Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

Similar documents
Aggregate Consumption, Aggregate Demand, GDP and the Keynesian Cross 1 Instructional Primer 2

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

Intro to Economic analysis

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

ECON Micro Foundations

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. The Budget Set for Consumers. Indifference Curves are Like a Topographical Map for Utility.

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

ECO101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS Notes. Consumer Behaviour. U tility fro m c o n s u m in g B ig M a c s

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

Lecture 4: Consumer Choice

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

The Theory of Consumer Behavior ZURONI MD JUSOH DEPT OF RESOURCE MANAGEMENT & CONSUMER STUDIES FACULTY OF HUMAN ECOLOGY UPM

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Intermediate Microeconomics UTILITY BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

We are going to see the consumer s decision theory that you have seen in ECON 111 in another way.

Review of Previous Lectures

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Johanna has 10 to spend, the price of an apple is 1 and the price of a banana is 2. What are her options?

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Chapter 3. Consumer Behavior

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. Maximizing Utility. The Budget Set for Consumers. Slope =

= quantity of ith good bought and consumed. It

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

Summer 2016 ECN 303 Problem Set #1

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

Applications of Exponential Functions Group Activity 7 Business Project Week #10

Lecture 3: Consumer Choice

CHAPTER 4 APPENDIX DEMAND THEORY A MATHEMATICAL TREATMENT

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Consumer Choice and Demand

Problem Set 2 Solutions

Homework 3 Solutions

Garrison Schlauch - CLAS. This handout covers every type of utility function you will see in Econ 10A.

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Consumer Choice and Demand

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

Linear Modeling Business 5 Supply and Demand

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Economics 307: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory A Brief Mathematical Primer

I. More Fundamental Concepts and Definitions from Mathematics

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

Choice Under Uncertainty (Chapter 12)

Chapter 21: Theory of Consumer Choice

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices

A b. Marginal Utility (measured in money terms) is the maximum amount of money that a consumer is willing to pay for one more unit of a good (X).

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Modelling Economic Variables

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

x 1 = m 2p p 2 2p 1 x 2 = m + 2p 1 10p 2 2p 2

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Solutions to Assignment #2

File: ch03, Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

Practice Problem Solutions for Exam 1

EconS 301 Written Assignment #3 - ANSWER KEY

Summer 2016 Microeconomics 2 ECON1201. Nicole Liu Z

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

Economics 101 Section 5

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

BOSTON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT. Math Notes

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

3. Consumer Behavior

Economics 386-A1. Practice Assignment 3. S Landon Fall 2003

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

GE in production economies

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

Utility Maximization and Choice

JAMB (UTME), WAEC (SSCE, GCE), NECO,

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Transcription:

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2 As rational, self-interested and utility maximizing economic agents, consumers seek to have the greatest level of overall satisfaction, but find themselves constrained by the possible choice of goods and services available to them and the budget with which they have to purchase these items. If you think about this, the never-completelysatisfied consumer wants the greatest level of utility they can afford and as such they will seek to consume that combination of goods and services that gives them the highest level of satisfaction, but that still lies on their budget curve but just barely. This helps form the intuition behind the consumer s indifference curve being tangent to their budget curve. Think about the consumer s budget in a system in which the consumer can only choose between two goods, and. The consumer can spend the entire budget on or the entire budget on. In this relation we think of the prices of goods as being exogenously 3 set for the markets, and the consumer s budget as being exogenously imposed on the consumer. Agent A A * Slope = MRS = A * Budget A In this sense, the consumer must choose between the consumption (purchases) of good and/or with their budget and we recognize that as the consumer moves up or down the budget curve from any given point they are substituting units of for or for in an effort to reach a maximum level of utility or satisfaction. As such, the slope of the budget curve is referred to as the Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS), which is equal to. While on the budget curve the consumer s budget is constant, so if the budget is $2, then the allocation the consumer will choose of goods and are constrained by the budget amount while seeking the optimal allocation of and to yield maximum consumer utility or satisfaction. This relation falls out of a formation of consumer indifference curves and a budget curve. The indifference curve is that curve on which the consumer may obtain an allocation of goods (,) such that the consumer has the same level of utility at any point on the curve, as such the consumer is indifferent and doesn t care which allocation is met, but that the utility level is the same. Indifference curves have some basic rules: 1. They are downward sloping 2. Convex or quasi-convex 1 This primer is intended to present an abbreviated discussion of the included economic concepts and is not intended to be a full or complete representation of them or the underlying economic foundations from which they are built. 2 This primer was developed by Rick Haskell (rick.haskell@utah.edu), Ph.D. Student, Department of Economics, College of Social and Behavioral Sciences, The University of Utah, Salt Lake City, Utah (213). 3 Exogenous refers to something that has come from outside of a given system or an influence that does not stem from organic interactions within that system. Endogenous refers to those influences arising from within a system.

