers who receive subsidies because the coverage that the employer offers is not considered affordable for them or its benefits do not meet the bill s minimum benefit standard, or because some of a firm s full-time workers do not qualify for the firm s plan such as employees in the initial months on the job. An employer responsibility requirement is an essential component of health care reform; it is necessary to ensure that firms do not drop coverage in substantial numbers and shift costs to taxpayers. But the particular employer provision in the Finance Committee bill would pose significant problems. By imposing a tax on employers for hiring people from low- and moderate-income families who would qualify for subsidies in the new health insurance exchanges, it would discourage firms from hiring such individuals and would favor the hiring for the same jobs of people who don t qualify for subsidies (primarily people from families at higher income levels). In particular, it could make it more difficult for low-income parents with children to be hired. Whether an individual qualifies for a subsidy in the exchange depends on whether the income of the worker s family falls below the income limit for a subsidy, and those income limits appropriately rise with family size. Hence, an individual with children and especially a single parent (whose income is not supplemented by the wages of a second parent) is much more

likely to receive a subsidy than a single individual with the same income. Low-income single mothers trying to work rather than rely on welfare would be among those who could face greater barriers to employment. This problem will be still greater if employers are billed larger amounts for workers receiving subsidies for family health coverage than for workers receiving subsidies for individual coverage, an important detail that will not be clear until the bill s legislative language is available. It would provide an incentive for employers to convert full-time workers (i.e., workers employed at least 30 hours per week) to part-time workers. It would place significant new administrative burdens and costs on employers. Two changes approved during the Finance Committee s deliberations make these problems worse. First, looking for a way to offset the costs of another change it wanted to make in another part of the bill, the Committee voted to deny employers the right to deduct the payments they would be required to make under this provision as business costs. Although employers can deduct the costs of health insurance premiums, they would be prohibited from deducting these payments. Second, the Congressional Budget Office s preliminary cost estimate of the Finance Committee bill says that employers would be charged the sum of the national average premium subsidy provided to those who get such subsidies and the national average subsidy for cost-sharing assistance. Previously, the average cost-sharing subsidy was not included in this calculation. The result of these two changes is to make the cost to many employers of hiring people from lowand moderate-income families still greater, and thus to make the incentive to avoid hiring them (or to let them go first when a firm downsizes) stronger. The Provision Employers with more than 50 employees that do not offer health coverage would have to pay the cost of subsidies provided to full-time employees who purchase coverage through the new health insurance exchanges and qualify for subsidies because their family income is below 400 percent of the poverty line, currently $88,000 for a family of four. 1 Many employers with more than 50 employees who do offer coverage also would be subject to the requirement. Workers who would have to pay more than 10 percent of their income for their share of the premium costs under their employer s plan could go into the exchange, as could workers whose employer offers a health plan that has an actuarial value of less than 65 percent and workers who fall into a category of employees that does not qualify for their employer s plan, such as workers who have not yet worked a sufficient number of months to be eligible for the plan (in firms that impose such waiting periods). Employers would then be billed for those workers who receive subsidies because their family incomes were below 400 percent of the poverty line. 1 The provision would not apply to employees who work less than 30 hours per week, have a disability, or participate in a welfare-to-work program, or to subsidies provided for children in foster care. 2

