This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

Similar documents
THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Classifying exchange rate regimes: a statistical analysis of alternative methods. Abstract

Does a Bias in FOMC Policy Directives Help Predict Inter-Meeting Policy Changes? * John S. Lapp. and. Douglas K. Pearce

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

The RBI s Monetary Policy Reaction Function Does monetary policy in India follow an inflation targeting rule?

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

This is a repository copy of A Zero Inflated Regression Model for Grouped Data.

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy?

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Monetary Transmission in Simple Backward-Looking Models: The IS Puzzle

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

Monetary policy and the yield curve

Modelling Inflation Uncertainty Using EGARCH: An Application to Turkey

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate?

This is a repository copy of Financial Expectations, Consumption and Saving: A Microeconomic Analysis.

Global Slack as a Determinant of US Inflation *

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

BCEAO. Anja Shortland and David Stasavage 1

Modeling Federal Funds Rates: A Comparison of Four Methodologies

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment between stock prices and dividends

Creditor protection and banking system development in India

Calculating the real exchange rate

Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Inflation Targeting on the Risk Premium

The Relative Income Hypothesis: A comparison of methods.

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

MONETARY POLICY IN POLAND HOW THE FINANCIAL CRISIS CHANGED THE CENTRAL BANK S PREFERENCES

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

The persistence of regional unemployment: evidence from China

Is monetary policy in New Zealand similar to

Monetary Policy rule in the presence of persistent excess liquidity: the case of Trinidad and Tobago

Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

MARKET REACTION TO MONETARY POLICY NONANNOUNCEMENTS. V. Vance Roley. and. Gordon H. Sellon, Jr. First Version: March 6, 1998

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are

Asian Economic and Financial Review MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION AND BANK LENDING IN SOUTH KOREA AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Yu Hsing

Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia

TRADE COLLAPSE DURING THE 2009 CRISIS: HOW DID EUROPEAN COMPANIES FARE? LESSONS FROM

Did the Swiss Demand for Money Function Shift? Journal of Economics and Business, 35(2) April 1983,

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

FOREIGN TRADE MULTIPLIER IN ROMANIA BEFORE AND AFTER ACCESSION TO THE EUROPEAN UNION

Credit Channel of Monetary Policy between Australia and New. Zealand: an Empirical Note

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000

Output gap uncertainty: Does it matter for the Taylor rule? *

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Whether Cash Dividend Policy of Chinese

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

RE-EXAMINE THE INTER-LINKAGE BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INFLATION:EVIDENCE FROM INDIA

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

Estimating a Fiscal Reaction Function for Greece

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve

Investment Platforms Market Study Interim Report: Annex 7 Fund Discounts and Promotions

The Bank Lending Channel: Evidence from Australia

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements

LENDING IN A LOW INTEREST RATE ENVIRONMENT

Analysis of the Influence of the Annualized Rate of Rentability on the Unit Value of the Net Assets of the Private Administered Pension Fund NN

International evidence of tax smoothing in a panel of industrial countries

WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES AND THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS AT THE SHORT END OF THE YIELD CURVE. Selva Demiralp

Determinants of Revenue Generation Capacity in the Economy of Pakistan

Minutes of the Monetary Policy Council decision-making meeting held on 6 July 2016

IS READY ROMANIA FOR EURO ADOPTION? FROM STRUCTURAL CONVERGENCE TO BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION

Regional convergence in Spain:

Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Asian Economic and Financial Review, 2016, 6(4): Asian Economic and Financial Review. ISSN(e): /ISSN(p):

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Analysis of Stock Price Behaviour around Bonus Issue:

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

The Use of Market Information in Bank Supervision: Interest Rates on Large Time Deposits

Estimating the Impact of Changes in the Federal Funds Target Rate on Market Interest Rates from the 1980s to the Present Day

Transcription:

