Chapter 11 of Macroeconomics, Olivier Blanchard and David R. Johnson

Similar documents
ME II, Prof. Dr. T. Wollmershäuser. Chapter 12 Saving, Capital Accumulation, and Output

Blanchard, Amighini and Giavazzi, Macroeconomics: A European Perspective, 2 nd edition, Instructor s Manual on the Web

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 7, Questions

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

Incentives and economic growth

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS. Question 1: Inflation Expectations and Real Money Demand (20 points)

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

(S-I) + (T-G) = (X-Z)

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved.

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 4

Growth Theory: Review

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Final Exam Solutions

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

Intermediate Macroeconomics

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Advanced Macroeconomics 9. The Solow Model

CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

The Solow Model. DeÞnition 2: A balanced growth path is a situation where each variable in the model is growing at a constant rate.

ECON 302: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory (Spring ) Discussion Section Week 7 March 7, 2014

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

Come and join us at WebLyceum

Business Fluctuations. Notes 05. Preface. IS Relation. LM Relation. The IS and the LM Together. Does the IS-LM Model Fit the Facts?

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 2, Answers

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Topic 6. Introducing money

Problem set 7: Economic Growth: The Solow Model

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Homework Assignment #2: Answer Sheet

a) We can calculate Private and Public savings as well as investment as a share of GDP using (1):

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

QUESTIONNAIRE B I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (4 points each)

Homework Assignment #3 ECO 3203, Fall Consider a closed economy with demand for goods as follows:

1 Figure 1 (A) shows what the IS LM model looks like for the case in which the Fed holds the

ECON 3560/5040 Week 3

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

ECONOMIC GROWTH 1. THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL

Final Exam. Name: Student ID: Section:

Class 3. Explaining Economic Growth. The Solow-Swan Model

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach

Modelling Economic Variables

Introduction to Economic Fluctuations

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

3. Which of the following assertions CLEARLY DOES NOT correspond to what you learned in this course?

International Trade in Goods and Assets. 1. The economic activity of a small, open economy can affect the world prices.

Online Appendix for Revisiting Unemployment in Intermediate Macro: A New Approach for Teaching Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Why growth matters

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Savings and Economic Growth

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 3: AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM INCOME

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (4 points each)

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

Road Map to this Lecture

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT. Chapter 20

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 1, Answers

Growth Growth Accounting The Solow Model Golden Rule. Growth. Joydeep Bhattacharya. Iowa State. February 16, Growth

Answer key to the Second Midterm Exam Principles of Macroeconomics

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (2 points each)

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 2 Solutions Spring 2003

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Fall 2006 Solutions to Problem Set 4 (35 points)

EC 205 Macroeconomics I. Lecture 19

ANSWER: We can find consumption and saving by solving:

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Class 5. The IS-LM model and Aggregate Demand

Economics 222 Exercise A due Thursday 27 September in class

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

NAME: ID Number: 3. Lump sum taxes cause effects. a) Do not; wealth b) do; wealth c) do; substitution d) both (b) and (c).

Review: objectives. CHAPTER 2 The Data of Macroeconomics slide 0

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

1. Consider the aggregate production functions for Wisconsin and Minnesota: Production Function for Wisconsin

Economics Macroeconomic Theory. Spring Final Exam, Tuesday 6 May 2003

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Final Exam - Answers April 26, 2004

Foundations of Economics for International Business Supplementary Exercises 2

MA Macroeconomics 11. The Solow Model

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

1. Consider the aggregate production functions for Wisconsin and Minnesota: Production Function for Wisconsin

Chapter 1: The Science of Macroeconomics*

EQ: What are the Assumptions of Keynesian Economic Theory?

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (3 points each)

ECON2010 test 2 study guide

004: Macroeconomic Theory

14.02 Quiz 3. Time Allowed: 90 minutes. Fall 2012

Intermediate Macroeconomics

macro macroeconomics Economic Growth I Economic Growth I I (chapter 7) N. Gregory Mankiw

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 9: INTRODUCTION TO THE AD-AS MODEL

5. If capital lasts an average of 25 years, the depreciation rate is percent per year. A) 25 B) 5 C) 4 D) 2.5

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

Capital Income Tax Reform and the Japanese Economy (Very Preliminary and Incomplete)

Transcription:

Chapter 11 of Macroeconomics, Olivier Blanchard and David R. Johnson

Our two main relations are: Y t f K t K K s Y K t 1 t t t First relation: Capital determines output. Second relation: Output determines capital accumulation Combining the two relations, we can study the behavior of output and capital over time.

Y t f K t K K s Y K t 1 t t t From our main relations above, we express output per worker (Y t /) in terms of capital per worker to derive the equation below: Kt 1 Kt Change in capital from year t to year t + 1 = = sf K t Investment during year t K t Depreciation during year t

Kt 1 Kt Change in capital from year t to year t + 1 = = sf Kt Investment during year t K t Depreciation during year t This relation describes what happens to capital per worker. The change in capital per worker from this year to next year depends on the difference between two terms: If investment per worker exceeds depreciation per worker, the change in capital per worker is positive: Capital per worker increases. If investment per worker is less than depreciation per worker, the change in capital per worker is negative: Capital per worker decreases.