The Amounts That Employers Would Be Charged According to information provided to Senators on the Finance Committee by Committee staff at the outset of the mark-up, for workers receiving a subsidy for individual coverage in the exchange, an employer would be charged the average subsidy for individual coverage, while the employer would be charged the average subsidy for family coverage for workers receiving a subsidy for that type of coverage. The Kaiser Family Foundation reported last month that the average premium for family coverage in employer-based plans equals $13,375 in 2009. Using this figure, if the subsidy structure in the Finance Committee plan were in effect in 2009, the premium subsidy for family coverage for a worker at 150 percent of the poverty line could exceed $11,000, while the subsidy would be about $5,000 for a family at 350 percent of the poverty line. Subsidies for cost-sharing assistance, which would be available to households below 200 percent of the poverty line, would be in addition to these amounts. Another source of information is a document that the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) produced for the Senate Finance Committee on October 9, based on the bill as it stood at that time following the Committee s mark-up. The CBO estimates show that the average family premium in 2016 for the low-cost silver health insurance plan the plan to which the premium subsidies would be tied under the Finance Committee bill would be $14,700. The CBO estimates show that premium subsidies for family coverage for people between 133 percent and 300 percent of the poverty line would range from about $13,700 to $5,900 in 2016, depending on where in that income range an enrollee s income falls. Since firms apparently would have to pay the average subsidy for family coverage for workers receiving a subsidy for such coverage, employers would be charged well over $5,000 for each worker they hire who receives such a subsidy. Some subsequent information raises a question as to whether the statutory language for the Finance Committee bill, which is not yet available, will retain these separate charges for individual and family subsidies, or will simply use a single overall average figure for all subsidies when calculating the amounts employers are charged. If the latter approach is used, employers will be billed more than $4,000 for each worker receiving a subsidy in the exchange. 2 There would be an upper limit on the charges an employer would face. The amount an employer would pay would be capped at $400 times the total number of full-time workers that a firm employs, including workers who do not get subsidies. Many firms that do not offer coverage would likely hit the cap. For many of those firms that do offer coverage but have some employees who would receive subsidies in the exchange, the percentage of employees getting subsidies likely would be too low to hit the cap, so the firm would be charged thousands of dollars for each worker it employed who received a subsidy. 2 The $4,000 figure is based on CBO estimates of the average premium subsidy amount. The average cost-sharing subsidy amount would be added to this figure, according to CBO s preliminary cost estimate issued on October 9. 3

Effects on Employer Hiring The provision would make it more expensive for some employers to hire workers from low- and moderate-income families than to hire workers from higher-income backgrounds to do the same job. As a result, employers would have incentives to try to tilt hiring toward people who would be unlikely to receive subsidies and away from people who would need subsidies. For example, employers would have incentives to favor prospective employees who have a spouse with a decent income (or who have health coverage through a family member) as well as teenagers whose parents make a decent living. Employers who hire people with family incomes sufficiently low that they receive Medicaid (rather than subsidies for coverage purchased in the exchange) also would avoid a charge for such workers. However, most jobs, other than those paying low wages, generally would lift people above the Medicaid income limit. The incentives also would favor prospective employees who do not have children over those who do. Hiring parents would make it more likely that an employer would face substantial charges. A parent with children would be more likely to qualify for a subsidy and hence to cause the employer to be charged than a single individual or a person who is married but has no children because the income limit for subsidies would vary by family size. The income level up to which a worker would be eligible for a subsidy would be $43,320 (in 2009 dollars) for an individual, compared to $88,000 for a family of four. Second, as noted above, it appears that employers would face greater charges for workers who receive a subsidy for family coverage, although that is not certain. This could be a problem for single parents trying to work and keep their children out of poverty. The 1996 welfare law limited welfare assistance for these mothers and pushed them to get a job. This provision could lessen their chances of doing so. This differential treatment of workers based on their family income also might influence the decisions of some employers about which employees to let go when firms trim their workforces to cut costs, such as during a recession. Workers receiving subsidies through the exchange would cost a firm more to retain than other workers paid the same wage to do the same job. Similarly, the provision would create an incentive for some firms to convert full time to part time jobs and to reduce the work hours of some employees to less than 30 hours per week. Employers would not pay anything for employees who receive subsidies if the workers are employed fewer than 30 hours a week. Finally, because minorities are much more likely to have modest family incomes than nonminorities, a larger share of prospective minority workers likely would be affected. Burdens on Employers 4