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/9880/ Monograph: Gascoigne, J. and Turner, P. (200) Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. Working Paper. Department of Economics, University of Sheffield ISSN 1749-868 Sheffield Economic Research Paper Series 200007 Reuse Unless indicated otherwise, fulltext items are protected by copyright with all rights reserved. The copyright exception in section 29 of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988 allows the making of a single copy solely for the purpose of non-commercial research or private study within the limits of fair dealing. The publisher or other rights-holder may allow further reproduction and re-use of this version - refer to the White Rose Research Online record for this item. Where records identify the publisher as the copyright holder, users can verify any specific terms of use on the publisher s website. Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing eprints@whiterose.ac.uk including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. eprints@whiterose.ac.uk https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/

Sheffield Economic Research Paper Series SERP Number: 200007 Jamie Gascoigne and Paul Turner Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy August 200 Department of Economics University of Sheffield 9 Mappin Street Sheffield S1 4DT United Kingdom www.shef.ac.uk/economics

Abstract In this paper we estimate limited dependent variable models for Bank of England monetary policy using monthly data over the period June 1997 to March 200. During this period the Bank has had operational independence to set the interest rate in order to meet the inflation target set by the Government. We find evidence that the Bank has responded to current output growth rather than inflation which is consistent with targeting future inflation when there is a lag in the response of inflation to the output gap. We also find evidence of an asymmetry in the sense that the link between the interest rate and output growth is stronger when an increase in the interest rate is required than when circumstances dictate it should be cut. On the other hand there is considerably more inertia for interest rate cuts in the sense that a cut in the rate in one month significantly increases the probability of a cut in the next month which is not the case for increases. Keywords: Monetary policy reaction functions, Central Bank independence, binary choice models. JEL Numbers: E4, E58, C25. 1

I. INTRODUCTION In May 1997 the incoming Labour government granted operational independence to the Bank of England. Its objective, as stated on the Bank s website, is to meet the Government s inflation target currently 2.5% - by setting short term interest rates. The Bank also defines its objective in the following terms to deliver price stability (as defined by the Government s inflation target) and, without prejudice to that objective, to support the Government s economic policy, including its objectives for growth and employment (both quotations from the Bank of England s website). This description of policy can be expressed mathematically in the form of a Taylor Rule linking short term interest rates to deviations of inflation and output from target values and the empirical fit of such equations has been the subject of much recent research. For example, Clarida, Gali and Gertler (1998) estimate monetary policy reaction functions of this type for a variety of economies. Judd and Rudebusch (1998); Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000) and Rudebusch (2001) use this framework to analyse the monetary policy followed by the US Federal Reserve while Nelson (2000) carries out a similar exercise for the Bank of England. Decisions on interest rates in the UK are taken by the Bank of England s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) which meets on a monthly basis to decide on the official repo rate (rate at which the Bank lends to the money markets). Changes in this rate are quickly transmitted to other short term interest rates and then, with lags, to longer term rates, asset prices, real output and inflation (Bank of England 1999). In practice decisions on monetary policy have proved to be less concerned with the ideal level of interest rates and more with the direction in which they should move. Since May 1997, in the 7 months for which we have data, there have been only four different policy decisions taken by the MPC on 9 occasions the repo rate has been raised by ¼ point, on 11 it has been lowered by ¼ pt, on 4 it has been lowered by ½ pt and on 49 it has been left unchanged. 2

