TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

Similar documents
Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

LINES AND SLOPES. Required concepts for the courses : Micro economic analysis, Managerial economy.

Chapter 10: Price Competition Learning Objectives Suggested Lecture Outline: Lecture 1: Lecture 2: Suggestions for the Instructor:

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Textbook Media Press. CH 27 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

0 $50 $0 $5 $-5 $50 $35 1 $50 $50 $40 $10 $50 $15 2 $50 $100 $55 $45 $50 $35 3 $50 $150 $90 $60 $50 $55 4 $50 $200 $145 $55 $65

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

New Keynesian Model. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame. Sims (ND) New Keynesian Model Fall / 20

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Chapter 9 Chapter 10

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Macroeconomic Analysis Econ 6022

Midterm Exam No. 2 - Answers. July 30, 2003

Linear Modeling Business 5 Supply and Demand

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Questions and Answers

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Mixed Strategies. Samuel Alizon and Daniel Cownden February 4, 2009

Macroeconomic Theory IV: New Keynesian Economics

Answers to Problem Set 4

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Symmetric Game. In animal behaviour a typical realization involves two parents balancing their individual investment in the common

Chapter 10 Aggregate Demand I

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Solution Problem Set 2

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 8010) Spring 2014 Foundations of Decision Analysis

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

11 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Chapter 11 1/19/2018. Basic Keynesian Model Expenditure and Tax Multipliers

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Math 135: Answers to Practice Problems

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

University of Toronto June 22, 2004 ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #1

OVERVIEW. 1. This chapter presents a graphical approach to the determination of income. Two different graphical approaches are provided.

Part2 Multiple Choice Practice Qs

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

EQ: What are the Assumptions of Keynesian Economic Theory?

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

There are 10 questions on this exam. These 10 questions are independent of each other.

Strategic Production Game 1

Market demand is therefore given by the following equation:

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

MICROECONOMICS II. Author: Gergely K hegyi. Supervised by Gergely K hegyi. February 2011

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 3

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Solution Guide to Exercises for Chapter 4 Decision making under uncertainty

FINAL EXAM. Name Student ID 1. C 2. B 3. D 4. B 5. B 6. A 7. A 8. D 9. C 10. B 11. C 12. B 13. A 14. B 15. C

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Chapter 11 Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS -LM Model

Kyunghun Kim ECN101(SS1, 2014): Homework4 Answer Key Due in class on 7/28

Short Run Competitive Equilibrium. Figure 1 -- Short run Equilibrium for a Competitive Firm

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 7: Producer Theory - costs and competition revisited

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Final Exam - Solutions

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

Strategy -1- Strategy

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Transcription:

Page 75 TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES Kevin Quinn, Bowling Green State University John Hoag,, Retired, Bowling Green State University ABSTRACT In this paper we describe a simple way of conveying to undergraduates the central message of Ball and Romer s paper Sticky Prices as Coordination Failure. For the simple framework we use, we also find an asymmetry between ments to decreases versus increases in the money supply, with the former, as in Ball and Romer, creating a coordination game, while the latter gives rise, in our formulation, to a game of chicken. INTRODUCTION In this paper we describe a simple way of conveying to undergraduates the central message of Ball and Romer s paper Sticky Prices as Coordination Failure. For the simple framework we use, we also find an asymmetry between ments to decreases versus increases in the money supply, with the former, as in Ball and Romer, creating a coordination game, while the latter gives rise, in our formulation, to a game of chicken. The model is simple. We have monopolistic competition with all of a large number of firms facing the same inverse demand curve of the form where Pi is the i th firm s price, P is the average price, M is the money supply, and Qi is the i th firm s quantity. Firm i s sales depend negatively on its relative price and positively on the real money supply. The latter dependence can be rationalized as a real balance effect, on the basis of money in the utility function, or indirectly through the effect of real money on interest rates and interest-sensitive spending. To make things simple, we assume that firms have no variable costs, so that they maximize profits by maximizing revenue. It is then easy for students to see that the optimal relative price is ½ the vertical intercept, which in this case is M/P; while the optimal quantity is ½ the horizontal intercept. Since we have given the inverse demand a slope of -, the horizontal intercept is also M/P. Since all firms are identical, the long run relative price must be, so the real money supply must be as depicted in the graph below. Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04

