Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Similar documents
Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2014 Answer any 7 of these 8 questions Good luck!

PhD Qualifier Examination

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Choice under risk and uncertainty

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

EconS Micro Theory I Recitation #8b - Uncertainty II

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Final Exam Economic 210A, Fall 2009 Answer any 7 questions.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

ABattleofInformedTradersandtheMarket Game Foundations for Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Intro to Economic analysis

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Buying and Selling. Chapter Nine. Endowments. Buying and Selling. Buying and Selling

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Solutions to Assignment #2

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

The Robinson Crusoe model; the Edgeworth Box in Consumption and Factor allocation

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Econ 210, Final, Fall 2015.

Expected Utility And Risk Aversion

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

ECON Micro Foundations

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

ECON 311 Fall Quarter, 2009 NAME: Prof. Hamilton. FINAL EXAM 200 points

Mean-Variance Analysis

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

Advanced Microeconomic Theory

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

ECON 200 EXERCISES. (b) Appeal to any propositions you wish to confirm that the production set is convex.

3 General Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I. In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations!

Portfolio Selection with Quadratic Utility Revisited

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Answer Key to Midterm Exam. February

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

ECON 5113 Microeconomic Theory

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

ECON Financial Economics

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Mock Examination 2010

Lecture 6 Introduction to Utility Theory under Certainty and Uncertainty

ECON 310 Fall 2005 Final Exam - Version A. Multiple Choice: (circle the letter of the best response; 3 points each) and x

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 28 February 2008.

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Midterm 1 (A) U(x 1, x 2 ) = (x 1 ) 4 (x 2 ) 2

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Question 1: (60 points)

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Reuben Gronau s Model of Time Allocation and Home Production

Game theory and applications: Lecture 1

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

File: Ch03; Chapter 3: The Standard Theory of International Trade

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

Solutions to Problem Set 1

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax

Lecture Notes 1

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

Econ 210, Final, Fall 2015.

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Attitudes Toward Risk. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/16. (Lecture 11, Micro Theory I)

Transcription:

Prof. Peck Fall 016 Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 871 1. (35 points) The following economy has one consumer, two firms, and four goods. Goods 1 and are consumption goods, good 3 is capital, and good 4 is labor. The consumer is endowed with one unit of capital and one unit of labor, =(0011), and only receives utility from consumption of goods 1 and. Thus, capital and labor will be inelastically supplied to the market. The consumer s utility function is given by ( 1 )=4log( 1 )+log( ) The consumer owns both firms. Firm 1 produces good 1 using capital and labor as inputs. For convenience, denote the (nonnegative) capital input used by firm 1 as 1 and the (nonnegative) labor input used by firm 1 as 1. Firm 1 s production function (the boundary of the production set) is given by: 1 1 = ( 1 1 ) 1 where 1 0 and 1 0 Firm produces good using capital and labor as inputs. For convenience, denote the (nonnegative) capital input used by firm as and the (nonnegative) labor input used by firm as. Firm s production function (the boundary of the production set) is given by: = ( ) 1 where 0 and 0 (a) (10 points) Define a competitive equilibrium for this economy. (b) (5 points) Compute the competitive equilibrium price vector and allocation. Answer: (a) A CE is a price vector, ( 1 3 4 ) andanallocation,( 1 3 4 ) and ( 1 1 1 1 ), such that (i) ( 1 3 4 ) solves max 4 log( 1 )+log( ) 1 1 + + 3 3 + 4 4 3 + 4 + 1 + 0 1

(ii) 1 1 1 1 solves (iii) solves (iv) markets clear: max 1 1 1 3 1 4 1 1 1 ( 1 1 ) 1 1 0 and 1 0 max 3 4 ( ) 1 0 and 0 1 1 1 3 + 1 + 1 4 + 1 + 1 (b) First, we know that any CE will have budget, technology, and market clearing inequalities hold as equalities, and we will have 3 = 4 =0.Also,we know that both firms must be producing in equilibrium, in order to avoid utility of negative infinity. We will normalize 4 =1. Firm 1 profit maximization implies the marginal rate of technical substitution condition, 1 = 3 1 (1) Substituting the production function into the profit expression yields 1 ( 1 1 ) 1 3 1 1 From (1), the profit expression becomes 1 ( 1 3 1 ) 1 3 1 3 1,or [ 1 ( 3 ) 1 3 ] 1 which requires (this is due to constant returns to scale) the term in brackets to be zero, or 1 = p 3 () Similarly, firm profit maximization implies the marginal rate of technical substitution condition, = 3 (3)

Substituting the production function into the profit expression yields ( ) 1 3 From (3), the profit expression becomes ( 3 ) 1 3 3,or [ ( 3 ) 1 3 ] which requires (this is due to constant returns to scale) the term in brackets to be zero, or = p 3 (4) Solving the utility maximization problem yields the marginal rate of substitution condition, 4 1 = 1 which, along with the budget equation (imposing zero profit income), allows us to solve for the demand functions, 1 = 4(3 +1) 5 1 = (3 +1) 5 Substituting (1) and (3) into the market clearing condition for good 4 yields 1= 1 + = 3 1 + 3 = 3 ( 1 + ) (5) Market clearing for good 3 requires 1 + =1, which when substituted into (5) implies 3 =1. By () and (4), it follows that 1 = =holds, so we have all the prices. From the demand functions, we have =( 4 5 1 5 0 0). Market clearing for goods 1 and requires 1 1 = 4 5 and = 1 5. Using the production function and the mrts conditions, we have 1 = 1 = 4 5 and = = 1 5. 3

