Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Similar documents
Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

International Joint Venture under Asymmetric Information: Technology vis-à-vis Information Advantage

research paper series

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Competition for Foreign Direct Investment: the Role of Technology and Market Structure

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Structure and Privatization Policy under International Competition

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. International Trade, Crowding Out, and Market Structure: Cournot Approach. James P.

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment in. Mixed Oligopolies

A new model of mergers and innovation

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Technology cooperation between firms of developed and less-developed countries

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Small countries have a low corporate tax rate

Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

FTA Negotiations with Side Payments: Asymmetric Countries and Asymmetric. Information

International Rent-shifting under Foreign Entry. through R&D and Licensing

Strategic export policy, monopoly carrier, and product differentiation

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Endogenous FDI Spillovers: Do You Want to Keep Your Recipe to Yourself?

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

Modes of Exports by Sub-Saharan African Firms: Intensive Margins and Interdependencies

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment *

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Export performance requirements under international duopoly*

It Takes a Village - Network Effect of Child-rearing

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector

Endogenous Product Differentiation and International Competition

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Tax Competition with Asymmetric Market Structures: The Role of Policy Instruments

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Overview Basic analysis Strategic trade policy Further topics. Overview

The Nightmare of the Leader: The Impact of Deregulation on an Oligopoly Insurance Market

Profitable Mergers. in Cournot and Stackelberg Markets:

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

Organizational Structure and the Choice of Price vs. Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem

General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing innovation

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Taxes or Subsidies in Self-financing Environmental Mechanisms?

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies

Subsidizing Non-Polluting Goods vs. Taxing Polluting Goods for Pollution Reduction

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

An Oligopolistic Heckscher-Ohlin Model of Foreign Direct Investment

Cost Heterogeneity and the Destination of Foreign Direct Investment

Transcription:

Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Discussion Papers Department of Economics 7-2007 Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures Litao Zhong St Charles Community College Sajal Lahiri Southern Illinois University Carbondale Follow this and additional works at: http://opensiuc.lib.siu.edu/econ_dp Recommended Citation Zhong, Litao and Lahiri, Sajal, "Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures" (2007). Discussion Papers. Paper 69. http://opensiuc.lib.siu.edu/econ_dp/69 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Department of Economics at OpenSIUC. It has been accepted for inclusion in Discussion Papers by an authorized administrator of OpenSIUC. For more information, please contact opensiuc@lib.siu.edu.

July 13, 2007 Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures By Litao Zhong a and Sajal Lahiri b ABSTRACT This paper suggests a new approach to the determination of profit allocation between the partners in joint ventures. We also examine the issue of partnership choice. The foreign firm would be willing to give more than half of profits to its partner, and it would like to choose the more efficient firm. However, the host government, under certain situation, may persuade the foreign firm, by a suitable lump-sum transfer, to form partnership with the less efficient firm. JEL Classifications: F1, F2 Keywords: Joint ventures, profit sharing, partner choice, oligopoly, technology transfer. a Division of Business and Social Sciences, St. Charles Community College, St. Peters, MO. 63376, U.S.A.; E-mail: ltzhong@gmail.com b Department of Economics, Southern Illinois University Carbondale, Carbondale, IL 62901, U.S.A.; Email: lahiri@siu.edu

