Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

Similar documents
We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Topic 2 Part II: Extending the Theory of Consumer Behaviour

Solutions to Assignment #2

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester. ECON 101 Mid term Exam

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

ECNB , Spring 2003 Intermediate Microeconomics Saint Louis University. Midterm 2

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Fall 2018) Consumer Choice Theory

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Intro to Economic analysis

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Chapter 3. Consumer Behavior

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

max x + y s.t. y + px = m

ECO101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS Notes. Consumer Behaviour. U tility fro m c o n s u m in g B ig M a c s

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Rose-Hulman Institute of Technology / Department of Humanities & Social Sciences / K. Christ SL354, Intermediate Microeconomics / Sample Exam #1

D

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

ECON 310 Fall 2005 Final Exam - Version A. Multiple Choice: (circle the letter of the best response; 3 points each) and x

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

Consumer Surplus and Welfare Measurement (Chapter 14) cont. & Market Demand (Chapter 15)

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

1. What is the vertical intercept of the demand curve above? a. 20 b. 6 c. 120 d. 60 e. 1/6

Consumer Choice and Demand

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Sign Pledge I have neither given nor received aid on this exam

SOLUTIONS. ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test # 1 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto June 22, 2006

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2006 Prof Montgomery

Note 1: Indifference Curves, Budget Lines, and Demand Curves

Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

Microeconomics I 2011/12

CHAPTER 4 APPENDIX DEMAND THEORY A MATHEMATICAL TREATMENT

POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES

Chapter 4. Our Consumption Choices. What can we buy with this money? UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

Chapter 4. Consumer Choice. A Consumer s Budget Constraint. Consumer Choice

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

Competitive Firms in the Long-Run

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

ECON 103C -- Final Exam Peter Bell, 2014

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis July 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm - Solutions

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

<Table 1> Total Utility Marginal Utility Total Utility Marginal Utility

a. Graph the demand for calculators below. Label your axes and intercepts. (4 points)

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

The supply function is Q S (P)=. 10 points

Utility Maximization and Choice

Eliminating Substitution Bias. One eliminate substitution bias by continuously updating the market basket of goods purchased.

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS

ECON Micro Foundations

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 3

3. Consumer Behavior

Mathematical Economics

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Homework 1 Solutions

Take Home Exam #2 - Answer Key. ECON 500 Summer 2004.

Economics 602 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Problem Set 3 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2012

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH CONSUMER CHOICE AND BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS

DO NOT BEGIN WORKING UNTIL YOU ARE TOLD TO DO SO. READ THESE INSTRUCTIONS FIRST.

Appendix: Indifference Curves

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Spring Semester

2010 Pearson Education Canada

The Static Model. Consumer Assumptions on the preferences: Consumer. A description of the Model Economy

Full file at Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach (with and without Calculus) Chapter 2

1. What is the vertical intercept of the demand curve above? a. 120 b. 5 c. 24 d. 60 e. 1/5

ECONS 301 Homework #1. Answer Key

Midterm 1 - Solutions

~ In 20X7, a loaf of bread costs $1.50 and a flask of wine costs $6.00. A consumer with $120 buys 40 loaves of bread and 10 flasks of wine.

Assignment 1 Solutions. October 6, 2017

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

c U 2 U 1 Econ 310 Practice Questions: Chaps. 4, 7-8 Figure 4.1 Other goods

There are 7 questions on this exam. These 7 questions are independent of each other.

MIDTERM #2 VERSION 1

Chapter 5: Utility Maximization Problems

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

Transcription:

Budget Constraint: Review Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods. Model Assumption: Consumers spend all their income (no savings). Let: M=Income X and Y are two goods Px=price of each unit of good X Py = price of each unit of good Y Budget constraint: numerical expression of which market baskets the consumer can afford. The Budget Constraint: P x X + P y Y = M Total expenditure = Income Rearranging the above expression for the budget constraint, we are able to determine how many units of good Y we can consume for any given quantity of good X: Y M = P Y PX P X This equation of a straight line illustrates the trade-off between Y and X. Y

Y M P y Slope of budget constraint is P x Py. 0 P x Dividing income by the price of Y yields the maximum number of units of Y that can be purchased when no units of X are purchased. Dividing income by the price of X yields the maximum number of units of X that can be purchased, when no units of Y are purchased. M These are the intercepts of the budget line. X P X The slope of the equation PY is negative because in order to purchase more units of Y, the consumer must give up units of X.