. (30 points) The following pure-exchange Arrow Securities economy has 1 consumers, 1 states of nature, and 1 physical commodities per state of nature. Assume that endowments are strictly interior, and that each consumer is a von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility maximizer with Bernoulli utility function that is strictly concave, continuous, and strictly monotonic. Consider arbitrary prices, { ()}. Note: these prices might not be equilibrium prices. For =1, let the security holdings { }, and consumption ()} solve the utility maximization problem { max () X 0 X ( ()) X () () X () ()+ for all () 0 For the following two statements, either prove the statement (if the statement is true) or find a counterexample (if the statement is false). Statement 1 (15 points): For all =1, wehave X X () () = X X () () Statement (15 points): If we have X X () () = X X () () for all =1, then{ ()} are competitive equilibrium prices. Answer: Statement 1 is false. Intuitively, the equation cannot hold if prices are such that all consumers want to transfer income into the same state. The easiest counterexample is for =1, =1,and =. Let the Bernoulli utility function be () =log(), andsuppose() =1and = 1 for =1. Set 4

(1) = () = =1. If 1 =1holds, then the equation in the statement is satisfied, but for any other 1, it will not be satisfied. Suppose 1 =holds. It is easy to compute (I leave the details to you) that (1) 1 and () 1 hold, so the equation does not hold for either state. Statement is false. Intuitively, the equation implies that the security market clears, but there is no reason that the spot market must clear when we have 1. The simplest counterexample is for =1, =,and =1. Let the utility function be ( 1 )=log( 1 )+log( ), and suppose =1 for =1. Since there is only one state, we must have =0,sothespot market constraint, which must hold with equality at a maximum due to strict monotonicity, is X X = This is exactly the equation in the statement, so we know it must hold for any prices. We will now find prices that are not equilibrium prices, establishing the counterexample. It is easy to see that when we have 1 = =1,the consumer will demand exactly his endowment, so we have a CE at those prices (the security price does not matter, since there is only one state). Any other relative price is inconsistent with equilibrium. For example, set 1 =and = =1. It is easy to compute (I leave the details to you) that 1 holds, so there is excess demand for good. 5

3. (35 points) In the following Rothschild-Stiglitz model, there is one consumer, who has initial wealth of and a potential accident with damages of, so the statecontingent initial endowment is ( 0). The consumer has a von Neumann- Morgenstern utility function with a "Bernoulli" utility of certain consumption given by ( )=log(). The consumer knows her risk type, but the competing insurance firms believe that she is high risk with probability 1 and low risk with probability 1. A high risk type has an accident probability, = 1,andalow risk type has an accident probability, = 1 3. (a) (0 points) Compute the "candidate" separating equilibrium. Now suppose instead that the consumer (call her consumer 1) can trade on a contingent commodities market before she learns her risk type or whether she will have an accident. In place of the competing insurance companies, suppose there is a single risk-neutral consumer (call him consumer ) with an endowment of in all states. (b) (15 points) Compute the competitive equilibrium price vector and allocation. Answer: (a) The R-S model applies to the case of one consumer with unknown type just as well as it does to the case of a population of consumers. The contract offered to the high risk type is at the intersection of the fair odds line and the 45 degree line. The fair odds line for the high risk type has slope 1, sothe contract is =(1 )=(11). The contract offered to the low risk type is at the intersection of the type-h indifference curve through (1 1) and the fair odds line for the low risk type. The equation of the indifference curve is 1 log( 1)+ 1 log( ) = 1 log(1) + 1 log(1), or 1 = 1 The equation of the fair odds line is 3 1 + 1 3 =, or 3 1 + = 4 Substitution yields the equation ( 1 ) 4 1 +1=0 with solutions, 1 =1± 6

Since the correct root is the one below the 45 degree line, we have the contract =(1+ ). (b) It is an interesting philosophical question, whether there are states (no accident or accident) or 4 states (no accident-h, no accident-l, accident-h, or accident-l). Does it matter that consumer 1 will learn something after the trading occurs but before delivery? In either case, consumer is risk neutral with enough of an endowment to fully insure consumer 1, so the CE prices will be proportional to the probabilities and consumer 1 will consume the same in each state. Basically, the slope of consumer s linear indifference curves determines prices, and consumer 1 faces fair odds before she learns anything about the state. In the two state case, the probability of an accident is 1 1 + 1 1 3 = 5 1 Letting state 1 be the no-accident state, the CE price vector is ( 7 1 5 1 ).Consumer 1 s constant consumption equals her expected endowment income, which is 7 1 = 7 6. Therefore, the CE allocation is 1 =( 7 6 7 6 ) and =( 17 6 5 6 ) If you set it up with 4 states, the probabilities are ( 1 4 1 3 1 4 1 6 ),sothisisthe CE price vector. The CE allocation is 1 =( 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 ) and =( 17 6 17 6 5 6 5 6 ) 7