Final Report on MAPPR Project: The Detroit Living Wage Ordinance: Will it Reduce Urban Poverty? David Neumark May 30, 2001

Similar documents
Mean Wage US LQ MI LQ. Northwest Michigan

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF LIVING WAGE LAWS: A PROVISIONAL REVIEW. Scott Adams David Neumark

Michigan Socioeconomic Conditions and Trends: West Michigan Compared to East Michigan

Program Review Analysis

Michigan s July Unemployment Rate Moves Up Seasonally

Michigan s January Unemployment Rate Moves Up Seasonally

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be

Program Review Analysis

Forecast for Muskegon County was a great year!

{City of East Lansing} INCOME TAX FEASIBILITY STUDY OCTOBER 30, 2016

The misplaced debate about job loss and a $15 minimum wage

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Adjusting Poverty Thresholds When Area Prices Differ: Labor Market Evidence

APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE. Christina D. Romer David H.

Program Review Analysis

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

The Minimum Wage, Fringe Benefits, and Worker Welfare: Response. to Cengiz. Jeffrey Clemens, Lisa B. Kahn, and Jonathan Meer.

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

Summary. July 30, Blue Ribbon Revenue Panel c/o: Mr. Jim Ritsema, City Manager City of Kalamazoo 241 West South Street Kalamazoo, MI 49007

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity?

POLICY BRIEF. The Employment Effects of Eliminating the Tip Credit in Michigan

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

Thinking about Local Living Wage Requirements

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

LABOR MARKET NEWS MICHIGAN S. The Components of Personal Income in Michigan. Map of the Month: Michigan Median Age by County

Alternative Labor Market Policies to Increase Economic Self-Sufficiency: Mandating Higher Wages, Subsidizing Employment, and Raising Productivity

Effects of the Oregon Minimum Wage Increase

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession

November Unemployment Rates Decrease in Most of Michigan s Regional Labor Markets

Do Living Wages alter the Effect of the Minimum Wage on Income Inequality?

THE TRANSMISSION OF IMPORT PRICES TO DOMESTIC PRICES: AN APPLICATION TO INDONESIA * Peter Warr

An Overview of the U.S. Economy

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECTS OF CHANGES IN STATE SSI SUPPLEMENTS ON PRE-RETIREMENT LABOR SUPPLY. David Neumark Elizabeth T.

Summary of Latest Federal Income Tax Data

BENTON HARBOR CITY TAX HOSTED BY PLANTE MORAN AND CORNERSTONE ALLIANCE DECEMBER 2017

Fixing the Payroll Tax and Improving Unemployment Insurance Reserves

LABOR MARKET NEWS MICHIGAN S. Occupational Supply and Demand in the Michigan Labor Market

Labor Market Conditions in Ohio Versus the Rest of the United States:

Use of the Federal Empowerment Zone Employment Credit for Tax Year 1997: Who Claims What?

July 23, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

The Huntington National Bank

COMPARING RECENT DECLINES IN OREGON'S CASH ASSISTANCE CASELOAD WITH TRENDS IN THE POVERTY POPULATION

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries

Comment on Christina and David Romer s Do Tax Cuts Starve the Beast? By Steven J. Davis 2 July 2009

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES. Thomas M.

The Service Contractor Provision of the Proposed Living Wage Ordinance in Allegheny County. An Impact Assessment

There is poverty convergence

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

Volume Title: Private Pension Funds: Projected Growth. Volume URL: Chapter URL:

Persistent Mispricing in Mutual Funds: The Case of Real Estate

Social Security Policy and Rural Communities, with Comparisons to Urban Communities

VIEWPOINT state tax notes

Redistributive Effects of Pension Reform in China

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A CROSS-NATIONAL ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF MINIMUM WAGES ON YOUTH EMPLOYMENT. David Neumark William Wascher

Portfolio Rebalancing:

Turning everyday people into money heroes! Impact of Payday Lending on Families in Greater Grand Rapids. Original Report: July 7, 2015

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

Examining the Determinants of Earnings Differentials Across Major Metropolitan Areas

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

How would an expansion of IDA reduce poverty and further other development goals?

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio. William Melick Kenyon College. Eric Andersen American Action Forum

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

By eliminating jobs and/or reducing employment growth,

NST TUTE FOR RESEARCH

Determinants of Federal and State Community Development Spending:

STRATEGIES FOR THE ANALYSIS OF IMPUTED DATA IN A SAMPLE SURVEY

GOVERNMENT TAXES ITS PEOPLE TO FINANCE

A Hand Up for Michigan Workers: Michigan s State Earned Income Tax Credit

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Minimum wages and the distribution of family incomes in the United States

Online Appendix What Does Health Reform Mean for the Healthcare Industry? Evidence from the Massachusetts Special Senate Election.

