Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4

Similar documents
Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 4

Questions for Review. CHAPTER 8 Economic Growth II

7 Economic Growth I. Questions for Review CHAPTER

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved.

CHAPTER SEVEN - Eight. Economic Growth

ECON 3560/5040 Week 3

Check your understanding: Solow model 1

The Role of Physical Capital

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach

a) We can calculate Private and Public savings as well as investment as a share of GDP using (1):

Economic Growth: Extensions

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

EC 205 Macroeconomics I

SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

Chapter 7. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I. slide 0

ECON 302: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory (Spring ) Discussion Section Week 7 March 7, 2014

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Why growth matters

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Economics 202A Suggested Solutions to the Midterm

Road Map to this Lecture

Economic Growth II. macroeconomics. fifth edition. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich Worth Publishers, all rights reserved

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Intermediate Macroeconomics, 7.5 ECTS

Online Appendix for Revisiting Unemployment in Intermediate Macro: A New Approach for Teaching Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2012

Foundations of Economics for International Business Supplementary Exercises 2

(S-I) + (T-G) = (X-Z)

The Solow Growth Model

CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

Homework Assignment #3 ECO 3203, Fall Consider a closed economy with demand for goods as follows:

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 7, Questions

Problem Set 2: Answer Key

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

ECONOMIC GROWTH 1. THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL

Chapter 11 of Macroeconomics, Olivier Blanchard and David R. Johnson

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Introduction to economic growth (2)

The Solow Model. DeÞnition 2: A balanced growth path is a situation where each variable in the model is growing at a constant rate.

Chapter 8 Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

Econ 302 Assignment 2 Answer Key

ME II, Prof. Dr. T. Wollmershäuser. Chapter 12 Saving, Capital Accumulation, and Output

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

3. Which of the following assertions CLEARLY DOES NOT correspond to what you learned in this course?

Macroeconomics. Review of Growth Theory Solow and the Rest

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics

FINAL EXAM. Name Student ID 1. C 2. B 3. D 4. B 5. B 6. A 7. A 8. D 9. C 10. B 11. C 12. B 13. A 14. B 15. C

Chapter 8. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics and Policy 10/6/2010. Introduction. Technological progress in the Solow model

Growth 2. Chapter 6 (continued)

14.02 Quiz 3. Time Allowed: 90 minutes. Fall 2012

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS. Question 1: Inflation Expectations and Real Money Demand (20 points)

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Introduction

Shall we play a game? Solow growth model Steady state Break-even investment Rule of 70 Depreciation Dilution

Answer key to the Second Midterm Exam Principles of Macroeconomics

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Exam # 1 Suggested Solutions

Chapter 8: Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy*

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2014

TOPIC 4 Economi G c rowth

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

macro macroeconomics Economic Growth I Economic Growth I I (chapter 7) N. Gregory Mankiw

1 The Solow Growth Model

Economic Growth I Macroeconomics Finals

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems I (Solutions)

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (2 points each)

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Neoclassical Growth Theory

Growth Theory: Review

Savings and Economic Growth

ECON 385. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II. Solow Model With Technological Progress and Data. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

K and L by the factor z magnifies output produced by the factor z. Define

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

The Solow Growth Model

Problem set 7: Economic Growth: The Solow Model

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

Long run economic growth, part 2. The Solow growth model

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

A Note on the Solow Growth Model with a CES Production Function and Declining Population

Lecture 3: National Income: Where it comes from and where it goes

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

Transcription:

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4 Due May 4th (Friday), in-class 1. In this chapter we saw that the steady-state rate of unemployment is U/L = s/(s + f ). Suppose that the unemployment rate does not begin at this level. Show that unemployment will evolve over time and reach this steady state. (Hint: Express the change in the number of unemployed as a function of s, f, and U. Then show that if unemployment is above the natural rate, unemployment falls, and if unemployment is below the natural rate, unemployment rises.) Assuming the total labor force to be constant, then the change of the number of unemployed workers is U $%& = s L U $ fu $. Divide both sides with L, we have U $%& /L = s 1 U $ /L fu $ /L, which leads to Therefore. /01 2. /01 2 = s + f [ 5 5%6. / 2 ]. > 0 when. / < 5, and. /01 < 0 when. / > 5. That is to say 2 5%6 2 2 5%6 when the unemployment rate is above the natural rate, unemployment falls. Otherwise, unemployment rises. 2. Consider how unemployment would affect the Solow growth model. Suppose that output is produced according to the production function Y = K = [(1 u)l] &A=, where K is capital, L is the labor force, and u is the natural rate of unemployment. The national saving rate is s, the labor force grows at rate n, and capital depreciates at rate d. 1). Express output per worker (y = Y/L) as a function of capital per worker (k = K/L) and the natural rate of unemployment. Describe the steady state of this economy. 2). Suppose that some change in government policy reduces the natural rate of unemployment. Describe how this change affects output both immediately and over time. Is the steady-state effect on output larger or smaller than the immediate effect? Explain. 1) Divide both sides with L and we have Y L = K = (1 u) &A=, L which leads to y = f(k) = k = (1 u) &A=. At the steady state, investment equals depreciation plus the capital that has to be

