Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business. Fiscal policy. Nicolas Coeurdacier

Similar documents
Understanding the World Economy. Fiscal policy. Nicolas Coeurdacier Lecture 9

Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business. Fiscal policy. Nicolas Coeurdacier

THE TAX SYSTEM IN BELGIUM COMPARED TO OTHER OECD COUNTRIES

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

COVERAGE OF PRIVATE PENSION SYSTEMS AND MAIN TRENDS IN THE PENSIONS INDUSTRY IN THE OECD

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

Earnings related schemes: Design, options and experience. Edward Whitehouse

Income support for older persons in the Republic of Korea : a perspective of older persons

Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok October, 2009

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government?

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

TAX REFORM TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Can employment be increased only at the cost of more inequality?

Unemployment in the Great Recession

Capital Access Index 2006 Gauging Entrepreneurial Access to Capital

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

Fiscal Policy in Japan

axia Axia Economics Civil-service pension schemes Edward Whitehouse Civil-Service World Bank core course Washington DC, April 2016

Corrigendum. Page 41, Table 1.A1.1. Details of pension reforms, September 2013-September 2015 : Columns on Portugal should read as follows:

Public Pension Spending Trends and Outlook in Emerging Europe. Benedict Clements Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund March 2013

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

Session 11. Fiscal Policy

Chapter 12 Government and Fiscal Policy

Stronger growth, but risks loom large

Turkey s Saving Deficit Issue From an Institutional Perspective

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Some Basic Facts about Government Expenditures and Taxation in Canada. Econ 525

Slovak Competitiveness: Fundamentals, Indicators and Challenges

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Appendix. December 2011 Ministry of Finance

Financial wealth of private households worldwide

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

An International Perspective on Tax Reform in OECD countries

The Economics of Public Health Care Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

Budget repair and the size of Australia s government. Melbourne Economic Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute December 2015

Extract from Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising

Budget repair and the changing size of Australia s government. Crawford Australian Leadership Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute June 2016

SWM. The impact of reducing pension generosity on schooling and inequality ECON. Miguel Sánchez-Romero 1,2 and Alexia Prskawetz 1,2

London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine. Affording Our Future Conference Wellington, December, 2012

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

SEE macroeconomic outlook Recovery gains traction, fiscal discipline improving. Alen Kovac, Chief Economist EBC May 2016 Ljubljana

Entrepreneurship at a Glance 2018 Highlights

Statistical Annex ANNEX

Monetary policy regimes and exchange rate fluctuations

Macroeconomics Graphs. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

Ways to increase employment

Pensions at a Glance: Europe and Central Asia

The Global Financial Crisis and the Return of the Nordic Model?

GESUNDHEITLICHE VERSORGUNG

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Major Trends in Pension Reforms. Ambrogio Rinaldi Director, COVIP, Italy Chair, OECD Working Party on Private Pensions

Waiting for the Recovery: OECD Labour Markets in the Wake of the Crisis

Primary Health Care Needs-Based Resource Allocation through Financing of Health Regions

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

RESILIENCE IN A TIME OF HIGH DEBT

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

HOUSING MARKETS, BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES

REFORMING PENSION SYSTEMS: THE OECD EXPERIENCE

FEDERAL BUDGET RECOMMENDATIONS

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

Statistical Annex. Sources and definitions

Saving, Investment, and the Financial System. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich, Updated by Vance Ginn

LA SOSTENIBILITÀ E L ADEGUATEZZA DEI SISTEMI PENSIONISTICI NEI PAESI OCSE

PROGRESSIVITY IN TAX DESIGN. Michael Keen International Monetary Fund

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

Economic Performance. Lessons from the past and a guide for the future Björn Rúnar Guðmundson, Director

Alternative measures of well-being

FDI drops 18% in 2017 as corporate restructurings decline

Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle

Fiscal sustainability report Robert Chote Chairman

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July

GLOBAL TRENDS IN PENSION POLICIES AND REGULATIONS

Pensions Incentives to Retire

OECD Labour Markets in the Great Recession

InterTrade Ireland Economic Forum 25 November 2011 The jobs crisis: stylised facts and policy challenges

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Introduction to Public Finance

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

Transcription:

Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business Fiscal policy Lecture 9 Nicolas Coeurdacier nicolas.coeurdacier@sciencespo.fr

Lecture 9 : Fiscal policy 1. Public spending 2. Taxation 3. Debt and deficits 4. Fiscal policy as a stabilization tool

UK public spending (% of GDP), 1900-2009 % 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1900 1904 1908 1912 1916 1920 1924 1928 1932 1936 1940 1944 1948 1952 1956 1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 Source: UK National Income and Expenditure. ONS (Public Expenditure Statistical Analyses, 2009) Upward trend over time with major increases during war time