Page 76 Pi/P = M/P Q In the absence of menu costs, this equilibrium comes about as follows. Suppose we reduce M to /3 its former value, shifting the demand curve down and reducing the real money supply to (/3)* = 4/3 so each would want to reduce his price to /3 of what others are charging. But as prices fall, the real money supply increases, shifting the demand curve up again. When prices are /3 of their former value, the real money supply is again, so each will want to set a relative price of, and we have our new equilibrium. In the absence of menu costs, then, money is clearly neutral. Similarly, an increase in M would increase the optimal relative price above ; prices would rise in proportion to M. Now let s add menu costs and stick with the same reduction in M. Pi/ P Demand if all 3/ 4/3 Don t adjus t /3 Demand if none / /3 4/3 Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04 Qi

Page 77 If none, the typical /3 firm is on the lower demand curve. Should they or not i.e., is not ing the best response to all others not ing? By lowering relative price to /3, they would have profits of /3(/3)= 4/9. By maintaining price, charging a relative price of, they sell /3 and get profits of /3. Thus if menu costs exceed /9, they do better by not ing, and we have an equilibrium where no one s. But now suppose that all. Is this a Nash equilibrium? In this case, the typical firm is on the higher demand curve. Adjusting, which means charging a relative price of given that all others have cut price by /3, gives them profits of ()() =. If they do not change price, then they will have a relative price of Po/(/3)Po where Po was the price all were charging before the change. With a relative price of 3/, they sell ½, for profits of ¾. So they will want to if menu costs are less than ¼ and not otherwise. There is a range of menu costs, between /9 and /4, for which we have two symmetric Nash equlibria, one where all and another where none. The second equilibrium, where prices are sticky, is a coordination failure. This illustrates the main message of Ball and Romer s paper in a simple framework that undergraduates can grasp. The key to the result is that the benefits of ing, gross of menu costs, are greater when demand is higher. Demand is higher when all then when none do. Benefits of ing net of menu costs may thus be negative when none and positive when all. In our model, the case of an increase in the money supply is different. Suppose we have the money supply increase to 3/ times its initial value. The graph below illustrates. Pi/ P 3 Demand if none 3/ / 3 adjus t don t Demand if all / 4/3 3/ 3 Qi Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04

Page 78 If all, we are on the lower demand curve. The typical firm would have profits of if it s. If it does not, it will have a relative price of Po/(3/)Po = /3 and can sell 4/3 units for profits of 8/9. Thus it would not want to if menu costs exceeded /9. In other words, if all and menu costs exceed /9, it is not a best response to. All ing is not a Nash equilibrium, therefore. If none, each firm would face the higher demand curve. Adjusting optimally requires a relative price of 3/ for profits of 3/(3/) = 9/4. Failing to means setting a relative price of and selling units, for profits of. Thus if menu costs are less than ¼, each wants to when other do not ; there is no symmetric equilibrium in which none. Instead of a coordination game, in this case we have a game of chicken. In the appendix (We generally teach this without the appendix material, although the appendix requires nothing particularly advanced.), we show that the unique symmetric Nash equilibrium has each ing with probability equal to (/MC) /, where MC is the menu cost. Alternatively, the equilibrium has this proportion of firms ing, while the others do not. It is easy to see why the two cases, decreases versus increases in the money supply, are so different. In the case of an increase in M, demand is greater, and thus the costs of sub-optimal ment are greater, when none. For a decrease in M, the costs of sub-optimal ment are greater when all. It is interesting, too, that in this simple context, we get a micro foundation for the old Keynesian idea that the aggregate supply curve is steeper for increases in output than for decreases (The L-shaped AS function beloved of many old Keynesian texts.). Hence decreases in the money supply move us along a horizontal AS if we get the sticky price equilibrium, while increases in M move us along an upward sloping, though not vertical, AS curve, since prices but only partially. END NOTE. One of the desirable features of Ball and Romer is that they have started from utility maximization to obtain the demand curves for their consumers. One might wonder if demand functions such as what we have could be the outcome of utility maximization. It turns out that in an n good world, n- demands can have the form Q = (M b i P i )/P n and arise from utility maximization. While these demand functions are not exactly the ones we have above, they suggest that the results we get are consistent with standard assumptions. Details of this computation can be obtained from the authors upon request. REFERENCES Ball, Laurence and David Romer, Sticky Prices as Coordination Failure, American Economic Review, 8(3) 539-55. Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04