When the Bank was initially granted operational independence there was considerable concern that this might introduce a deflationary bias into the system. For example, Bean (1998) argues that the lack of a complete contract between the Bank and the Government is a potential source of deflationary bias (although the empirical evidence suggests this might be quite weak). The argument was that the Bank would be less likely to respond by cutting rates in response to a fall in inflation below target than it was to increase rates when inflation rose above target. This problem was seen as arising because of the composition of the MPC which, at least initially, reflected the more conservative views of the banking and finance community rather than manufacturing and industry which were more likely to favour a stimulus in periods of economic downturn cf. Palley (1996). In this paper we examine an alternative to the continuous Taylor rule for interest rates by estimating an ordered or binary choice model in which the choice is whether to raise or lower the repo rate. We believe this is close to the way in which actual policy has evolved in that changes in the rate are relatively infrequent and, when they do occur, tend to be of a predictable magnitude. This contrasts with much of the literature in which the interest rate is generally treated as continuous an exception being Dolado et al (2000) in which equations for Germany, France, Spain and the US are estimated using an ordered probit approach. Our evidence for the UK is consistent with interest rate movements being more sensitive to output conditions rather than inflation. Although this may seem surprising when inflation is the primary target, we argue that it is consistent with forward looking behaviour when inflation responds to output deviations with a lag. We also show that there is evidence of asymmetry in the sense that an increase in the interest rate in response to positive deviations of inflation and output from target is higher than a cut in the interest rate in response to equivalent negative deviations. On the other hand cuts in rates tend to show more persistence in the sense if the interest rate is cut in one month makes it more likely that there will be a cut in the next month, a pattern which does not hold for increases.

II. DATA The interest rate data used in this paper is taken from the Bank of England s website. For the ordered logit and probit regressions we code the data as follows 0 = ½ pt cut in repo rate, 1 = ¼ pt cut, 2 = no change, = ¼ pt increase. For the binary choice models the variable is coded as 0 for no change and 1 for either an increase or decrease. Inflation is the 12 month rate of increase in the retail price index minus mortgage interest payments (RPIX). Growth is the 12 month rate of increase in Gross Domestic Product (GDP) where the monthly data have been constructed using ONS quarterly data and interpolating using data on Industrial Production by means of the Chow-Lin (1971) procedure. The other variables used are zero-one dummy variables for increases or cuts in the interest rate in the previous month. III. ESTIMATES As a first stage we estimated ordered regressions for interest rate changes in which the independent variables are the current rate of inflation and the rate of growth of GDP. Our prior expectation is that both these variables will have a positive sign i.e. will increase the probability of an interest rate increase while reducing that of a cut. Since the sample is somewhat unbalanced (zero change occurs more often than either increases or cuts) we estimated our regressions using both probit and logit functional forms to investigate if any differences emerged. The results are reported in Table 1. Numbers in parentheses are z statistics which provide an asymptotically normal test for the null hypothesis that the coefficient in question is equal to zero. Goodness of fit is measured by the Likelihood Ratio Index or the Pseudo R 2. All estimates were obtained using the EViews 4.1 regression package. [Insert Table 1 here] 4

In practice the functional form used makes very little difference to the results but we report both sets for the interested reader. In terms of the economic interpretation of the regression equations, we find that the current rate of inflation plays very little role in determining the probability of interest rate changes as can be seen by the low level of significance of this variable and the fact that its sign is opposite to that expected. In contrast the growth rate coefficient both has the correct sign and is statistically significant. It is tempting to interpret this as indicating that the Bank is stabilising output rather than pursuing its designated target of stabilising inflation. However, an alternative explanation (which we believe) is that the Bank is adopting a forward looking strategy to stabilise inflation over the immediate future. Since most estimates of the price adjustment equation indicate that the output gap enters with a lag, it makes sense to respond to the current output gap in order to stabilise future inflation. One implication of the fact that changes in interest rates have tended to be small in magnitude (typically ¼ pt) is that there are occasions when the total desired change is unlikely to be achieved in a single adjustment. Thus there have been occasions when there have been several months in which successive interest rate changes have been in the same direction. To test for this formally we report regressions in Table 1 in which dummy variables have been included which capture the direction of movement of the interest rate in the previous period. Thus the lagged cut term is zero if the interest rate was not cut in the previous month and one if it was. The lagged increase term is defined in the same way. We note from Table 1 that the lagged cut coefficient is significant in both the probit and logit regressions while the lagged increase coefficient is insignificant in both cases. This indicates a basic asymmetry in monetary policy in the sense that a cut in the interest rate in one month makes it more likely that it will be cut again in the next month. However, no such inertia exists with respect to increases in the interest rate. Note that the inclusion of the lagged adjustment terms makes little difference to the estimated coefficients for inflation and the growth rate. 5