Government spending (% of GDP) France Germany Netherlands UK Japan US 1913 8.9 17.7 8.2 13.3 14.2 8.0 1938 23.2 42.4 21.7 28.8 30.3 19.8 1950 27.6 30.4 26.8 34.2 19.8 21.4 1974 39.3 44.6 47.9 44.8 24.5 32.1 2013 57.0 44.1 46.2 45.5 42.4 38.7 Common international pattern although level of spending varies across countries. Source: Maddison (1991) updated from OECD (2015) and DataStream international sources

Korea Estonia United States Russia Ireland Slovak Republic Israel Czech Republic Japan Luxembourg Norway Iceland Germany Spain United Kingdom Netherlands Hungary Portugal Italy Austria Sweden Belgium France Denmark Finland 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Total Government Spending (% of GDP) (sample of OECD countries) Source OECD

Motives for government spending 1. Collective provision of goods and services, e.g. Defence Law and order Education and health Roads Current expenditure on goods and services and public investment. Part of value added = GDP. 2. Redistribution of income between individuals Pensions Unemployment benefits Support for families Transfer payments. Do not contribute to GDP.

U.S. Federal Government Spending, by Category (2011) National Defense Health (including Medicare) Expenditure on goods and services Other expenditures Social Security Income Security Transfer payments Net interest payment In the U.S., transfers account for almost half of the federal budget. This number is even higher in Europe (almost 60 %).

Why do some governments spend more than others? Public spending is 30% in Korea, 35-40% in US, 45-60% in Europe. Certain level of spending required for national defence, law and order, basic education, etc Beyond that, the level of spending is a matter for political choice about the level of collective provision. Collective spending appears to be a luxury good - as incomes rise, we tend to spend an increasing proportion of it collectively. Tax revenue is a key constraint for developing countries.

The Fiscal Problem of the 21 st Century Annual average growth in real per capita expenditure on health and GDP, 1995 to 2005 Source: Health Data, OECD (2007)

Is big government bad for growth? Not necessarily. Stupid government is bad for growth. Big government can be stupid on a bigger scale. No simple correlation between government size and economic growth or investment rate - at least among OECD countries. It is what the government spends money on and how it delivers services that matter.

Government spending and growth - 8% is there a relationship? (OECD Countries, 1970-2007 ) ) 7% SVK GDP growth (annual, per capita 6% 5% 4% 3% 2% 1% KOR MEX JAP IRE ESP POR ICE GRE AUS USA SWI LUX UK IT CAN NWZ POL CZE NOR FIN AUT BLG FRA GER NET DEN HUN SWE 0% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 55% Source: OECD (2009) Government spending (% GDP)

Lecture 9 : Fiscal policy 1. Public spending 2. Taxation 3. Debt and deficits 4. Fiscal policy as a stabilization tool

60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Total Government Revenues (% of GDP) (OECD countries) Mexico Korea United States Switzerland Japan Australia Ireland Israel Spain Canada Estonia Poland Slovak Republic New Zealand United Kingdom Russia Czech Republic Iceland Luxembourg Netherlands Germany Portugal Slovenia Hungary Greece Italy Austria Belgium Sweden France Finland Norway Denmark Source OECD

Relative importance of different taxes (Average across OECD countries) Other taxes Specific consumption taxes General consumption taxes Personal income tax Corporate income tax Property and wealth taxes Payroll taxes Social security contributions: employer Social security contributions: employee Source: OECD Economic Outlook 2008

Principles of taxation Pigouvian taxes market prices are socially undesirable and need to be altered to improve outcomes (e.g pollution externality when buying gas so impose petrol taxes). Ramsey Taxes need to raise revenue to finance desired government expenditure and want to raise taxes in a way that distorts the economy the least. Which goods to tax? Tax items lightly where peoples decisions are very responsive to tax rates. Tax heavily when they do not respond (alcohol, petrol and cigarettes). Redistribution marginal utility of an extra dollar higher for the poor.

Taxation and revenue While low taxes lead to low distortions they don t produce much revenue. But do high taxes necessarily produce high revenue? High rates of tax on earned income discourage productive effort because: - People work less hard - They spend their time trying to avoid tax - Brightest people leave the country If supply effects strong then cutting taxes may increase revenue VOODOO economics!