Robert Reischauer s Observations on the Administrative Burdens of the Provision In a Center on Budget and Policy Priorities briefing for journalists on this provision on August 5, Robert Reischauer offered the following assessment: Inevitably, there s going to be some administrative complexity added to our health system when we consider ways of getting resources from employers to help finance the health subsidies but, of all the play or pay options, this one [the free rider proposal] is probably the most complex and has the most disincentives for what one would hope to be efficient behavior. If we re talking about systems in which the employer that doesn t provide health insurance has to pay a set fee of x dollars or y percent of payroll to the subsidy-granting entity or to the exchange, those are fairly simple kinds of payments to work out and aren t particularly intrusive. When we think of going down to the individual level, which is in effect what the [free rider] proposal would do, it gets administratively horrendously complex as well as quite intrusive. We re in a situation in which we re trying to have an exchange figure out how much is owed to it for subsidies from hundreds, possibly thousands, of different firms. It has to accurately identify the workers with the firms and differentiate workers who have subsidies from those who don t. As you know, firms come and go, particularly smaller firms and firms that tend to hire substantial numbers of low wage workers. We know that the worker population in the low-wage workforce is more unstable than those in the high-wage workforce and so they re tending to shift in and out of jobs, possibly because of the fluctuation of the demand of the employer, possibly because of other unstable circumstances in their lives. The exchange is going to have to be sending bills to employers. These bills are undoubtedly going to have substantial lags built into them, in the sense that none of this can happen on a real time basis and you might get a quarterly bill for the subsidy amount from six months ago or nine months ago. The firm is going to probably have problems with that bill, and not feel sure it s being charged correctly. There are likely to be disputes of one sort or another. In other words, it s going to be an immense hassle on the administrative front and one that we could reduce considerably by moving to one of the alternative forms of responsibility, such as those that depend on the entire wage bill of the firm or just the wage bill of those who don t have insurance coverage somewhere else. We re almost guaranteeing that a rather large new administrative burden would be placed on both the exchange and on employers The proposed requirement would place new burdens on employers. It would likely be complicated and costly for firms to administer. It also would impose fees on some firms in a way that could make it more difficult for them to fully pass on the costs though offsetting reductions in employee compensation. The Congressional Budget Office noted some of the administrative problems this proposal would cause in a recent report. 3 In a similar vein, Robert Reischauer, the President of the Urban Institute and a former CBO director, has said this proposal would result in a rather large new administrative burden and an immense hassle on the administrative front (see the box on this page). Administrative complexities and burdens would arise for the following reasons: 3 Congressional Budget Office, Effects of Changes to the Health Insurance System on Labor Markets, July 13, 2009. Emphasis added. 5

Under the provision, the health insurance exchanges would bill employers, presumably either monthly or quarterly, based on the number of a firm s employees who receive subsidies in the exchange. Employers consequently would need to maintain detailed, ongoing data exchange with the state health insurance exchanges. Worker turnover and changes in workers hours would complicate matters, because exchanges would inevitably bill firms for some people who no longer worked there or no longer worked at least 30 hours a week. This would require employers to dispute various billing charges from the exchanges. Moreover, while employers would not have to pay for employees who get a subsidy but have a disability or participate in a welfare-to-work program or for children in foster care the exchanges often would not know which subsidy recipients fall into these categories and would bill employers anyway. To escape these unwarranted charges, employers would have to challenge the charges and provide documentation. Another problem that the Congressional Budget Office identified in its analysis is that employers often would not know how much they owed until they received bills from the exchange, since employers may not know exactly which, or how many, of their employees were getting subsidies until the bills arrive. This would create some uncertainty and make financial planning more difficult for firms. 4 Finally, employers could, as a result of the provision, face the filing of discrimination complaints that would have to be litigated or otherwise resolved. Consider, for example, a circumstance in which a firm has two employees that perform the same job and are paid the same wage, but one gets a subsidy in the exchange (because there is no second earner in the family and its family income is modest) while the other employee is covered through a spouse. If the firm hits hard times and must lay off a workers and it lays off the one receiving the subsidy, there could be a potential for the firm to be hit with a discrimination complaint. Difficulty in Passing Costs Through In its recent analysis of the effects of this and other employer responsibility proposals, the Congressional Budget Office noted that under traditional play-or-pay requirements where employers pay a relatively modest amount per worker for all workers, employers would generally be able to cover those costs by paying lower wages than they otherwise would. CBO noted that under this proposal, where employers could pay much larger amounts per worker for a smaller number of workers (i.e., those receiving subsidies through the health insurance exchange), the employers might not be able to pass these much larger amounts through to the affected workers if those workers pay was not far enough above the minimum wage level to absorb the full reduction. 4 CBO noted that the proposal might also create greater uncertainty for firms because their liability would depend on whether workers chose a government subsidized plan, obtained other coverage, or became uninsured. 6