Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows

Similar documents
Making Money out of Publicly Available Information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

Corrigendum to Prospect Theory and market quality Journal of Economic Theory 149 (2014),

Bid-Ask Spreads and Volume: The Role of Trade Timing

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

D.1 Sufficient conditions for the modified FV model

Pricing Prices. Alex Boulatov and Martin Dierker C.T. Bauer College of Business, University of Houston, Houston, TX March 1, 2007.

Market Size Matters: A Model of Excess Volatility in Large Markets

Research Article Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value

REPORTING BIAS AND INFORMATIVENESS IN CAPITAL MARKETS WITH NOISE TRADERS

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Learning whether other Traders are Informed

Algorithmic and High-Frequency Trading

Insider trading with partially informed traders

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Misallocation and the Distribution of Global Volatility: Online Appendix on Alternative Microfoundations

Market based compensation, trading and liquidity

Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Information acquisition and mutual funds

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Imperfect Competition, Information Asymmetry, and Cost of Capital

Liquidity and Asset Prices in Rational Expectations Equilibrium with Ambiguous Information

Accounting Conservatism, Market Liquidity and Informativeness of Asset Price: Implications on Mark to Market Accounting

Dynamic signaling and market breakdown

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Game-Theoretic Risk Analysis in Decision-Theoretic Rough Sets

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Forbearance in Prudential Regulation

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Market Efficiency with Micro and Macro Information

Roy Model of Self-Selection: General Case

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

A Model of Portfolio Delegation and Strategic Trading

Investor Information Choice with Macro and Micro Information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Delegated Trade and the Pricing of Public and Private Information

Disclosure Requirements and Stock Exchange Listing Choice in an International Context

COMPARATIVE MARKET SYSTEM ANALYSIS: LIMIT ORDER MARKET AND DEALER MARKET. Hisashi Hashimoto. Received December 11, 2009; revised December 25, 2009

Information Disclosure in Financial Markets

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Optimal Disclosure and Fight for Attention

Credit Rating Changes, Information Acquisition and Stock Price Informativeness

Executive Compensation and Short-Termism

Supplementary Appendix for Are CDS Auctions Biased and Inefficient?

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS. Private and public information

Technical Analysis, Liquidity Provision, and Return Predictability

Liquidity and Asset Returns Under Asymmetric Information and Imperfect Competition

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Dispersed Information, Monetary Policy and Central Bank Communication

Risk Aversion, Strategic Trading and Mandatory Public Disclosure

Supplementary Appendix for Liquidity, Volume, and Price Behavior: The Impact of Order vs. Quote Based Trading not for publication

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

LectureNote: MarketMicrostructure

Investment Constraints and Delegated Portfolio Management

Information, Imperfect Competition, and Volatility

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

Learning to Trade with Insider Information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE. Are We Better-off for Working Hard? QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE F INANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

Market Efficiency and Real Efficiency: The Connect and Disconnect via Feedback Effects

Information Disclosure and Real Investment in a Dynamic Setting

Abstract In this paper we model a corporate manager's choice of a disclosure regime. In a model in which disclosure has no efficiency gains like reduc

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

FIN CORPORATE FINANCE Spring Office: CBA 6.246, Phone: ,

Accounting Tinder: Acquisition of Information with Uncertain Precision

Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan. Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe:

Does order splitting signal uninformed order flow?

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

A Theory of Asset Prices based on Heterogeneous Information and Limits to Arbitrage

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Fund managers contracts and short-termism 1

Effi cient monetary policy frontier for Iceland

The Lender of Last Resort and Bank Failures Some Theoretical Considerations

Short Selling, Earnings Management, and Firm Value

Kyle Model Governance Atoms Bonds. Presence of an Informed Trader and Other Atoms in Kyle Models. Kyle Model Governance Atoms Bonds

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Information and Evidence in Bargaining

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

News Trading and Speed

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods?

This is an author-deposited version published in: Eprints ID: 5803

Transcription:

Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows Liyan Yang Haoxiang Zhu July 4, 017 In Yang and Zhu (017), we have taken the information of the fundamental investor and the back-runner as given. In this internet appendix, we explicitly model information acquisition. Besides showing the robustness of our earlier results, this additional step sheds light on questions such as Does back-running discourage acquisition of fundamental information? Setup of Information Acquisition We add one period, t = 0, before the two-period economy considered in Yang and Zhu (017). At t = 0, the fundamental investor decides the amount of fundamental information she acquires, and the back-runner decides the precision of order flow information he acquires. Specifically, for the fundamental trader, we follow Admati and Pfleiderer (1989), Madrigal (1996), and Bond, Goldstein, and Prescott (010) and assume that the fundamental investor can pay a cost C F (φ) upfront to observe the fundamental value v with probability φ (0, 1). For the back-runner, we follow( Verrecchia ) (198) and Vives (008) and assume that the 1 back-runner can pay a cost C B upfront to observe a signal s of x σε 1 with precision 1. σε These information-acquisition decisions are simultaneous. After time 0, the choices of φ and σ ε become public information. In reality, investment in fundamental research, such as hiring analysts, and investment in advanced trading technology, such as high-speed connections to exchanges, are usually observable. To ensure interior solutions of σ ε and φ, we make the standard technical assumptions: (i) C B ( ) and C F ( ) are increasing and convex; and (ii) C B (0) = C B (0) = 0, C B ( ) = C B ( ) =, C F (0) = C F (0) = 0, and C F (1) = C F (1) =. Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto; liyan.yang@rotman.utoronto.ca. MIT Sloan School of Management; zhuh@mit.edu. 1