Graph 1 At K 0 /, capital per worker is low, investment exceeds depreciation, thus, capital per worker and output per worker tend to increase over time. F G K t+1 K t = sf K t δ K t

The highest curve is the graph of Y t / against K t / or Y t = f K t. The second curve is sf K t which is lower because 0<s<0. The straight line shows that the higher the amount of K t, the larger the depreciated amount. So when sf K t straight line, δ K t = δ K t, that is when the curve sf K t and meet at point F. At this point, the capital accumulation is equal to zero. All investment is spent on making up for the depreciated amount of capital. Therefore, FG is the amount of investment which is also the amount of depreciated capital. Suppose that the economy is not at point F but is having capital per capita to be K 0. So amount of output produced is AB, the amount of saving (or investment is equal to AC); but since the amount of depreciated capital is equal to AD so take AC subtract AD, we have the amount of capital being added on to the next period is equal to CD.

Output per worker Y t / In the end Graph 2 Period t B Period t + 2 Period t + 1 B B C C f K t sf δ K t K t C D D D K t+1 = K t + CD K t+2 = K t+1 + C D K o / A CD A C D A K K t /

Suppose that the economy initially has K o / (or K t / ) at time t. In this period, the economy invests (or saves) AC amount of output into capital for time t+1. But AD amount is for making up for the amount of capital per capita depreciated. So, the amount of capital accumulation (or the increase in capital per capita) is CD. Thus, CD amount of capital would be added on to the capital per capita stock. That is why the amount of capital per capita in the next period (t+1) is K t + CD. ote that, to be precise, we have: K t+1 know: K t δ K t + AC = K t δ K t = K t δ K t + AC; but we + AD + CD; note here that AD = δk t (see grh. 2). Therefore: K t δ K t + AC = K t + CD = K t+1

Since in period t+1 we have K t+1, the economy will produce at A B and save an amount equal to A C. The depreciated amount of capital is now A D ; so the increase in the capital per capita for period t+2 is equal to C D Thus, the amount of capital per capita in the next period ( K t+2 ) is: K t+2 = K t+1 + C D = K t + CD + C D In period t+2, we can see that the capital per capita stock is higher, K t+2 ; so the economy will produce higher output per capital which is equal to A B, the amount of capital added on to the capital stock in period t+3 would be C D. This process would be repeated for many periods until the capital per capita reach K*/, at which the investment is just enough to cover for the depreciation of capital.

Graph 3 Figure 11-2 Capital and Output Dynamics

At K*/, output per worker and capital per worker remain constant at their long-run equilibrium levels. When capital and output are low, investment exceeds depreciation, and capital increases. (as shown earlier) When capital and output are high, investment is less than depreciation, and capital decreases. (Homework) Investment per worker increases with capital per worker, but by less and less as capital per worker increases. Depreciation per worker increases in proportion to capital per worker.

K The state in which output per worker and capital per worker are no longer changing is called the steady state of the economy. In steady state, the left side of the equation above equals zero, then: sf K K = sf K t 1 t t t K* K* Given the steady state of capital per worker (K*/), the steady-state value of output per worker (Y*/), is given by the production function: Y* K* f

Three observations about the effects of the saving rate on the growth rate of output per worker are: 1. The saving rate has no effect on the long run growth rate of output per worker, which is equal to zero. 2. onetheless, the saving rate determines the level of output per worker in the long run. Other things equal, countries with a higher saving rate will achieve higher output per worker in the long run. 3. An increase in the saving rate will lead to higher growth of output per worker for some time, but not forever.

Figure 11-3 The Effects of Different Saving Rates Graph 4 A country with a higher saving rate achieves a higher steady- state level of output per worker.

Graph 5 Figure 11-4 The Effects of an Increase in the Saving Rate on Output per Worker An increase in the saving rate leads to a period of higher growth until output reaches its new, higher steady-state level.

Graph 6 Figure 11-5 The Effects of an Increase in the Saving Rate on Output per Worker in an Economy with Technological Progress An increase in the saving rate leads to a period of higher growth until output reaches a new, higher path.

Output per worker Y t / Graph 7 δ K t F X f K t sf K t E In LR, consumption is equal to FE M s f K t This is where the consumption is highest X K t /

An increase in the saving rate always leads to an increase in the level of output per worker. But output is not the same as consumption. To see why, consider what happens for two extreme values of the saving rate: An economy in which the saving rate is (and has always been) 0 is an economy in which capital is equal to zero. In this case, output is also equal to zero, and so is consumption. A saving rate equal to zero implies zero consumption in the long run. (Point X on graph 7) ow consider an economy in which the saving rate is equal to one: People save all their income. The level of capital, and thus output, in this economy will be very high. But because people save all their income, consumption is equal to zero. A saving rate equal to one also implies zero consumption in the long run. (Point X on graph 7)

The level of capital associated with the value of the saving rate that yields the highest level of consumption in steady state is known as the golden-rule level of capital.