supplied of for the new workers: sf k = (δ + n)k which leads to sk = (1 u) &A= = δ + n k. Hence the steady state capital stock per worker is k s = 1 u ( δ + n ) 1IJ. 1 The corresponding steady state output per worker is y = f k s = 1 u ( δ + n ) J 2) Figure 1 shows that when u is increased, we have a new steady state with lower capital stock per worker and output per worker. Now we are experiencing a reduction of u, we would expect to have a new steady state with higher capital stock per worker and output per worker. Figure 2 below shows the pattern of output over time. As soon as unemployment falls from u1 to u2, output jumps up from its initial steady-state value of y*(u1). The economy has the same amount of capital (since it takes time to adjust the capital stock), but this capital is combined with more workers. At that moment the economy is out of steady state: it has less capital than it wants to match the increased number of workers in the economy. The economy begins its transition by accumulating more capital, raising output even further than the original jump. Eventually the capital stock and output converge to their new, higher steady-state levels. 1IJ. Figure 1

Figure 2 3. The Solow model we have learned in class is for the closed economy. For an open economy, the national saving does not necessarily equal investment as international capital flow is possible. Let s assume that the country has an imperfect financial system so that only a λ fraction of the national saving can be transformed as investment, that is I = λ sy. Assume the production function takes a standard form as Y = K = L &A=. 1). Express output per worker (y = Y/L) as a function of capital per worker (k = K/L). Describe the steady state of this economy. 2). Suppose that some changes in government policy make the financial system more efficient and hence raise the saving to investment transformation rate λ. Describe how this change affects output both immediately and over time. Is the steady-state effect on output larger or smaller than the immediate effect? Explain. 1) The relationship between output per worker and capital per worker is unchanged by introducing this saving to investment transformation rate λ.: y = f k = k =. At the steady state we have that investment equals the depreciation (it is fine if you assume there is population growth as well): λsk = = δk Hence the steady state capital stock per worker is k = ( λs δ ) 1IJ. 1 The corresponding steady state output per worker is y = f k = ( λs δ ) 1IJ. J

As evident from this equation, the saving to investment transformation rate has a positive effect on the steady state capital stock and output. 2) Overtime, the economy will transit to a new steady state where the output per capita is higher. However, then immediate effect is zero as the capital stock and amount of labor cannot change immediately right after the change of λ. 4Two countries, Richland and Poorland, are described by the Solow growth model. They have the same Cobb Douglas production function,f K, L = AK = L &A=, but with different quantities of capital and labor. Richland saves 32 percent of its income, while Poorland saves 10 percent. Richland has population growth of 1 percent per year, while Poorland has population growth of 3 percent. (The numbers in this problem are chosen to be approximately realistic descriptions of rich and poor nations.) Both nations have technological progress at a rate of 2 percent per year and depreciation at a rate of 5 percent per year. a. What is the per-worker production function f(k)? b. Solve for the ratio of Richland s steady-state income per worker to Poorland s. (Hint: The parameter a will play a role in your answer.) c. If the Cobb Douglas parameter α takes the conventional value of about 1/3, how much higher should income per worker be in Richland compared to Poorland? d. Income per worker in Richland is actually 16 times income per worker in Poorland. Can you explain this fact by changing the value of the parameter a? What must it be? Can you think of any way of justifying such a value for this parameter? How else might you explain the large difference in income between Richland and Poorland? a) Let k = P Q(P,2), we have f k = = Ak =. 2 2 b) In the steady state we have sf k = (δ + n + g)k sak = = δ + n + g k, and hence k = ( S%T%U 5V ) 1 JI1. Correspondingly, f( k ) = A( S%T%U ) JI1. J 5V Since these two countries have identical A and α, at the steady state their ratio of income per worker is (5% + 1% + 2%)/32% [ (5% + 3% + 2%)/10% ] J JI1 = 0.25JI1. J Note that because 0 < α < 1, this ratio is actually larger than one, i.e. Richland has a