Quarterly Journal of the Business Valuation Committee of the American Society of Appraisers

Pension Simulation Project Rockefeller Institute of Government

Economic and fiscal impacts of the Michigan film tax credit

Empirical Study on Market Value Balance Sheet (MVBS)

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects

2016 Adequacy. Bureau of Legislative Research Policy Analysis & Research Section

2016 Community Reinvestment Report

ADB Economics Working Paper Series. Poverty Impact of the Economic Slowdown in Developing Asia: Some Scenarios

Potential Effects of an Increase in Debit Card Fees

While real incomes in the lower and middle portions of the U.S. income distribution have

Tax Reform and Charitable Giving

The Center for Local, State, and Urban Policy

The Huntington National Bank

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

Cost-Effectiveness of Targeted Reemployment Bonuses

Testimony of Dean Baker. Before the Subcommittee on Housing and Community Opportunity of the House Financial Services Committee

The Employment Impact of a Comprehensive Living Wage Law

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Blue Cross Blue Shield Administrative Costs Accelerate in 2017

Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Transcription:

Final Report on MAPPR Project: The Detroit Living Wage Ordinance: Will it Reduce Urban Poverty? David Neumark May 30, 2001

Detroit s Living Wage Ordinance The Detroit Living Wage Ordinance passed in the fall of 1998. As in other major urban areas passing living wage ordinances in the 1990s, Detroit s ordinance seeks to reduce urban poverty. The ordinance seeks to accomplish this by imposing a substantial minimum wage requirement on any business or other entity that either has a contract to provide services to the city or has a grant from the city for the purpose of economic development or job growth; the value of the contract or grant must exceed $50,000 for the ordinance to be binding. The ordinance s goal of reducing poverty is made explicit in the linkage of its minimum wage requirement to the federal government s definition of poverty. Specifically, for a contractor or grantee that does not provide fully paid, comprehensive family medical coverage, the minimum wage on an annual basis must equal 125 percent of the federal poverty level for a family of four. The requirement falls to 100 percent of the poverty line for contractors or grantees meeting the health insurance requirement. As of March 2000, the required wage was $8.53 with health insurance, and $10.66 without health insurance. Living Wages Nationwide Since December 1994, many cities in the United States have passed living wage ordinances. These ordinances typically mandate that businesses under contract with the city, or in some cases receiving assistance from the city, must pay their workers a wage sufficient to support a family financially. Baltimore was the first city to pass such legislation, and nearly 40 cities and a number of other jurisdictions have followed suit. Like Detroit s, living wage laws have three prominent features. First, all living wage ordinances feature a minimum wage floor that is higher and often much higher than the traditional minimum wages set by state and federal legislation. Second, living wage laws frequently link the wage floor to a poverty threshold, for example requiring a wage that would 1

get a family of four with one full-time worker to the poverty level. Third, coverage by living wage ordinances is far from universal. The most common specification of coverage and also the most narrow is restricted to companies under contract with the city. Some living wage laws also impose the wage on companies receiving business assistance from the city, while the least common feature is for cities to impose the requirement on themselves, covering city employees. Regardless, this narrower coverage contrasts with minimum wage laws, which cover nearly all workers. Thus, living wage laws impose high wage floors, have an anti-poverty objective that is often reflected in the choice of the wage floor, and apply to what may constitute a relatively narrow group of workers. Prior to the research described in this final report, there has been no analysis of the actual effects of living wages on the expected beneficiaries low-wage workers and their families. Given the fact that a large number of cities have passed living wage laws recently, and that campaigns for such laws are under way in many other cities, it is an opportune time to present research analyzing the effects of these laws. Only then can policy-makers, employer organizations, labor unions, and voters make informed judgments regarding the merits of this increasingly popular policy innovation. Research Objectives Resources from the MAPPR were used to support research aiming to present such evidence. Three papers have been written, which together address a broad-ranging set of questions intended to make a significant start on developing a research agenda on living wages. In particular, this research aims to provide evidence relevant to (i) understanding how living wage laws work and how policy analysts can study their impact, (ii) assessing whether living wages achieve their primary policy goal, and (iii) understanding the incentives of actors in the 2