Shifts in the Budget Constraint What happens to the budget constraint when: (1) income changes, (2) the price of X changes or (3) the price of Y changes? 1) Income changes Let M 0 = initial income M 1 =new income When income changes the Y intercept changes from M 0 P Y to 1 M P Y and the X intercept changes from I P X 0 1 to I P X. The slope of the budget line remains unchanged at P X. PY Hence, a change in income is shown as a parallel shift inward or outward of the budget constraint. # Units of Y 1 M P Y Budget line after an increase in income. 0 M P Y 0 BL 0 0 M P x BL 1 1 M P x #Units of X

(2) A change in the price of good X: A change in the price of good X does not change the amount of good Y the consumer could buy if he or she spent all their income on Y. (i.e. the intercept remains the same.) The budget line does change: For price increases, the budget line becomes steeper For price decreases, the budget line becomes flatter. # Units of Y 1 M P Y Budget line after a decrease in the price of X. 0 BL 0 M P x 0 M P x 1 BL 1 #Units of X Let P X0 = the initial price of good X. Let P X1 = the new (lower) price of X. When the price of X decreases, the consumer can now purchase more of good X. The budget constraint swings outward and becomes flatter.

(3) A Change in the Price of Good Y: A change in the price of good Y does not change the amount of X the consumer could buy if he or she spent all their income on X. (I.e. the X intercept remains the same.) However, the budget line does change: For price increases the budget constraint becomes flatter. For price decreases the budget constraint becomes steeper. (I.e. the Y intercept increases.) # Units of Y M P y 1 Budget line after a decrease in the price of Y. M P y 0 0 BL 0 BL 1 M P x 0 #Units of X Let P Y 0 = the initial price of good Y. Let P Y 1 =the new (lower) price of Y. Note: If all prices and income change by the same proportion, the budget constraint is unaffected.

Consumer Choice Constraints: Prices Income (Endowments) Budget Constraint Time Constraint Preferences: Represented by: Indifferences Curves Utility Functions Optimal Choice: Maximize Utility s.t. constraints Demand for Goods Labor Supply Savings 1

Budget Constraint: Imagine: You have $24 (Y=24) to spend on beer (x 1 ) and pizza (x 2 ). Beer costs $2 per cup (p 1 = 2) and pizza costs $3 per slice (p 2 = 3). The budget constraint is: 2x 1 + 3 x 2 = 24 => x 2 = 8-2 3 x 1 or, in general : p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = Y => Y x 2 = - p1 p 2 p 2 x 1 Assume : Can consume fractions of beer, pizza Can t consume negative beer or pizza (Note: can have, in principle, any # of goods p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 + p 4 x 4 +... + p N x N = Y Also, we can aggregate several good together to compare x 1 with all other goods x 2 ) 2

x 2 : Slices Of Pizza Y p = 8 1 Slope = p2 2 p 2 = 3 Y p 1 =12 x 1 : Cups of Beer 2x 1 + 3 x 2 = 24 => x 2 = 8-2 3 x 1 p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = Y => x 2 = Y p 2 p - 1 p2 Slope of the budget line is the opportunity cost : number of slices of pizza need to give up to consume one more cup of beer. x 1 3

Budget Constraint (Budget Set, Affordable Set, Feasible Set): Triangle and Interior Budget Line : Just the line: 2x 1 + 3 x 2 = 24 On Budget Line: spend all money Inside the Budget Line: have money left over. E.g.: Consider these bundles (baskets): (x 1, x 2 ) = (0, 8) (12, 0) (3, 6) (5, 4.67) are all on the budget line. (x 1, x 2 ) = (0, 7) (0, 0) (3, 5) (5, 4.2) are all affordable (feasible), but not on the budget line. (x 1, x 2 ) = (0, 9) (12, 12) (3, 6.5) are not affordable (not feasible). 4

x 2 : Slices Of Pizza 10 Shifts in the Budget Constraint (income): 8 Slope = - 2 3 Suppose Y increases to $30: 2x 1 + 3 x 2 = 30 => x 2 = 10-2 3 x 1 Change in income: parallel shift in budget line Increase (decrease in income): shift out (in) 12 15 x 1 : Cups of Beer 5

Shifts in the Budget Constraint (price) x 2 : Slices Of Pizza 8 Slope = - 4 3 12 6 x 1 : Cups of Beer Suppose p 1 increases to $4: 4x 1 + 3 x 2 = 24 => x 2 = 8-4 x 1 3 Change in a price: change in slope of the line. Price increases: budget set smaller. Q: What if all prices, and income triple? 6

