Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma

Similar documents
1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion

Martingales & Strict Local Martingales PDE & Probability Methods INRIA, Sophia-Antipolis

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MAS452/MAS6052. MAS452/MAS Turn Over SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS. Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Option Pricing Models for European Options

FINANCIAL PRICING MODELS

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Theory and practice of option pricing

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Enlargement of filtration

1 Interest Based Instruments

The Black-Scholes Equation

The Mathematics of Currency Hedging

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Hedging under Arbitrage

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Binomial Model for Forward and Futures Options

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Financial Stochastic Calculus E-Book Draft 2 Posted On Actuarial Outpost 10/25/08

Basics of Asset Pricing Theory {Derivatives pricing - Martingales and pricing kernels

King s College London

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Futures Options. The underlying of a futures option is a futures contract.

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Arbeitsgruppe Stochastik. PhD Seminar: HJM Forwards Price Models for Commodities. M.Sc. Brice Hakwa

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

One-Factor Models { 1 Key features of one-factor (equilibrium) models: { All bond prices are a function of a single state variable, the short rate. {

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Financial Risk: Credit Risk, Lecture 2

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

DYNAMIC CDO TERM STRUCTURE MODELLING

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Homework Assignments

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

(c) Consider a standard Black-Scholes market described in detail in

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Fractional Brownian Motion as a Model in Finance

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

The Black-Scholes Model

A new approach for scenario generation in risk management

Transcription:

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma 1 The Sharpe Ratio 2 The Risk-Neutral Process

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma 1 The Sharpe Ratio 2 The Risk-Neutral Process

The Sharpe Ratio Consider a portfolio of assets indexed by i. If asset i has expected return α i, the risk premium is defined as where r denotes the risk-free rate. The Sharpe ratio is defined as RiskPremium i = α i r SharpeRatio i = RiskPremium i σ i = α i r σ i, where σ i stands for the volatility of the asset i We can use the Sharpe ratio to compare two perfectly correlated claims, such as a derivative and its underlying asset Two assets that are perfectly correlated must have the same Sharpe ratio, or else there will be an arbitrage opportunity

The Sharpe Ratio Consider a portfolio of assets indexed by i. If asset i has expected return α i, the risk premium is defined as where r denotes the risk-free rate. The Sharpe ratio is defined as RiskPremium i = α i r SharpeRatio i = RiskPremium i σ i = α i r σ i, where σ i stands for the volatility of the asset i We can use the Sharpe ratio to compare two perfectly correlated claims, such as a derivative and its underlying asset Two assets that are perfectly correlated must have the same Sharpe ratio, or else there will be an arbitrage opportunity

The Sharpe Ratio Consider a portfolio of assets indexed by i. If asset i has expected return α i, the risk premium is defined as where r denotes the risk-free rate. The Sharpe ratio is defined as RiskPremium i = α i r SharpeRatio i = RiskPremium i σ i = α i r σ i, where σ i stands for the volatility of the asset i We can use the Sharpe ratio to compare two perfectly correlated claims, such as a derivative and its underlying asset Two assets that are perfectly correlated must have the same Sharpe ratio, or else there will be an arbitrage opportunity

The Sharpe Ratio Consider a portfolio of assets indexed by i. If asset i has expected return α i, the risk premium is defined as where r denotes the risk-free rate. The Sharpe ratio is defined as RiskPremium i = α i r SharpeRatio i = RiskPremium i σ i = α i r σ i, where σ i stands for the volatility of the asset i We can use the Sharpe ratio to compare two perfectly correlated claims, such as a derivative and its underlying asset Two assets that are perfectly correlated must have the same Sharpe ratio, or else there will be an arbitrage opportunity

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty Consider two nondividend-paying stocks modeled as ds t = α 1 S t dt + S dz t d S t = α 2 St dt + σ 2 St dz t where Z is a standard Brownian motion The stock price processes S and S are perfectly correlated since they have the same driving Brownian motion Let us suppose that they have different Sharpe ratios and demostrate that there is arbitrage opportunity in the market

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty Consider two nondividend-paying stocks modeled as ds t = α 1 S t dt + S dz t d S t = α 2 St dt + σ 2 St dz t where Z is a standard Brownian motion The stock price processes S and S are perfectly correlated since they have the same driving Brownian motion Let us suppose that they have different Sharpe ratios and demostrate that there is arbitrage opportunity in the market

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty Consider two nondividend-paying stocks modeled as ds t = α 1 S t dt + S dz t d S t = α 2 St dt + σ 2 St dz t where Z is a standard Brownian motion The stock price processes S and S are perfectly correlated since they have the same driving Brownian motion Let us suppose that they have different Sharpe ratios and demostrate that there is arbitrage opportunity in the market