1 Introduction The importance of international joint venture (IJV) as a mode for entering a foreign market cannot be understated. For example, more than a third of foreign investment China now takes the form of IJV (Folta, 2005). The high incidence of IJVs is also reflected in a large number of academic papers on IJVs (see, for example, Al-Saadon and Das, 1996; Asiedu and Esfahani, 2001; Darrough and Stoughton, 1989; Harrigan, 1984; Svejnar and Smith, 1984). The existing literature considers many issues, but not that of partner choice. This paper contributes to the emerging literature by first developing a theoretical model in which the foreign firm makes an attractive offer to a potential partner which has no bargaining power, and this way extracts a favorable tax/subsidy outcome from the host government. We then consider the issue of the formation of partnership when there are more than one potential partners. We find that, depending on the degree of technology transfer in an IJV, the equilibrium partnership could be with either with the more efficient or the less efficient domestic firm. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops the theoretical framework. Section 3 examines the multinational firm s partner choice. Concluding remarks are made in section 4. 2 The Model A multinational corporation, labelled firm F, with constant unit or marginal cost c F, wishes to enter a country s market via forming a joint venture (IJV) with one of two local firms with marginal costs c A and c B. We assume that c F < c A < c B, i.e., firm F is more efficient than firm A which in turn is more efficient than firm B. The host government uses the tax/subsidy policy to influence the nature of IJV. The foreign firm offers a contract in the form of a share of profits to one domestic firm. That firm can only take or leave that offer. The model is formulated in terms of a three-stage game. We first specify the the model assuming that the IJV takes place first with firm A. The analysis will be analogous if the IJV is with firm B. In stage one, firm F decides the optimal profit share it offers to a domestic firm 1

by maximizing its share of profits, without any bargaining and tries to maximize its own profit. In stage two, the host government decides on the level of output tax/subsidy. Finally, in the third stage a Cournot oligopoly game is played between the IJV and the other domestic firm for deciding output levels. The model is solved with backward induction to achieve a sub-game perfect equilibrium. We assume that the marginal cost of the IJV is a convex combination of the two partner firms. That is, c J1 = θc A + (1 θ)c F, 0 θ 1, (1) where the subscript 1 refers to case 1 (partnership with firm A) and 1 θ represents the degree of technology transfer in the IJV from firm F. Assuming that the two firms produce a homogeneous good, the demand function is D 1 = α βp 1, (2) D 1 and P 1 are respectively total demand and price of the good respectively. The market-clearing condition is D 1 = q J1 + q B, (3) where q J1 is the output of the IJV and q B is the output of firm B. From equations (2) and (3), the inverse demand function is obtained as P = a b(q J1 + q B ), (4) where a = α/β, and b = 1/β. Starting with stage 3 of the game, the problems facing the IJV and firm B are given by max q J1 π J1 = (P c J1 t 1 )q J1, max q B π B = (P c B )q B, where t 1 denotes the rate of output tax imposed by the host government on the IJV. 2

From the first order conditions of the above probles are q J1 = (a 2t 1 2θc A 2c F + 2c F θ + c B )/(3b), q B = (a + t 1 + θc A + c F θc F 2c B )/(3b). (5) In stage 2, the host government sets the optimal tax to maximize the national welfare, taking into account output response functions in (5): max t 1 W 1 = s 1 π J1 + π B + t 1 q J1 + CS 1, where s 1 is the share of firm A in the IJV profits. The first and the second terms are profits of firm A and firm B respectively, the third term is tax revenue, and the last term is consumers surplus. The solution of the above problem yields t 1 = (3a 3c A θ 3c F + 3c F θ 4s 1 a 4s 1 c B + 8s 1 c A θ + 8s 1 c F 8s 1 c F θ)/(9 8s 1 ), (6) whence we find the relationship between the tax rate and the profit-share parameter s 1 : dt 1 /ds 1 = 12(a + 3c B 4c A θ 4c F + 4c F θ)/(9 8s 1 ) 2 < 0. (7) That is, if firm F gives a larger share of IJV profits to its domestic partner, the government lowers the tax rate. Finally, in stage 1 firm F decides on s 1 by maximizing its share of profits: max s 1 π F 1 = (1 s 1 )π J1, (8) taking into account reaction functions from stages 2 and 3, and this gives s 1 = 7/8. Substituting this solution into (5) and (6), we get t 1 = (8θc A + 8c F a 8c F θ 7c B )/4 = ( 2bq J1 4(c B c J1 ))/4 < 0, (9) q J1 = (a 4θc A 4c F + 4c F θ + 3c B )/(2b), q B = (a + 4θc A + 4c F 4c F θ 5c B )/(4b).(10) 3