Y t / Graph 8 δ K t X f K t X For every saving rate, there is a steady state capital per capita level, at which we can find the corresponding consumption per capita level. K t /

Figure 11-6 The Effects of the Saving Rate on Steady- State Consumption per Worker An increase in the saving rate leads to an increase and then to a decrease in steady-state consumption per worker.

Government can affect the saving rates in various way: Vary public saving: if public saving is positive, overall saving would be higher and vice versa. Vary taxes: e.g. tax breaks to provide more incentive to save o Government should care about the consumption per worker, not the output per worker because consumption per worker reflects the welfare of the people. o The level of capital per capita that yields highest level of consumption per capita in steady state is known as the golden-rule level of capital.

If the capital per capita is below the golden rule level, there should be an increase in the saving rate in the economy. o But immediately after the increase in saving rate, there would be lower consumption in the short run. (can you show it?) o However, in the long run, there would be higher consumption per capita. So there is a problem: Should the governments care about the future generations more or the current generation more? Because by increasing saving rate (through policies) the OECD governments can help the future generations but hurt the current generation. But the politics is about votes, rights to vote belong to the current generation, not the future generations it is unlikely that the governments will ask the current generations to make large sacrifices capital level would be still below the golden rule level.

One way to run a social security system is the fullyfunded system, where workers are taxed, their contributions invested in financial assets, and when workers retire, they receive the principal plus the interest payments on their investments. Another way to run a social security system is the payas-you-go system, where the taxes that workers pay are the benefits that current retirees receive.

Assume the production function is: Y K Output per worker is: Y K K K Output per worker, as it relates to capital per worker is: Kt Kt f Given our second relation, K K t 1 t t t K = sf K Then, K K K K s t 1 t t t

2 Y * K * s s Steady-state output per worker is equal to the ratio of the saving rate to the depreciation rate. (result applicable only for this particular production function) A higher saving rate and a lower depreciation rate both lead to higher steady-state capital per worker and higher steady-state output per worker.

Figure 11-7 The Dynamic Effects of an Increase in the Saving Rate from 10% to 20% on the Level and the Growth Rate of Output per Worker It takes a long time for output to adjust to its new, higher level after an increase in the saving rate. Put another way, an increase in the saving rate leads to a long period of higher growth.

In steady state, consumption per worker is equal to output per worker minus depreciation per worker. C Y K Knowing that: K* s 2 and 2 Y * K * s s then: C 2 s s s 1 s These equations are used to derive Table 11-1 in the next slide.

The U.S. Saving Rate and the Golden Rule Table 11-1 Saving Rate, s The Saving Rate and the Steady-state Levels of Capital, Output, and Consumption per Worker Capital per Worker, (K/) Output per Worker, (Y/) Consumption per Worker, (C/) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 1.0 1.0 0.9 0.2 4.0 2.0 1.6 0.3 9.0 3.0 2.1 0.4 16.0 4.0 2.4 0.5 25.0 5.0 2.5 0.6 36.0 6.0 2.4 1.0 100.0 10.0 0.0

The set of skills of the workers in the economy is called human capital. An economy with many highly skilled workers is likely to be much more productive than an economy in which most workers cannot read or write. The conclusions drawn about physical capital accumulation remain valid after the introduction of human capital in the analysis.

When the level of output per workers depends on both the level of physical capital per worker, K/, and the level of human capital per worker, H/, the production function may be written as: Y f K H, (, ) An increase in capital per worker or the average skill of workers leads to an increase in output per worker.

For example, a production function with human capital, capital and labour can look like this: Y = K α H β 1 α β Y = K α H β 1 α β Y = K α H β = f K, H

A measure of human capital may be constructed as follows: Suppose an economy has 100 workers, half of them unskilled and half of them skilled. The relative wage of skilled workers is twice that of unskilled workers. Then: H H 150 [( 50 1) ( 50 2)] 150 15. 100

An increase in how much society saves in the form of human capital through education and on-the-jobtraining increases steady-state human capital per worker, which leads to an increase in output per worker. In the long run, output per worker depends not only on how much society saves but also how much it spends on education.

In the United States, spending on education comprises about 6.5% of GDP, compared to 16% investment in physical capital. This comparison: Accounts for the fact that education is partly consumption. Does not account for the opportunity cost of education. Does not account for the opportunity cost of on-thejob-training. Considers gross, not net investment. Depreciation of human capital is slower than that of physical capital.

A recent study has concluded that output per worker depends roughly equally on the amount of physical capital and the amount of human capital in the economy. Models that generate steady growth even without technological progress are called models of endogenous growth, where growth depends on variables such as the saving rate and the rate of spending on education. Output per worker depends on the level of both physical capital per worker and human capital per worker. Is technological progress unrelated to the level of human capital in the economy? Can t a better-educated labor force lead to a higher rate of technological progress? These questions take us to the topic of the next chapter: the sources and the effects of technological progress.