economic and political arena to push for living wage laws. Specifically, the following questions are addressed: Do living wage laws have any teeth, raising wages for at least some low-wage workers? Are living wage laws sufficiently broad and strongly enforced to have effects that can be detected in the data available to policy analysts? Do living wage laws achieve their stated policy objective of improving economic outcomes for low-wage workers and low-income families? Are any wage gains for low-wage workers offset by employment or hours reductions? Do living wage laws reduce urban poverty? Given the stated anti-poverty goal of living wage campaigns, why do the laws frequently narrowly restrict coverage to city contractors, rather than imposing wage floors for broad groups of workers? Do these narrow coverage restrictions help other economic actors in particular unionized municipal workers who stand to gain from living wages? While the Detroit living wage was to some extent the catalyst, the empirical analysis conducted in this research project exploits all of the city-level living wage ordinances in the United States in estimating the effects of these laws, in order to obtain as reliable and precise a set of estimates as possible. However, at the end of this document, some tentative results specific to Detroit and a control sample of Michigan cities is discussed. Principal Research Findings The following principal findings emerge from the empirical analysis of living wage laws in the United States. 3

First, there are sizable positive effects of living wage ordinances on the wages of low-wage workers in the cities in which these ordinances are enacted. At the same time, the magnitudes of the estimated wage effects are larger than would be expected based on the limited coverage of the most common type of living wage laws covering city contractors. It turns out that the large wage effects are driven by cities in which coverage of living wage laws is more broad specifically, cities that also impose living wages on employers receiving business assistance from the city. Thus, existing analyses of the likely effects of living wage laws based on narrow coverage and ignoring business assistance provisions may be quite misleading, and it may be appropriate to think of at least some living wage ordinances in particular those with business assistance provisions as operating considerably more broadly than wage floors imposed on city contractors. Second, while living wage laws raise wages of low-wage workers, they also appear to generate some employment reductions among the affected workers, with the negative employment effects corresponding quite closely to the wage increases. Thus, the positive impact of living wage laws on the wages of low-wage workers is accompanied by disemployment effects among the potentially affected workers, pointing to a trade-off between wages and employment, exactly as economic theory would predict. Third, while economic theory offers some guidance as to the expected trade-offs regarding higher mandated wage floors, it makes no predictions regarding the effects of living wage laws on family incomes or poverty. The impact ultimately depends on the family incomes of those workers who experience wage gains and those individuals who experience reduced employment 4

prospects. The evidence indicates, however, that living wage ordinances result in moderate reductions in the likelihood that urban families live in poverty. Fourth, the evidence is consistent with living wage laws reducing the incentives for cities to contract out work that would otherwise be done by municipal employees, hence increasing the bargaining power of municipal unions and leading to higher wages. As indirect evidence, labor unions especially those representing municipal workers are very active in the movement to pass living wage laws. More directly, the wages of unionized municipal workers are increased as a result of living wages. Evidence that unionized municipal workers gain from living wage laws does not imply that living wages offer no assistance to low-wage workers or low-income families. But that fact that an unintended beneficiary advocating for living wage laws also gains from them raises the possibility that alternative policies intended to achieve the goal of reducing urban poverty may well be more effective. The combined evidence suggests that the cup is either half-full or half-empty, depending on one s point of view. Policy-makers whatever their own view of the merits of living wage laws ought to be encouraged by the findings that living wage laws have their most direct intended consequence raising wages of low-wage workers. Economists will nonetheless find it reassuring that the wage increases engineered by living wage laws result in some trade-offs in the form of lower employment. Advocates of living wages should be pleased by the results indicating that living wage laws reduce urban poverty. And finally skeptics will likely find satisfaction in the evidence that unionized municipal workers reap gains from living wages. Note, however, that none of these conclusions are necessarily in conflict. Living wage laws can in principle engender some employment losses, but coupled with wage increases, and 5

depending on the magnitude and incidence of each of these effects, help the poor. And higherwage unionized municipal workers can gain at the same time that low-income families gain. A cautious reading of the evidence, then, suggests that on net living wages may provide some assistance to the urban poor. But the evidence that other workers who are not the intended beneficiaries also gain emphasizes that there is no basis as yet for concluding that living wages provide the best means of helping the urban poor, and that there is some basis for skepticism regarding this point. Policy-makers contemplating implementing living wage laws, and policy analysts assessing living wage laws, should give full consideration to comparisons among alternative methods of reducing poverty. Limited Results for Detroit As discussed earlier, the empirical analysis exploits all of the city-level living wage ordinances in the United States in estimating the effects of these laws, in order to obtain as reliable and precise a set of estimates as possible. Nonetheless, it is possible to estimate the models reported in the three papers resulting from this research project (cited below) using only cities in Michigan. In this case, the effects of living wages are identified from how changes in Detroit in periods when the living wage increased compare with changes in other Michigan cities (actually, standard metropolitan statistical areas, or SMSAs) in the same period. For example, if poverty in Detroit fell more sharply than elsewhere in Michigan in a period when the living wage was being implemented or increased, the empirical approach would show that the Michigan living wage reduced poverty. However, these estimates must be interpreted very cautiously, and in my view should not be used for the purposes of drawing any firm policy conclusions. Because there is only one city in this Michigan-only sample that imposes a living wage, it is very difficult to sort out the effects of living wages from the effects of other changes over the same period that might have 6