The analysis is similar to the case where firm F picks firm B as the partner. The marginal cost of the IJV is then: c J2 = θc B + (1 θ)c F, 0 θ 1; and solution of all the variables can be analogously solved as: s 2 = 7/8, t 2 = (8θc B + 8c F a 8c F θ 7c A )/4 = ( 2bq J2 4(c A c J2 ))/4 < 0, (11) q J2 = (a 4θc B 4c F + 4c F θ + 3c A )/(2b), q A = (a + 4θc B + 4c F 4c F θ 5c A )/(4b).(12) Three interesting points need to be noted. First, no matter whether firm F chooses firm A or firm B, it offers the same share to the domestic partner. Second, the optimal share offered is larger than 50%. This result is interesting since the domestic firm has no bargaining power. The foreign firm knows that by committing a higher profit share to the domestic partner, it can induce the host government to impose a lower tax on the IJV. Finally, the optimal policy for the host government is to subsidize the IJV no matter which firm the IJV is formed with. The presence of endogenous profit share makes the sign of the optimal tax is negative since by doing so the government can induce the foreign firm to pass on a larger share of IJV profits to the domestic partner. We conclude this section by showing that the host government offer a higher subsidy if IJV is formed with the more efficient firm. Formally, Lemma 1 The host government offers a better tax/subsidy to the IJV when Firm F chooses the more efficient firm as a partner. Proof: From (9) and (11) we get t 1 t 2 = (c A c B )(7 + 8θ)/4. Thus, c B > c A t 1 < t 2. The intuition behinds this proposition is that the consumers enjoy a higher surplus if the IJV is formed with the more efficient firm. 3 Partner Choice In this section, we want to address the following questions: Which of the two firms would the foreign firm like to choose as a partner? Will the chosen domestic firm accept the offer? Which of 4

the two firms does the host government prefer the foreign firm to choose as a partner? The answer to the first question is given in the following proposition. Proposition 1 The foreign firm prefers to the more efficient domestic firm as its partner in the IJV. Proof: π F 1 π F 2 = (1 s 1 )π J1 (1 s 2 )π J2 = b(q 2 J1 q 2 J2)/8, where from (10) and (12) we have q J1 q J2 = (4θ + 3)(c B c A )/(2b). Thus, π F 1 > π F 2 c B > c A. The foreign firms prefers the more efficient firm to be its partner mainly for two reasons. First, this way the IJV will be more efficient and therefore make more profits, and second it will extract a higher subsidy from the host government (lemma 1). We shall now show that the domestic firms are always willing to join the IJV. Formally, Proposition 2 Both domestic firms would like to join the IJV. Proof: The difference in profits for firm A in the two scenarios is s 1 π J1 π A = b((7/8)qj1 2 bq2 A ), and since (7/8) q J1 q A > (3/4) q J1 q A and (3/4)q J1 q A = (a 12θc A 20c F + 20c F θ + 9c B 8θc B + 10c A )/(8b) = f(θ) (say),the proposition is proved if we can show that f(θ) is always positive. In fact, 8b f (θ) = 12(c F c A ) + 8(c F c B ) < 0 and 8b f(1) = 2bq J1 θ=1 + 2(c A c B ) = 2bq J2 θ=1 + 5(c B c A ) > 0, irrespective of the relative efficiencies of firms A and B. Thus, for all values of θ such that 0 θ 1, we have f(θ) > 0. Finally, how can the host government influence the nature of the IJV? This is the question that we now turn to. For this, we first define the host country welfare levels W 1 and W 2, and global welfares GW 1 and GW 2, under the two scenarios. Now, we compare the welfare levels of the country under the two scenarios, i.e., when the partnership is formed with firm A and firm 5