higher steady state income per worker compared to Poorland. c) If α = 1/3, the ratio above becomes 1/\ 1 0.25\ I1 = 2, i.e. in the steady state, Richland s income per worker is twice as high as Poorland s income per worker. d) Yes, we can explain this fact if we set the value of α as α = 2/3. Since α measures the labor intensity of the production function, you can justify this value by arguing that both countries are abundant in labor and hence focus on labor intensive productions. Apart from the difference in saving rate and population growth rate, we can also explain this large difference using the fact that poor countries typically have higher technology growth rate (late-move-advantage, 后发优势 ). 5. This question asks you to analyze in more detail the two-sector endogenous growth model presented in the text. a. Rewrite the production function for manufactured goods in terms of output per effective worker and capital per effective worker. b. In this economy, what is break-even investment (the amount of investment needed to keep capital per effective worker constant)? c. Write down the equation of motion for k, which shows Δk as saving minus break-even investment. Use this equation to draw a graph showing the determination of steady-state k. (Hint: This graph will look much like those we used to analyze the Solow model.) d. In this economy, what is the steady-state growth rate of output per worker Y/L? How do the saving rate s and the fraction of the labor force in universities u affect this steadystate growth rate? e. Using your graph, show the impact of an increase in u. (Hint: This change affects both curves.) Describe both the immediate and the steady-state effects. f. Based on your analysis, is an increase in u an unambiguously good thing for the economy? Explain. a). In the two-sector growth model, the production function takes this form: Y = F K, 1 u EL. Let y = ^ and k = P, we have _2 _2 y = f k = F k, 1 u. b). In order to keep capital per effective worker (K/EL) constant, break-even investment includes three terms: δk is needed to replace depreciating capital, nk is needed to provide capital for new workers, and g(u) is needed to provide capital for the greater stock of knowledge E created by research universities. That is, break-even investment is (δ + n + g(u))k.

c) The motion for k is k = sf k δ + n + g u k, and in the steady state we have k = sf k δ + n + g u k = 0. The corresponding graph should look like the one below: d). The steady state has constant capital per effective worker k. We also assume that in the steady state, there is a constant share of time spent in research universities, so u is constant. (After all, if u were not constant, it wouldn t be a steady state!). Hence, output per effective worker y is also constant. Output per worker equals ye, and E grows at rate g(u). Therefore, output per worker grows at rate g(u). The saving rate does not affect this growth rate. However, the amount of time spent in research universities does affect this rate: as more time is spent in research universities, the steady-state growth rate rises. e). An increase in u shifts both lines in our figure. Output per effective worker falls for any given level of capital per effective worker, since less of each worker s time is spent producing manufactured goods. This is the immediate effect of the change, since at the time u rises, the capital stock K and the efficiency of each worker E are constant. Since output per effective worker falls, the curve showing saving per effective worker shifts down. At the same time, the increase in time spent in research universities increases the growth rate of labor efficiency g(u). Hence, break-even investment [which we found above in part (b)] rises at any given level of k, so the line showing breakeven investment also shifts up. f). In the short run, the increase in u unambiguously decreases consumption. After all, we argued in part (e) that the immediate effect is to decrease output, since workers spend less time producing manufacturing goods and more time in research universities expanding the stock of knowledge. For a given saving rate, the decrease in output implies

a decrease in consumption. The long-run steady-state effect is more subtle. We found in part (e) that output per effective worker falls in the steady state. But welfare depends on output (and consumption) per worker, not per effective worker. The increase in time spent in research universities implies that E grows faster. That is, output per worker equals ye. Although steady-state y falls, in the long run the faster growth rate of E necessarily dominates. That is, in the long run, consumption unambiguously rises. Nevertheless, because of the initial decline in consumption, the increase in u is not unambiguously a good thing. That is, a policymaker who cares more about current generations than about future generations may decide not to pursue a policy of increasing u. (This is analogous to the question considered in Chapter 7 of whether a policymaker should try to reach the Golden Rule level of capital per effective worker if k is currently below the Golden Rule level.)