For simplicity, we assume that at the beginning of period 1, it becomes public knowledge whether the fundamental investor has successfully observed v. It is a standard assumption in Kyle-type models whether such an (fundamentally) informed investor exists. Then, the subsequent game has two possible outcomes: 1. If the fundamental investor observes v, then the economy is the one that we analyzed in Yang and Zhu (017).. If the fundamental investor does not observe v, then as an uninformed investor she will not trade in either period. As a result, the back-runner will not trade in period, either, despite receiving the signal of the fundamental investor s (zero) order flow. In this case, only noise traders submit orders, and so the price is p 1 = p = E (v) = p 0. Analysis and Results Our objective is to find the equilibrium levels of φ and σ ε. These are determined jointly by the period-0 maximization problems of the fundamental investor and the back-runner. Recall that π F,1 and π F, denote the realized profits of the fundamental investor in dates 1 and, respectively. The fundamental investor s period-0 expected net profit is: Π F,0 φe (π F,1 + π F, ) C F (φ), and her problem is to chose φ to maximize Π F,0, taking her conjectured equilibrium value of σ ε as given. Because E (π F,1 + π F, ) does not depend on φ, and given the technical assumption on C F (φ), we know that the solution to the fundamental investor s problem is characterized by the first-order condition: E (π F,1 + π F, ) = C F (φ). Now we consider the back-runner s information acquisition problem. Recall that π B, (v p ) d is the back-runner s realized period- profit. So, his period-0 expected net profit of acquiring order flow information is: Π B,0 φe (π B, ) C B ( 1 σ ε The back-runner takes the equilibrium value φ as given and chooses σ ε to maximize Π B 0. ).

The back-runner s choice of σ ε affects E (π B, ) through its effect on the equilibrium strategies, σ z, β v,1, β v,, β x1, β y1, δ s, δ y1, λ 1 and λ. Specifically, we can compute [ E (π B, ) = λ (δs δ y1 ) βv,1σ 0 + (δ s δ y1 ) σz + δsσ ε + δy 1 σu], and hence Π B,0 = φλ [ (δs δ y1 ) β v,1σ 0 + (δ s δ y1 ) σ z + δ sσ ε + δ y 1 σ u] CB ( 1 σ ε There is an important complication in the solution to the back-runner s informationacquisition problem. Although this problem has an interior solution, as ensured by the cost function C B ( ), the optimal choice of σ ε cannot in general be guaranteed by setting the firstorder derivative to zero. This is because whether the equilibrium has a mixed strategy or a pure strategy (used by the fundamental investor) depends on σ ε. As σ ε decreases and drops below the threshold value of ( 17 4/)σu, the equilibrium switches from pure strategy to mixed strategy, giving rise to a kink in E (π B, ). If the optimal value of σ ε occurs at the kink, the first-order condition is characterized by two inequalities rather than an equality. (This complication does not apply to the fundamental investor s problem.) To solve the equilibrium explicitly and numerically, we need explicit functional forms of C B and C F. Following Vives (008), we choose the following parametrization: ) ( ( ) hb 1 1 C B = k σε B = k σε B σ h B ( ) hf φ C F (φ) = k F, 1 φ ε, ). where > 0, k F > 0, h B > 1 and h F > 1. We will conduct comparative statics with respect to parameter, which is taken as a proxy for the cost of acquiring order flow information. A larger means a higher cost. In order to gain better intuition of the comparative statics, it is useful to first illustrate the kink in Π B,0. Figure 1 plots the profit function Π B,0 against σ ε, for {1, 8, 15}, in the three panels. In each panel, φ is set to its equilibrium value corresponding to the particular and does not vary with σ ε, since this value of φ is the belief of the back-runner at the information-acquisition stage. But for each σ ε, other equilibrium variables in periods 1 and 3