been driving labor market outcomes in Detroit relative to other Michigan cities. In a sense, this is true in the results for the United States as a whole, as well. But because in that analysis there are many cities in the treatment group of those raising living wages, it seems likely that cityspecific changes roughly average out. In contrast, having only one city with a living wage does not permit any averaging across different types of cities to avoid the influence of idiosyncratic factors. With these provisos in mind, Table 1 reports results from an analysis of the effects of living wages on wages of low-wage workers. A similar analysis for the U.S. as a whole appears in the paper Detecting Effects of Living Wage Laws, and that paper provides a full discussion of the equation from which the estimates in Table 1 are derived. Here, the results are simply summarized. The estimates in column (1) indicate that living wages are associated with sharp increases in wages of the lowest-wage workers those whose wages are in the bottom decile of the wage distribution. In contrast, the estimates in the other columns generally indicate little impact of living wages on the wages of higher-wage workers, which is as expected. However, the estimates in column (1) are implausibly large. For example, looking at the effect after 12 months, the estimate of 28.01 implies that a 50-percent increase in the living wage raises wages of low-wage workers by 14 percent. This estimate is roughly four times as big as that obtained using the data for the United States as a whole. At most what one should take away from this table is that the data for Detroit s living wage (compared to the rest of Michigan), like for the United States as a whole, indicate positive effects of living wages on the wages of workers at the bottom of the wage distribution. Table 2 reports estimates of employment effects of living wages. These estimates (and those in Table 3) are the focus of the paper Do Living Ordinances Reduce Urban Poverty? In the data for the U.S. as a whole, the positive wage impact for low-wage workers was offset 7

partially by employment reductions for these same workers. However, as column (1) of Table 2 shows, no disemployment effects appear to flow from the Detroit living wage. Given that the positive wage impact was so large, and that there was a disemployment effect in the data for the United States as a whole, this is difficult to believe, and suggests instead that something other than the living wage is driving the estimated effect of the living wage on wages. One possibility is that economic conditions were improving more rapidly in Detroit than in the rest of Michigan during the sample period. Consistent with this conjecture, between 1996 and 2000, among the cities for which unemployment rates can be calculated, with the exception of Jackson the unemployment rate fell fastest in Detroit. This highlights the inherent problem of inferring the effect of a policy change that occurred in only one location. Finally, Table 3 turns to the impact of the living wage on poverty, measured first in terms of earnings only, and then in terms of total income (as in official poverty classifications). These estimates reveal that living wages decrease the probability that families have earnings below the poverty line, but not the probability that total income is below the poverty line. In contrast, in the data for the United States as a whole, living wages reduce the probability that families are poor, but do not significantly reduce the probability that families have earnings below the poverty line. The paper cited above discusses possible reasons for differential effects on earnings and total income. Nonetheless, the combined evidence tends to suggest that living wages may have some beneficial effects on low-income/poor urban families. 8

Papers Resulting from the Research Three papers have resulted from this research, copies of which are available by contacting David Neumark at neumarkd@msu.edu. The papers are as follows: 1. Detecting Effects of Living Wages, co-authored with Scott Adams (a former Ph.D. student in the Department of Economics at Michigan State), is under review at Industrial Relations. 2. Do Living Wage Ordinances Reduce Urban Poverty?, also co-authored with Scott Adams, is under a second review at Journal of Human Resources. 3. Living Wages: Protection For or Protection From Low-Wage Workers, will be submitted to the Journal of Political Economy early this summer. Presentations Based on the Research Public Policy Institute of California University of California, Berkeley University of Washington University of California, Santa Cruz American Economic Association Annual Meetings, New Orleans 9