B respectively. These two welfare levels are given by: W 1 = s 1 π J1 + π B + t 1 q J1 + CS 1, W 2 = s 2 π J2 + π A + t 2 q J2 + CS 2, GW 1 = π J1 + π B + t 1 q J1 + CS 1, GW 2 = π J2 + π A + t 2 q J2 + CS 2, where CS i is the consumers surplus in scenario i (i = 1, 2). From the above, we derive: 16b(W 1 W 2 ) = (c B c A )((15 16θ 2 )(c A + c B ) + 32θ 2 c F + 8θ(a c F ) 6a 24c F ), 32b(GW 1 GW 2 ) = 3(c B c A )((13 16θ 2 )(c A + c B ) + 32θ 2 c F + 8θ(a c F ) 2a 24c F ), GW 1 GW 2 = 3(W 1 W 2 )/2 + 3(c B c A )(2a c B c A )/(16b). (13) From the first two equations it can be that W 1 > W 2 θ > θ = a c F K 4(c A + c B 2c F ), GW 1 > GW 2 θ > θ = a c F K + 2(c A + c B 2c F )(2a c A c B ), 4(c A + c B 2c F ) where K = 49c 2 F + 10ac F + a 2 + 15(c 2 A + c2 B ) 6a(c A + c B ) + 30c A c B 54c F (c A + c B ). Clearly, θ < θ. The reason why the host government may prefer the IJV partnership to be formed with the less efficient firm when θ is sufficiently low is that in this case the technology transfer is high and the average efficiency level of the industry (and thus the consumers surplus) will be higher if the foreign firm forms a partnership with the less efficient firm than with the more efficient one. We can now consider three cases. First, when θ > θ both the foreign firm and the host government will prefer an IJV with the more efficient firm, and the latter is happy to join in. Second, when θ < θ < θ, the host government would prefer the partnership to be with the less efficient firm where as the foreign firm prefers the more efficient one. However, since GW 1 > GW 2 in this case, the foreign firm would be able to make a lump-sum payment to the host government so that both parties are happy with a partnership with the more efficient firm. Finally, when θ < θ, the host government and the foreign firm will have opposite interests as above, but since 6

GW 2 > GW 1 in this case, the host government would be able to make a lump-sum payment to the foreign firm so that both parties are happy with a partnership with the less efficient firm. Formally, Proposition 3 (i)if θ > θ, the MNC will form an IJV with the more efficient domestic firm,and the host government is happy with the outcome, (ii)if θ < θ < θ, the MNC can form an IJV with the more efficient domestic firm by making a lump-sum transfer to the host government, and (iii)if θ < θ, the host government can induce the MNC to form an IJV with the less efficient domestic firm by making a lump-sum transfer to the MNC. 4 Conclusion In this paper, we develop a three-stage game to analyze how an IJV allocates profits between the partners. However, the MNC has a choice between forming an IJV partnership with one of two cost-asymmetric firms. The foreign firm takes the leadership of the IJV and is solely responsible for deciding the optimal profit share. However, the domestic partner receives more than 50% share of profits from the IJV. This is because the host government offers a subsidy to the IJV and this subsidy can be affected by the foreign firm by manipulating the sharing of profits. We show that the foreign firm always prefers the more efficient domestic firm as a partner. However, the host government may prefer the partnership to be with the less efficient firm when the level of technology transfer in the IJV is sufficiently high. In the latter case, by allowing for lump-sum transfer, we characterize two situations when the partnership will be with the more and the less efficient firm respectively, in a mutually beneficial manner. 7

References [1] Al-Saadon, Y. and S. Das, 1996, Host-country Policy, Transfer Pricing and Ownership Distribution in International Joint Ventures: A Theoretical Analysis, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14, 345-364. [2] Asiedu, E. and H.S. Esfahani, 2001, Ownership Structure in Foreign Direct Investment Projects, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 83, 647-662. [3] Darrough, M.N. and N.M. Stoughton, 1989, A bargaining approach to profit sharing in joint ventures, Journal of Business, 62, 237-270. [4] Folta, P., 2005, Cooperative Joint Ventures, The China Business Review Online, Jan-Feb 2005. [5] Harrigan, K.R.,1984, Joint ventures and global strategies, Columbia Journal of World Business, 19, 7-16. [6] Svejnar, J. and S. Smith, 1984, The Economics of Joint Ventures in Less Developed Countries, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99, 149-167. 8