Figure 1: Illustration of Possible Kink in Π B,0 11.4 (a) =8 11.3 11. 11.1 11 10.9 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 1.4 1. 1 11.8 11.6 (b1) =1 11 10.5 10 (b) =15 11.4 1 1. 1.4 1.6 1.8 9.5 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 This figure plots Π B,0 against σ ε for three values of. In each panel, φ is set to its equilibrium value corresponding to the particular and does not vary with σ ε. For each σ ε, other equilibrium variables in periods 1 and are optimized to this particular σ ε. The red dot is the global maximum. Other parameters: σ u = 10, Σ 0 = 100, k F = 1, and h F = h B =. are determined according to Propositions 1 and of Yang and Zhu (017) for this particular σ ε (and the fixed equilibrium value of φ), because at the information-acquisition stage, the back-runner takes into account how the fundamental investor and the market maker react in future periods. As in earlier figures, we set σ u = 10 and Σ 0 = 100. We also set k F = 1 and h F = h B =. In Panel (a), where = 8, the optimal σ ε occurs exactly at the kink. In Panels (b1) and (b), where = 1 and = 15 respectively, the optimal values of σ ε are found in the smooth regions. Intuitively, if the information-acquisition cost is very high or very low, the unconstrained optimal σ ε the solution without considering the equilibrium switch is sufficiently far away from the threshold ( 17 4/)σu, so the switch in equilibrium does not bind, as in Panels (b1) and (b). If, however, takes an intermediate value, the nature 4

of equilibrium depends heavily on σ ε. In the mixed strategy region of Panel (a), i.e. if σ ε < ( 17 4/)σu, the back-runner prefers to acquire less precise information because the fundamental investor injects noise anyway; but in the pure strategy region of Panel (a), i.e. if σ ε ( 17 4/)σu, the back-runner prefers more precise information because the fundamental investor does not inject any noise. The result is that the unique maximum of Π B,0 is obtained when σ ε is exactly at the threshold ( 17 4/)σu. As we see shortly, this corner solution leads to the stickiness in the responses of equilibrium outcomes to changes in. Now we proceed with describing the comparatives statics. The variables of interest include: Equilibrium values of φ, σ ε, σ z, β v,1, β v,, β x1, β y1, δ s, δ y1, λ 1 and λ ; Equilibrium profits: Π F,0 and Π B,0, and the expected cost of noise traders Π F,0 + Π B,0 ; Expected price discovery: φσ 1 +(1 φ) Σ 0 for period 1 and φσ +(1 φ) Σ 0 for period ; Expected illiquidity: φλ 1 + (1 φ) 0 = φλ 1 for period 1 and φλ + (1 φ) 0 = φλ for period. where λ 1 and λ are are Kyle s lambdas, and Σ 1 and Σ are conditional variances of v, all defined in Yang and Zhu (017). Figure plots the implications of changes in information acquisition cost for informationacquisition decisions, profits of various groups of traders, price discovery, and market illiquidity. An interesting and salient pattern is that all but one of these variables are entirely irresponsive to changes in when is in an intermediate range. As discussed earlier, in this range, the optimal σ ε is always equal to ( 17 4/)σu regardless of. As a result, the equilibrium has zero sensitivity to, leading to the flat parts of equilibrium variables. Moreover, we observe that a lower weakly reduces φ, which implies that technology improvement in processing order flow information reduces investment in fundamental information (top row of Figure ). A lower cost of acquiring order flow information leads to a higher profit of the back-runner but a lower profit of the fundamental investor. The loss of noise traders, the period-1 price discovery, and the period-1 market liquidity are all nonmonotone in. This last result mirrors the patterns in Figures 3 and 4 of Yang and Zhu (017) that these variables are also non-monotone in σ ε. 5

? Figure : Equilibrium Strategies and Implications of Information Acquisition 0.71 1.5 1 0.7 0.5 0.719 14 41.5?(6 1 +6 )< u 59.8 1 & F,0 41 40.5 59.7 59.6 10 40 59.5?' 1 +(1-?)' 0 84.5 84 83.5?' +(1-?)' 0 48.5 48 47.5 0.99 0.99?6 1 0.985 0.98?6 0.985 0.98 0.975 0.975 This figure plots the equilibrium levels of information acquisition, expected profits of various parties, price discovery, and market illiquidity, as functions of. Other parameters: σ u = 10, Σ 0 = 100, k F = 1, and h F = h B =. Overall, results in Yang and Zhu (017) are robust to information acquisition. A unique and novel prediction with information acquisition is that equilibrium outcomes can be insensitive to the cost of order flow information. This insensitivity is the consequence of the switch between a pure strategy equilibrium and a mixed strategy one. 6

References Admati, A. and P. Pfleiderer (1989): Divide and conquer: A theory of intraday and day-of-the-week mean effects. Review of Financial Studies,, 189 3. Bond, P., I. Goldstein, and E. S. Prescott (010): Market-Based Corrective Actions, Review of Financial Studies, 3, 781 80. Madrigal, V. (1996): Non-Fundamental Speculation, Journal of Finance, 51, 553 578. Verrecchia, R. E. (198): Information Acquisition in a Noisy Rational Expectations Economy, Econometrica, 50, 1415 1430. Vives, X. (008): Information and Learning in Markets: The Impact of Market Microstructure, Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford. Yang, L. and H. Zhu (017): Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows, Working paper, University of Toronto and MIT. 7