The estimated limit terms reported below each regression (z-statistics in parentheses) allow us to calculate the probability of each of the events being modelled as well as the marginal effects of the exogenous variables on each event cf. Greene (199, chapter 20). The actual frequencies observed for the ½ pt cut, ¼ pt cut, zero change and ¼ pt increase are 0.06, 0.14, 0.67 and 0.1. Using the probit model with the inertia terms included we obtain estimates of the probabilities equal to 0.004, 0.09, 0.84 and 0.07 and for the logit model with inertia terms we obtain 0.009, 0.07, 0.84 and 0.08. This is a source of some concern in that our estimated model tends to underpredict changes in the interest rate in either direction in favour of no change. In particular our model assigns virtually zero probability to a ½ pt cut in the interest rate. However, the results may simply reflect the fact that we have a relatively small sample and the addition of more data may lead to the estimated probabilities converging to their true values. [Insert Table 2 here] One of the problems of limited dependent variable models is that the coefficient estimates do not measure the marginal effects of changes in the exogenous variables in the same way as they do with the standard linear model with a continuous dependent variable. However, we can calculate the marginal probability effects as shown in Table 2. These results show that inflation and the lagged increase terms have almost no effect on the marginal probabilities. In contrast the output growth and the lagged cut terms both affect the marginal probability terms in meaningful ways. An increase in output growth increases the probability of an increase in the interest rate and reduces that of a cut. Similarly an interest rate cut in one period increases the probability of a cut in the next period and reduces the probability of an increase. Since our regressions in Table 1 indicate some prima facie evidence of an asymmetry in monetary policy, we decided to investigate this further by estimating simple binary models for increases and cuts in interest rates respectively. In Table we present the 6

results of a regression in which the dependent variable is a zero-one dummy variable in which zero corresponds to no change or a cut while one corresponds to an increase. We report three models the linear probability model, probit and logit estimates. Numbers in parentheses below coefficients are z statistics while numbers in bold type are the marginal probabilities. In the case of the linear probability model, the estimates of the marginal probabilities are equal to the coefficients. The estimates again indicate that both inflation and output growth have the correct sign but the inflation term is only marginally significant while the output growth term is strongly significant. The lagged increase term is not significant in any of the regressions. The marginal probabilities are very similar for the probit and logit models but in each case these are lower than those estimated using the linear probability model. [Insert Table here] Table 4 presents results for a binary regression for interest rate cuts. In this case the inflation coefficient has the wrong sign although growth has the correct sign. However, in both cases these variables are insignificant. The lagged cut term proves to be highly significant in this case indicating that inertia is much more important for interest rate cuts than it is for increases. [Insert Table 4 here] 7

IV. CONCLUSIONS In this paper we have investigated Bank of England monetary policy during its period of operation independence using a limited dependent variable approach. Estimation using an ordered dependent variable indicates that output growth is the most important determinant of the probability of interest rate changes. There is also some evidence of inertia in that a cut in the interest rate in one month increases the probability that it will be cut again in the subsequent month while reducing the probability that it will be increased. We investigated this asymmetry further by estimating simple binary choice models for increases and cuts in the interest rate. These indicate a significant asymmetry in policy in that the interest rate responds strongly in a positive direction to an increase in growth with very little evidence of inertia. In contrast the evidence for a systematic effect of low growth on the probability of a cut in the interest rate is much weaker and there is considerably more inertia when the direction of movement is downwards. 8