Page 79 APPENDIX Case : M decreases to /3 of its old value Suppose λ proportion of firms reduce money price by /3. First we show that this will give them the optimal relative price. We start from We now have M = M o /3. P = = Thus =. = So = = = optimal. Since the ers have P i = and P = P o, the ers have relative price: =, which is optimal as shown above. Now we want to find the payoff to ing and the payoff to not ing both as functions of λ, the proportion who. Here is the picture. 4/(3-λ) Pi/Po 3/(3-λ) D /(3-λ) A Demand for the typical firm when λ proportion /(3-λ) /(3-λ) 4/(3-λ) Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04

Page 80 As noted above, when λ proportion, the new real money supply = = =. The ers set relative prices at and sell units, earning - mc where mc is the menu cost. The non-ers will have relative price = = = =. They sell units and pay no menu costs, earning. We have two payoff functions, one for ers, π = - MC, and one for non-ers, π = Graphing both payoff functions gives us the following. - mc π er s profit non-er s profit - mc λ* λ The payoff functions intersect at λ* = under the assumption that < mc <. If mc < /9, then the er s profit function lies everywhere above the non-er s, so the only equilibrium has all ing. If mc exceeds ¼, on the other hand, then the situation is reversed the non-er s profit is then everywhere above the er s, so λ = 0 is the only equilibrium none will. With our assumptions, both λ = 0 and λ = are equilibria, since at λ = 0, not ing give greater profit than ing, while at λ =, ing give the greater profit. There is also a mixed strategy equilibrium here which has each firm ing with probability λ*. This is because when other firms will with probability λ*, the proportion ing (among a large number of firms) will be λ*, so that ing with probability λ* is a (weak) best response given the firm s indifference between ing and not at λ*. But λ* is clearly unstable. If λ > λ*, even slightly, the payoff to ing exceeds the Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04

Page 8 payoff to non-ing, so all will. If λ < λ*, even slightly, the payoff to not ing exceeds the payoff to ing so none will. The two stable equilibria are λ = 0 and λ =. Case : M increases to 3/ its former value Here we have M = (3/)M o. Again let λ proportion increase money price to 3/ its initial value. The new price level, P is P = λ (3/)P o + (-λ)p o =. So = = = =. The optimal relative price is, then,, as usual, or. Note that those who have increased money prices as supposed have relative prices of = and so have indeed ed optimally. A non-er will have a relative price equal to =. Here is the demand curve for the typical firm: Pi/P Qi Thus the payoff to ing is: =. Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04

Page 8 The payoff to not ing is: =. Again, assuming /9 < mc < ¼, the payoff functions can be drawn as shown below. - mc don t - mc λ * λ λ* solves: =. So λ* =. Here neither 0 nor are equilibria since at 0, the payoff to ing exceeds the payoff to not ing, while at, the reverse is true. We now have a stable equilibrium at λ*, since for λ > λ*, non- ment has a higher payoff, so λ falls; while for λ < λ*, ment has a higher payoff, so λ increases. It is easy to see that the discussion in the main text of the paper follows this appendix for the special cases of λ = 0 and λ =. Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, Volume 5, Number, 04