Table 1: Contemporaneous and Lagged Effects on Log Wages of Workers in Various Percentile Ranges of the Wage Distributions of SMSAs, Michigan Residents Only Centile: 10 (1) Specification 1: Living wage 14.82 ** (7.32) Effects for different centile ranges 10 25 25 50 (2) (3) 6.30 (4.85) 4.74 (4.81) 50 75 (4) 6.39 (4.46) Specification 2: Living wage 6 months ago 19.11 ** (8.07) 7.92 * (4.80) 9.13 * (5.08) 8.64 * (4.85) Specification 3: Living wage 12 months ago 28.01 ** (10.13) 4.67 (5.85) 3.40 (6.21) 4.31 (5.79) Sample size 1,544 2,028 3,246 3,382 Reported are the estimated effects of minimum wages and living wages effective in an SMSA on the log wages of workers in various percentile ranges of SMSAs. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. Specifications include dummy variables for each month in the sample, so minimum wage effects are not identified. All estimates are multiplied by 100. Thus for these log-log specifications, elasticities are given by the coefficients divided by 100. The sample includes data for each month from 1996-2000. Data from an SMSA is included for a month if there are at least 25 observations. Thus, the sample excludes individuals in small SMSAs and those not living in SMSAs. A total of 7 SMSAs are used in the analysis, including Ann Arbor, Detroit, Flint, Grand Rapids-Muskegon-Holland, Kalamazoo-Battle Creek, Lansing-East Lansing, and Saginaw-Bay City-Midland. Observations for which allocated information is required to construct the wage variable in the CPS are dropped. In all tables reporting regression results, a ** superscript indicates that the estimate is significantly different from zero at the five-percent level, and a * superscript at the ten-percent level. 10

Table 2: Contemporaneous and Lagged Effects on the Probability of Employment in Various Ranges of the Imputed Wage Distributions of SMSAs, Michigan Residents Only Effects for different centile ranges Centile: 10 (1) Specification 1: Living wage 4.29 (5.31) 10 25 (2) 12.86 ** (4.73) 25 50 (3) 7.11 ** (3.19) 50 75 (4) -2.39 (2.95) Specification 2: Living wage 6 months ago 4.04 (5.67) 11.81 ** (5.28) 5.16 (3.36) -1.99 (3.09) Specification 3: Living wage 12 months ago -1.41 (6.37) 18.15 ** (6.11) 4.03 (4.00) -4.03 (3.56) Sample size 3,970 5,633 9,400 9,514 Mean percentage employed 52.67 59.06 66.32 77.93 Reported are the estimated effects of the minimum wage and living wage effective in an SMSA on the employment of individuals in the range of an SMSA s imputed wage distribution specified at the top of each column, using linear probability models. All estimates are multiplied by 100. Because the living wage is expressed in logs, elasticities are given by the coefficient divided by the mean percentage reported in the last row of the corresponding column. See notes to Tables 1 for additional details. In addition to the SMSAs listed in Table 1, in this table data for Jackson are also used. 11

Table 3: Contemporaneous and Lagged Effects on the Probability that Family Earnings or Income Fall Below the Poverty Line, Michigan Residents Only Effects on the probability that families have total earnings below the poverty line Effects on the probability that families have total income below the poverty line (1) (2) (3) (4) Specification 1: Living wage (December of prior year for ADFs) -11.65 ** (3.67) -6.49 (4.01) -2.23 (2.62) -.490 (2.37) Specification 2: Living wage 6 months ago (June of prior year for ADFs) -12.40 ** (4.32) -9.26 ** (4.64) -4.74 (3.32) -3.32 (3.19) Specification 3: Living wage 12 months ago (January of prior year for ADFs) -12.78 ** (4.45) -9.54 ** (4.78) -4.89 (3.42) -3.43 (3.29) Data set ADF ADF ADF ADF Sample restrictions >=25 per cell >=25 per >=25 per >=25 per cell cell cell Years that sample covers 96-99 95-99 96-99 95-99 Number of observations 4,979 6,200 4,979 6,200 Mean percentage below poverty 29.13 29.16 13.60 13.94 Reported are the estimated effects of minimum wages and living wages effective in an SMSA on whether a family s earnings or income are below poverty, using linear probability models. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. All estimates are multiplied by 100. Because the living wage is expressed in logs, elasticities are given by the coefficient divided by the mean percentage reported in the last row of the corresponding column. Given that the ADF surveys are conducted in March and information on family earnings and income refer to the prior calendar year, the applicable contemporaneous and lagged minimum and living wages are noted in parentheses in the left-hand column. The regressions include year dummy variables, so minimum wage effects are not identified. Observations for which allocated information is required to construct the total earnings variable or the total income variable in the CPS are dropped for the relevant analyses. See notes to Tables 1 and 2 for additional details. The same SMSAs used in Table 2 are used in this table. 12