A simple model of the labour supply Suppose the government taxes labour income at rate. Government revenues: = With the aggregate supply of labour and the average wage. Workers earn 1. Suppose that the supply of labour of workers is jncreasing in the wage net of taxes as follows ( and positive numbers): = [ 1 ] measures the elasticity of labour supply to the wage rate (net of taxes). Revenues are non monotonic w.r.t the tax rate : () = 1 ( )

Taxes and revenues: Laffer Curve Revenues R() Low elasticity High elasticity 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100% Tax rate

The Laffer curve Is there any truth behind the Laffer curve? - Yes, beyond a certain point higher tax rates bring in less revenue. - But this is likely to be very high - estimates suggest above 75% Politicians love voodoo economics Reagan tried it out in practise: - Tax cuts led to huge deficit - supply side effects small - However for very wealthy/high income earners a Laffer curve does operate (e.g. football players)

Lecture 9 : Fiscal policy 1. Public spending 2. Taxation 3. Debt and deficits 4. Fiscal policy as a stabilization tool

Government revenues and spending(% of GDP) (OECD countries, 2013) 60 NOR DEN Total Government Revenues (% of GDP) 50 40 FRA KOR U.S. 30 30 40 50 60 Total Government Spending (% of GDP) Most countries have higher spending than tax revenues.

Fiscal deficit Each period, the government earns revenues through taxation and has some public spending. Taxation and spending do not have to balance since government can borrow (or accumulate assets). The primary fiscal deficit is the difference between spending and tax revenues (government surplus the opposite) Primary deficit = = Government surplus The (total) fiscal deficit also includes interest payment from previously accumulated debt Total fiscal deficit = + Net interest payments Ex: A country with a 3% total deficit but debt of 100% GDP and an interest rate of 7% has interest payments of 7% of GDP. Therefore it will have a primary deficit of -4% e.g it will be running a primary surplus.

Total Government Surplus (% GDP) 8 4 Germany 0 France -4 US -8 Japan -12 UK -16 2011 2012 2013 2014 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Source: OECD Economic Outlook 2015

Fiscal deficit over time Why do fiscal deficit change from year to year? Automatic Stabilisers: As economy expands and contracts so does the tax revenue. Also more modest effect on expenditure unemployment benefits rise in downturn. Therefore deficit becomes larger in recession and falls in a boom Discretionary Policy: In response to an economic slowdown the government may deliberately choose to cut taxes and increase expenditure. Once again this makes the deficit countercyclical. Government spending shock : war, natural disaster

Debt and deficits Every period the government runs a deficit its debt increases. Consider a government entering periodwith debt Pays net interests on existing debt and runs a fiscal deficit. Thus next period debt: = + + = (1+ ) + Total fiscal deficit

How does government debt accumulate? = (1+ ) + Debt tomorrow at end of period is high if: Higher debt yesterday at date 1 Higher interest rate on debt Higher fiscal deficit Useful to compute debt over GDP. Divide previous expression by! --- assuming GDP grows at rate":! = (1+")! # $ %#& $ = (')# $() %#& $ + % $* $ %#& $ = ( ' + ) # $() %#& $() + % $* $ %#& $

Sustainable debt = ( 1+! 1+" ) +!! ( # $ %#& $ # $() %#& $() ) ( ") # $() %#& $() + % $* $ %#& $ Suppose debt over GDP is constant equal to # %#& : # %#& " = * $% $ %#& $ = Primary surplus over GDP In other words the government needs to run a primary surplus to cover the excess of interest payments over GDP growth. Intuition? The debt is said sustainable if," and the primary surplus such that the debt over GDP stays constant.

Sustainable debt To keep debt levels constant fiscal policy needs to generate primary surplus/gdp = #. " If > " government has to run a primary surplus in order to control the Debt/GDP ratio. If < " then government can run a deficit (of a certain size) without seeing Debt/GDP ratio increase. Shifts in interest rates and growth rates have big impact on government debt dynamics. If r increases with Debt/GDP and higher r leads to lower g then countries can rapidly find their public finances deteriorating.

Application --- Debt sustainability in Greece in 2010 r-g Primary Balance 2010 Debt GDP 2010-0.12-0.08-0.04 0-14.80-9.86-4.93 0.00 Greece -9.8 123.3 0.04 0.08 0.12 0.16 Source: OECD Economic Outlook, 2010 4.93 9.86 14.80 19.73 Table shows primary surpluses needed (for different values r-g) to stabilise Greece s debt level at 2010 value.

180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 Government debt, interest rate and growth in Greece Public debtover GDP in % GrowthRate and InterestRate (in %) 1995 1995 1996 1996 2012 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2013 2014 2013 2014 25 20 15 10 5 0-5 -10-15 GDP growth Long term interest rate (10 y)

160 140 120 100 80 60 40 Government debt, interest rate and growth in Portugal 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 15 10 5 0-5 Public debtover GDP in % GrowthRate and InterestRate (in %) 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 GDP growth Long term interest rate (10 y)

Lecture 9 : Fiscal policy 1. Public spending 2. Taxation 3. Debt and deficits 4. Fiscal policy as a stabilization tool

Fiscal policy as stabilization tool Previous lecture we saw how monetary policy can be used to stabilize output. Similarly, the government can rely on fiscal policy: in period of recession, increase government spending or reduce taxes to boost aggregate demand. Less used than monetary policy for practical reasons: (1)Recognition lag. Economic info. about yesterday, not today (2)Decision/implementation lag. Making up your mind (3)Impact lag. It takes time before a change in policy affects demand. (2) particularly important for fiscal policy. Might end up fuelling the next expansion. Fiscal policy still used in desperate times (last recession).