Kinked, or Non-linear Budget Constraint: Rationing (eg: gas rationing) In-Kind Transfer (eg: WIC) Multiple Constraints (e.g., Time and Budget) Price depends on amount consumed: o Quantity Discount (Bon Marche) o Quantity Surcharge (Electricity) o Tax depends on amount Consumed Rationing: X 2 p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = Y x 1 = X 1 X1 X 1 7

In-Kind Transfer: E.g.: Kid has $30 to spend this week on healthy lunches and soda (pop). Healthy lunches cost $6 each, and soda costs $3 per gallon. Soda (x 2 ) 20 10 Original Budget Constraint : 6x 1 + 3x 2 = 30 With Cash Value : 6x 1 + 3x 2 = 60 5 10 Lunches (x 1 ) Two options: Give $30 more in cash Give 5 healthy lunches What if he can sell lunches for $6 each? $3? What are other examples of in-kind transfers? Why do we use them instead of cash? 8

Quantity Discount: E.g. Fertilizer is $5 per pound. o If Buy more than 20 pounds, price is $4 Question: Does the discount apply: (1) to just the fertilizer over the 20 pounds (2) to all the fertilizer Suppose you have $200 to spend on fertilizer, and all other goods. Let the price of all other goods (p 2 ) be $1. 9

x 2 200 Case 1: Discount only on incremental units Slope = -5 100 Slope = -4 20 40 45 x 1 What is the budget line if no kink? 5x 1 + x 2 = 200 Where is the kink (i.e., at what point does the slope change?) x 1 = 20 => x 2 = 100 What is the price beyond the kink? p 1 = 4 What is the maximum number of pounds? x 1 (max) = 45 10

Case 2: Discount on all units Slope = -5 Slope = -4 20 40 50 x 1 What is the budget line if no kink? 5x 1 + x 2 = 200 Where is the kink (i.e., at what point does the slope change?) x 1 = 20 => x 2 = 100 What is the price beyond the kink? p 1 = 4 What is the maximum number of pounds? x 1 (max) = 200/4 = 50 11

Quantity Surcharge: E.g. Suppose that electricity costs $.01 per kwh if use up to 5,000, but $.02 per kwh for all kwh over 5,000. X 2 Slope =.01 p 2 Slope =.02 p 2 5,000 X 1 12

Time and Budget Constraints E.g.: Joel has $40 to spend this weekend on movies (x 1 ) and meals (x 2 ). Movies cost $8 each and meals cost $10 each. So, his budget constraint is: 8x 1 + 10x 2 = 40 Also, he has only 9 free hours. Movies take 3 hours each, and meals take 1 hour. So, his time constraint is: 3x 1 + 1x 2 = 9 X 2 9 Time Constraint: Slope = -3 4 Budget Constraint: Slope = -4/5 3 5 X 1 13

Topic 4 page42 Taxes, Trade Limitations and Market Restriction On Total Surplus Total Surplus = consumer surplus + producer surplus A Per Unit Tax on A Competitive Firm When a per unit tax is imposed on the firm, the firm s profit function becomes: Total profit = total revenue - total long-run cost - total taxes π( q) = Pq C ( q) tq where tq are total taxes paid by the firm to the government. (t=tax; q= quantity produced) In order for the firm to maximize profits, it must produce an output such that it must satisfy: P L ΔC ( q) L = + t Δq The firm considers the per unit tax a cost of doing business. It determines output where price equals the sum of long run MC and t.

MC L +tax Topic 4 page43 Price MC L AC L +tax P m +tax tax AC L P m 0 q Quantity For the firm, when it considers the tax as another cost, the long run average cost of the firm becomes AC L + tax. The curve is exactly the same as the pre tax LAC curve, only shifted up by the amount of the per unit tax. The MC function also shifts up by the amount of the tax and becomes MC L + tax. Since the average and marginal cost functions shift upward by the amount of the tax, the new and old long-run average cost functions reach a minimum at the same quantity produced. Both long run average cost curves reach a minimum at q.