REFERENCES Bank of England, Monetary Policy Committee (1999) The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy www.bankofengland.co.uk. Bean, C. (1998) The New UK Monetary Arrangements: A View from the Literature, Economic Journal, Vol 108, No 451 pp. 1795-1809. Chow, G.C. and Lin, A.L. (1971) Best Linear Unbiased Interpolation, Distribution, and Extrapolation of Time Series by Related Series, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol 5, No 4, pp. 72-75. Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler M. (1998) Monetary Policy Rules in Practice: Some International Evidence, European Economic Review, Vol 42, Issue 6, pp. 10-1067. Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler M. (2000) Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol 115, Issue 1, pp. 147-180. Dolado, J., Maria-Dolores, R. and Navier, M. (2000) Asymmetries in Monetary Policy Rules: Evidence for Four Central Banks CEPR Discussion Paper No 2441. Greene, W.H. (199) Econometric Analysis: 2 nd Edition, New York: Macmillan. Judd, J. and Rudebusch, G.D. (1998) Taylor s Rule and the Fed, 1970-1997, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, Vol, pp. -16. Nelson, E. (2000) UK Monetary Policy 1972-1997: A Guide using Taylor Rules, Bank of England Working Paper No 120. Palley, T.I. (1996) The Institutionalization of Deflationary Monetary Policy, Economies et Societies, Vol 0, Nos 2-, pp. 247-268. Rudebusch, G.D. (2001) Is the Fed too Timid: Monetary Policy in an Uncertain World Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol 8, No 2, pp. 20-217. 9

Table 1: Ordered Dependent Variable Estimates. Monthly Data June 1997 to March 200 (70 Observations) Ordered Probit Ordered Logit Inflation -0.1991-0.0170-0.294-0.1279 (0.47) (0.04) (0.44) (0.16) Growth 0.97 0.822 1.6679 1.456 (.79) (2.85) (.61) (2.79) Lagged Cut -1.6500-2.8998 (.77) (.6) Lagged Increase -0.0410 0.0794 (0.08) (0.09) Limit 1-1.77 (6.18) -2.62 (5.88) -.21 (5.2) -4.61 (5.49) Limit 2-0.88 (4.8) -1.7 (4.90) -1.51 (4.22) -2.40 (4.51) Limit 1.62 (5.79) 1.44 (4.89) 2.74 (5.) 2.50 (4.56) Log Likelihood -56.78-49.11-57.6-49.79 Pseudo 2 R 0.1 0.25 0.12 0.24 10

Table 2: Marginal Probability Effects for the Ordered Regression Model Probit Model Inflation Output Lagged Cut Lagged Increase 4 ½ pt cut 2. 4-0.011 0.124.519 ¼ pt cut 2.58-0.12 0.60 1.818 4 No change 4.866 0.024-0.85 4.856 ¼ pt increase 2.285 0.111-0.099 7.026 Logit Model Inflation Output Lagged Cut Lagged Increase 4 ½ pt cut 2. 4-0.014 0.11 5.524 ¼ pt cut 7.595-0.098 0.76.96 4 No change 8.8 0.011-0.92 2.918 ¼ pt increase 7.872 0.102-0.095 7.4 11

Table : Interest Rate Increase Model. Monthly Data June 1997 to March 200 (70 Observations) Linear Probability Model Probit Logit Inflation 0.2001 1.28 2.158 (1.91) (1.81) (1.78) 0.118 0.098 Growth 0.1544 1.1619 2.0826 (2.87) (2.55) (2.4) 0.10 0.088 Lagged Increase -0.0257-0.72-0.5011 (0.21) (0.50) (0.44) -0.00-0.021 Log Likelihood -11.49-17.0-17.26 2 R - McFadden 2 R 0.20 0.2 0.1 12

Table 4: Interest Rate Cut Model. Monthly Data June 1997 to March 200 (70 Observations) Linear Probability Model Probit Logit Inflation 0.1476 0.7116 1.5205 (1.0) (1.20) (1.2) 0.15 0.162 Growth -0.0669-0.4222-0.7792 (1.11) (1.18) (1.18) -0.091-0.08 Lagged Cut 0.5442 1.6541 2.8548 (5.02) (.52) (.46) 0.56 0.04 Log Likelihood -18.68-2.47-2.60 2 R - McFadden 2 R 0.4 0.0 0.0 1