Fiscal policy and aggregate demand Prices Aggregate Demand Curve Short Run Supply Curve Fiscal expansion Output

Fiscal Response to the crisis Source OECD

Keynesian Fiscal Multiplier Keynes advocated used of fiscal policy to boost demand in the economy. Based around National Accounts Identity: Y = C + I + G + X M Lets ignore for now I and X-M and assume that C = a +b(y-t) in other words consumption depends on disposable income after tax. Therefore: Y = a/(1-b) bt/(1-b) + G/(1-b)

Keynesian Fiscal Multiplier Y = a/(1-b) bt/(1-b) + G/(1-b) Therefore raising G by $1bn would boost GDP by $[1/(1-b)]bn. If b=0.6 this is $2.5bn. Huge impact. Cutting taxes by $1bn would boost GDP by $[b/(1-b)]bn. If b=0.6 this is $1.5bn. Famous fiscal multiplier. If I spend $1 this appears as someones income. They then spend $b which appears as someones income and so they spend $(b 2 ) etc Total impact on economy is $(1+b+ b 2 +b 3 +...) = $1/(1-b)

Fiscal Multiplier Estimate

Fiscal Multiplier Estimate Range for US cumulative fiscal multipliers

Why might fiscal multiplier not work? Crowding out - Higher fiscal deficits crowds out consumption consumers save in expectation of future tax increases (Ricardian Equivalence). - Government Expenditure crowds out investment as increased borrowing leads to higher borrowing costs and less investment. Higher G Higher debt Higher Lower I(r) - Government expenditure crowds out net exports (external demand). Cf. next lectures.

Ricardian equivalence Modigliani-Miller for governments economy not affected by way government finances its activities Government can either finance its expenditure through current taxes or issuing debt but debt is just postponed taxes. When governments cut taxes consumers are not better off just face a delay in when they pay taxes. Therefore in response to government borrowing consumers save more possible for multiplier to be zero.

Ricardian equivalence Remember the 2-period model of lecture 7 (no financial frictions). U = log(c) +β log(7 8 ) with 0 < β < 1 Intertemporal budget constraint (consumer): 7 + 78 1+ = : + :8 8 1+ = ; Consumption path assuming β(1+r)=1 7 8 = 7 = ;/(1+β) Add government expenditure " (period 1) and " 8 (period 2). Intertemporal budget constraint (government): " + "8 1+ = + 8 1+ 7 8 = 7 = 1 1+β : + :8 8 1+ = 1 1+β : " + :8 " 8 1+

Ricardian equivalence 7 8 = 7 = 1 1+β : " + :8 " 8 1+ Permanent income consumer: path of taxes does not matter for consumption. Only their discounted sum matter = Ricardian equivalence A fall in public savings due to a tax cut is fully offset by a rise in private savings. Aggregate demand unchanged. Potential failure of Ricardian Equivalence? - Myopic consumers. - Future generations pay the burden of current deficits. - Financial frictions (borrowing constraints)

Ricardian Equivalence Is it True? Private and public saving: raw correlations 1 Data suggests around 50% crowding out on average Source: OECD 2002

Fiscal austerity Fiscal plans during the last financial crisis typical of a countercyclical fiscal policy. Fiscal tools used to stimulate aggegate demand in a slump. Still implies reducing deficits later as government cannot run very large deficits forever and needs to pay back the debt. = Fiscal austerity. Fiscal austerity when a country has recovered from the recession is not so painful. Lowers aggregate demand when it is high. Fiscal austerity very costly if country still in a slump. Output and demand are already low and governments are reducing further aggregate demand to reduce debt and deficits in order to stabilize public finance.

Fiscal austerity and sovereign debt crisis in Eurozone In Southern Europe, procyclical fiscal policy. Output and demand are low but governments searching to reduce debt and deficits to stabilize public finance. e.g. in Greece, primary deficit improved by 10% of GDP since 2009. This leads to even lower output and lower growth. Countries facing high interest rate and low growth see their debt quickly exploding (e.g. Greece).

Summary Government expenditure can be justified by market failure. Richer countries tend to spend more through their government and mainly on transfer payments. Taxes are used to correct for market failures or to raise revenue. Efficient taxes avoid taxing elastic commodities. Depending upon interest rates and growth governments can continually run a deficit without seeing debt to GDP increase. Fiscal tools can be used to stabilize output fluctuations. Fiscal deficits can have an expansionary effect on economy but controversies around the value of the fiscal multiplier.