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty (cont d) Without loss of generality assume that α 1 r > α 2 r σ 2 Buy 1/S shares of asset S Short-sell 1/ Sσ 2 shares of asset S Invest/borrow the risk-free bond in the amount of the cost difference 1 1 σ 2 The return of the above strategy is 1 S ds 1 σ ds 2 + ( 1 1 ) dt = 2 S σ 2 ( α1 r α ) 2 r dt > 0 σ 2

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty (cont d) Without loss of generality assume that α 1 r > α 2 r σ 2 Buy 1/S shares of asset S Short-sell 1/ Sσ 2 shares of asset S Invest/borrow the risk-free bond in the amount of the cost difference 1 1 σ 2 The return of the above strategy is 1 S ds 1 σ ds 2 + ( 1 1 ) dt = 2 S σ 2 ( α1 r α ) 2 r dt > 0 σ 2

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty (cont d) Without loss of generality assume that α 1 r > α 2 r σ 2 Buy 1/S shares of asset S Short-sell 1/ Sσ 2 shares of asset S Invest/borrow the risk-free bond in the amount of the cost difference 1 1 σ 2 The return of the above strategy is 1 S ds 1 σ ds 2 + ( 1 1 ) dt = 2 S σ 2 ( α1 r α ) 2 r dt > 0 σ 2

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty (cont d) Without loss of generality assume that α 1 r > α 2 r σ 2 Buy 1/S shares of asset S Short-sell 1/ Sσ 2 shares of asset S Invest/borrow the risk-free bond in the amount of the cost difference 1 1 σ 2 The return of the above strategy is 1 S ds 1 σ ds 2 + ( 1 1 ) dt = 2 S σ 2 ( α1 r α ) 2 r dt > 0 σ 2

The Sharpe Ratio: Two stocks with the same source of uncertainty (cont d) Without loss of generality assume that α 1 r > α 2 r σ 2 Buy 1/S shares of asset S Short-sell 1/ Sσ 2 shares of asset S Invest/borrow the risk-free bond in the amount of the cost difference 1 1 σ 2 The return of the above strategy is 1 S ds 1 σ ds 2 + ( 1 1 ) dt = 2 S σ 2 ( α1 r α ) 2 r dt > 0 σ 2

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma 1 The Sharpe Ratio 2 The Risk-Neutral Process

The True Price Process The model ds t = S t [(α δ) dt + σ dz t ] where δ denotes the dividend yield on S The drift contains the average appreciation of the stock The uncertainty is driven by the stochastic process Z To facilitate calculations (recall the binomial model!) we look at the process S under a new probability measure which renders the price process to be a martingale. This is different from the physical measure - whatever that may be...

The True Price Process The model ds t = S t [(α δ) dt + σ dz t ] where δ denotes the dividend yield on S The drift contains the average appreciation of the stock The uncertainty is driven by the stochastic process Z To facilitate calculations (recall the binomial model!) we look at the process S under a new probability measure which renders the price process to be a martingale. This is different from the physical measure - whatever that may be...

The True Price Process The model ds t = S t [(α δ) dt + σ dz t ] where δ denotes the dividend yield on S The drift contains the average appreciation of the stock The uncertainty is driven by the stochastic process Z To facilitate calculations (recall the binomial model!) we look at the process S under a new probability measure which renders the price process to be a martingale. This is different from the physical measure - whatever that may be...

The True Price Process The model ds t = S t [(α δ) dt + σ dz t ] where δ denotes the dividend yield on S The drift contains the average appreciation of the stock The uncertainty is driven by the stochastic process Z To facilitate calculations (recall the binomial model!) we look at the process S under a new probability measure which renders the price process to be a martingale. This is different from the physical measure - whatever that may be...

The True Price Process The model ds t = S t [(α δ) dt + σ dz t ] where δ denotes the dividend yield on S The drift contains the average appreciation of the stock The uncertainty is driven by the stochastic process Z To facilitate calculations (recall the binomial model!) we look at the process S under a new probability measure which renders the price process to be a martingale. This is different from the physical measure - whatever that may be...

The Risk-Neutral Measure Under the risk-neutral measure P the SDE for the stock-price reads as ds t = S t [(r δ) dt + σ d Z t ] with Z a standard Brownian motion under P Note that the volatility is not altered

The Risk-Neutral Measure Under the risk-neutral measure P the SDE for the stock-price reads as ds t = S t [(r δ) dt + σ d Z t ] with Z a standard Brownian motion under P Note that the volatility is not altered