3. Do not transect one another 4. Are not tangent to one another 5. The consumer s level of utility is the same at any point on the curve 6. As the curve moves out and to the right the level of utility increases (and vice versa) As with any other constrained optimization problem, we re looking for the maximum level of utility based on a given budget. If we assume that there are only two goods in an economy ( and ), that the consumer is bound by a budget (M), and that the entire budget is to be expended through purchases/consumption of the goods, then the Utility Maximization Model and equation set looks something like this: The consumer s budget can be represented as, which reads as the price of good times the quantity of good, plus the price of good times the quantity of good equals the budget (M). We can also consider the consumer s utility function 4 which forms the indifference curve as, which reads as utility is a function of the consumer s consumption of good and good. Agent A Finding the optimal levels of goods and that allow for the highest level of consumer satisfaction then includes setting the budget equal to the utility, which is as easy and as difficult as it sounds. We ll look at two ways of doing this with using two different levels of math: 1) principles level algebra and 2) intermediate level calculus. We ll also use two different forms of utility equation to which will show very different tastes, preferences and optimal levels of and. A * A * Budget A U 1 Principles level algebra using marginal utilities In this example we ll use a few pieces of information that must be given and then apply them to a set of rules or conditions that we ve learned or developed. In this case the given information is simply arbitrarily selected, but in reality it would be the result of some analysis of a particular consumer and their budget. We re simply going to take it as given and remember that these are derived relationships or values and are not necessarily going to be the same for any two situations: This is simply the consumer s budget (1) These are the prices for two goods (2) A relationship between the two goods (3) informing a particular form of consumer utility 4 Utility functions are used by economists, but are very theoretical that is, hard to expressly and specifically define. Their formation is most likely left up to sociologists, for which we economists are grateful.

We already addressed the consumer budget equation above so let s think a little about the issues involved in the indifference curve. We ve identified the consumer s utility as and we can be assured that the consumer will choose the quantity of the goods they consumer based on a utility optimizing condition, or rule, that tells us that the marginal utility of a good divided by the price of that good is equal to the marginal utility of the other good divided by the price of the other good. In this case we can write this as: Which can be rewritten as Since this is a utility maximizing condition, it s a target we want to achieve and as such governs much of the rest of what we ll do: remember that it simply tells us something about the marginal utilities of and in respect to their prices. We have another equation (3) that also tells us something about and in respect to their prices so let s rewrite these. Since we know the prices of these inputs we ll first substitute (2) into (3) Which can be rewritten as or (7) We ll think of this as one equation with two unknowns and to solve for the unknowns we need to have another equation with the same two unknowns present. So let s use the budget equation given (1) to lead us to another equation that includes the two unknowns we re looking at (4) (5) (6) (8) If we replace P and P with the values given in (2) we can rewrite the equation as Now we have two equations (7) and (9) and two unknowns ( and ) from which we re going to find the optimal values of and this consumer will use to achieve maximum utility given a budget constraint. We can substitute (7) into (9) such that or (9)

From here we can rewrite the equation as or (1) Now we simply need to substitute (1) into (9) to get or with some simple algebra So our optimal quantities of * and * are 15 and 25 respectively. We need to think about how this should look in our graphic model using the budget and indifference curves. ou might recall that we obtain the intercepts of the respective axes by dividing the budget by the price of the input represented by the axis. 1 5 Budget B = $2 * = 25 U B Agent B 15 = * 2 5 Intermediate level calculus using the Lagrangian method If we assume a Cobb Douglas utility function with constant returns to scale 5 in the form of. Note that this represents a very different set of tastes and preferences than the utility identified in the principles level example and the optimal and will be different as well. Our goal is to maximize utility subject to some budget constraint, which can be written as: or (1) Recall the budget equation (2) This requires some simple calculus (partial derivatives) to find the solution to this problem, yields Marshallian demand equations for and, and as a result can then reveal optimal values of and as noted in the model. 5 Cobb Douglas utility function with constant returns to scale simply refers to a particular equation form for which the sum of the exponents equals one (1)

To solve for * and * we need to find the partial derivatives of the equation (3) (4) We can then set (3) and (4) each to zero, equate the two equations (since = ), and move the exogenous variables (P and P ) to the right side of the equations and then solve for and separately for (these reveal the Marshallian demand equations): (5) (6) (7) Solve for and separately for to find the Marshallian demand equations (8) (9) Substitute (8) into (2) to find * (1) (11) (12) Now substitute (12) into (2) to find * (13) (14) (15) So now that we have the form of * and * we d like to find their respective values, but to do this we need to identify values for P, P, α and M. We consider that these are exogenously set so we ll arbitrarily assume that P = 1, P = 2, α =.25 and M =2 and plug these into (12) and (15): = 5

With these values (including those we ve assumed) we can better articulate the Utility Maximization Model including the and intercepts of the budget curve. To do this we ll rewrite the budget equation with the appropriate values for P, P, and M, so we ll substitute these into (2): And then we can find the intercepts by setting and to zero () in separate equations. This is a different method of finding the intercepts than the one we used in the principles level example, but it s no more or less accurate and has about the same level of difficulty. (16) (17) (18) We need to think about how this should look in our graphic model using the budget and indifference curves. 75 U C Budget C = $2 Agent C 5