Topic 4 page44 Price P 0 +tax P 0 B A tax S L +tax S L Demand 0 Q 1 Q 0 Quantity The green box represents the total amount of tax revenue collected by the government. For the industry, the long-run equilibrium price increases from P 0 to P 0 +tax. The equilibrium quantity produced decreases from Q 0 to Q 1. By raising the per unit tax, the government increases the price of the product and decreases the quantity demanded. Before tax, industry output at point A at price P 0.

Topic 4 page45 The amount by which the price increases depends on the price elasticity of demand and of supply. The greater the price elasticity of demand function, the smaller the price increase caused by a per unit tax. The greater the price elasticity of supply function, the greater the price rise caused by a per unit tax. Price P 0 +tax P 0 B A tax S L +tax S L Demand Demand 0 Q 1 Q 0 Quantity

Topic 4 page46 The Effect of A Per Unit Tax on Consumer and Producer Surplus It has been shown that the behaviour of consumers and producers change when a tax is imposed. Taxes have social consequences. Price CS Supply P 0 PS Demand 0 Q 0 Quantity Before the government imposes a per unit tax, the long-run equilibrium price and quantity in a competitive industry are P 0 and Q 0. Consumers benefit because they are willing to pay more than P 0 for each unit up to the Q 0 th. The area between the demand curve and the price measures consumer surplus. Producers receive P 0 for all the units they sell, even though they are willing to supply all units up to the Q 0 th unit at lower prices. The area between the price line P 0 and the industry supply function represents producer surplus when producers sell Q 0 units are price P 0.

Topic 4 page47 Now impose the Per Unit Tax: The sum of consumer and producer surpluses decreases when the government imposes a per unit tax on a competitive industry. Price Supply + tax CS A Supply P 0 B D P 1 P 2 P 3 C Demand 0 Q 1 Q 0 Quantity The market price increases to P 1 and equilibrium quantity decreases to Q 1 when the tax is imposed. Consumer surplus decreases by area P 0 P 1 AD. Consumer surplus is now P 1 P 4 A. Producer surplus in now area P 3 P 2 C. Although producers receive P 1 for Q 1 units, they must pay the government the tax of area P 2 P 1 AC. Producer surplus has decreased by area P 2 P 0 DC. Dead weight loss= ADC (loss of consumer and producer surplus that is not offset by an increase in value to some other group.

Utility Maximization Under Constraint 2 Methods Question: Tom spends all his $100 weekly income on two goods, X and Y. His utility function is given by U(X, Y) = XY. If P x = $4/ unit and P y =$10/ unit, how much of each good should he buy to maximize utility? The budget constraint equals: PX+ PY= M x 4X + 10Y = 100 y

Method 1: Lagrangean Multipliers: First, transform the constrained maximization problem into the following unconstrained maximization problem: Max L = U( X, Y) λ( P X + P Y M) XY,, λ x y The lagrangean multiplier s ( λ ) role is to assure that the budget constraint is satisfied.

The first order conditions for a maximum of L are obtained by taking the first partial derivatives of L with respect to X, Y and λ, and equating them to zero: Max L = XY λ( 4X + 10Y 100) XY,, λ L = Y 4λ = 0 X L = X 10λ = 0 Y L = 1( 4 X + 10Y 100 = 0 λ

Now: Using the ratio of the first two FOCs: Y X 4λ Y 4λ = 0 = = 10λ X 10λ 04. Y = 04. X Expression for Y Inserting the expression for Y into the budget constraint: 4X + 10Y = 100 4X + 10 04. X = 100 (8X = 100 X = 12 5 ).

Substituting X=12.5 into the expression for Y: Y Y = 04. X = 04.( 125.) = 5 The bundle X=12.5 and Y=5 will maximize utility while constrained at M=100.

Method 2: Solve the budget constraint for Y in terms of X and substitute the result wherever Y appears in the utility function. Utility then becomes a function X alone and we can maximize it by taking its first derivative with respect to X and equating that to zero. The value of X that solves that equation is the optimal value of X, which can them be substituted back into the budget constraint to find the optimal value of Y. PX+ PY= M x 4X + 10Y = 100 rearrange: Y = 10 0. 4 X y budget constraint

The utility function: U( X, Y) = XY U( X, Y) = X( 10 0. 4 X) = 10X 0. 4 X 2 Max Utility wrt X: U = 10 0. 8X = 0 X 10 = 0. 8X X = 12.5 Y=10-0.4X=10-0.4(12.5)=5 Same answer: (X=12.5, Y=5)

Graphically: Y 10 5 Budget line U=62.5 0 12.5 25 X Which leads us to indifference curves: