WACC is not the correct discount rate for general asset cash flows

Similar documents
The Scope of Validity of Modigliani and Miller Propositions

DIVIDEND CONTROVERSY: A THEORETICAL APPROACH

Using Microsoft Corporation to Demonstrate the Optimal Capital Structure Trade-off Theory

Advanced Corporate Finance. 3. Capital structure

Advanced Corporate Finance. 3. Capital structure

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 13 Number 1 Spring 2000 CAPITAL BUDGETING ANALYSIS IN WHOLLY OWNED SUBSIDIARIES

Market Value of the Firm, Market Value of Equity, Return Rate on Capital and the Optimal Capital Structure

Are Capital Structure Decisions Relevant?

PAPER No.: 8 Financial Management MODULE No. : 25 Capital Structure Theories IV: MM Hypothesis with Taxes, Merton Miller Argument

Inflation in Brusov Filatova Orekhova Theory and in its Perpetuity Limit Modigliani Miller Theory

SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Kogan and Wang E and 614 Summer 2017

Journal of Business Case Studies September/October 2011 Volume 7, Number 5

FINANCE 402 Capital Budgeting and Corporate Objectives. Syllabus

Financial Management Bachelors of Business Administration Study Notes & Tutorial Questions Chapter 3: Capital Structure

5. Equity Valuation and the Cost of Capital

CHAPTER 14. Capital Structure in a Perfect Market. Chapter Synopsis

Jeffrey F. Jaffe Spring Semester 2011 Corporate Finance FNCE 100 Syllabus, page 1 of 8

Optimal Capital Structure

Jeffrey F. Jaffe Spring Semester 2015 Corporate Finance FNCE 100 Syllabus, page 1. Spring 2015 Corporate Finance FNCE 100 Wharton School of Business

Corporate Finance Theory FRL CRN: P. Sarmas Summer Quarter 2014 Building 163 Room 2032 Monday and Wednesday: 8:00 a.m. 9:50 a.m.

UNIVERSIDAD CARLOS III DE MADRID FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Corporate Finance (Honors) Finance 100 Sections 301 and 302 The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Fall 2010

Corporate Finance Theory FRL CRN: P. Sarmas Summer Quarter 2012 Building 24B Room 1417 Tuesday & Thursday: 4:00 5:50 p.m.

European Edition. Peter Moles, Robert Parrino and David Kidwell. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd, Publication

AFM 371 Winter 2008 Chapter 16 - Capital Structure: Basic Concepts

Corporate Finance.

Page 515 Summary and Conclusions

Department of Management Sciences

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

The influence of capital structure on the value of the firm. A study of European firms. Aleksandr Klimenok Spring 2014

Review and Comments on Accrual Accounting Valuation Models

Corporate Finance (Honors) Finance 100 Sections 301 and 302 The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Fall 2014

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles

Financial reporting and analysis

THE DETERMINANT OF A FIRM OPTIMUM CAPITAL STRUCTURE: CONCEPTUAL AND THEORETICAL OVERVIEW. Ajao, Mayowa Gabriel

Stock price analysis of sustainable foreign investment companies in Indonesia

A Study on Cost of Capital

A PUZZLE FOR TEACHING THE CONSTANT GROWTH STOCK PRICING MODEL Lynda S. Livingston, University of Puget Sound

Al al- Bayt University. Course Syllabus Financial Management (3.0 cr ) 2015

Book Review of The Theory of Corporate Finance

Capital structure I: Basic Concepts

The Capitalization Rate of Commercial Properties and Market Returns

Laudation for the DB Prize Works of Stephen A. Ross: Some Highlights. Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis

Discounting Rules for Risky Assets. Stewart C. Myers and Richard Ruback

A literature review of the trade off theory of capital structure

Valuation and Tax Policy

Advanced Corporate Finance

New Meaningful Effects in Modern Capital Structure Theory

The 1958 paper by Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller has been justly

SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS

Financial Market Models. Lecture 1. One-period model of financial markets & hedging problems. Imperial College Business School

Table of Contents. Chapter 1 Introduction to Financial Management Chapter 2 Financial Statements, Cash Flows and Taxes...

Semester / Term: -- Workload: 300 h Credit Points: 10

Al al- Bayt University. Course Syllabus Advanced Financial Management (3.0 cr ) Masters in Business Administration 2015

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

3 Department of Mathematics, Imo State University, P. M. B 2000, Owerri, Nigeria.

DOES FINANCIAL LEVERAGE AFFECT TO ABILITY AND EFFICIENCY OF FAMA AND FRENCH THREE FACTORS MODEL? THE CASE OF SET100 IN THAILAND

Course Outline: PRINCIPLES OF FINANCE. Dr Shahab Q Khokhar Dr S Q Khokhar. Aims & Objectives

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

The I Theory of Money

Bank Analysis Bank of Nova Scotia (BNS)

INTERAMERICAN UNIVERSITY OF PUERTO RICO METROPOLITAN CAMPUS FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATIVE SCIENCES. : Ahmad H. Juma h, Ph D.

The implied cost of capital of government s claim and the present value of tax shields: A numerical example

Kavous Ardalan. Marist College, New York, USA

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Valuation Framework: APV 1 In-Class Problem 2

Practice questions. Multiple Choice

Part B: The stock price is next year s dividend divided by the difference between the capitalization rate (r) and the dividend growth rate (g):

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

Working Paper No. 807

The homework assignment reviews the major capital structure issues. The homework assures that you read the textbook chapter; it is not testing you.

Online Shopping Intermediaries: The Strategic Design of Search Environments

Volume 31, Issue 3. The dividend puzzle and tax: a note. Frank Strobel University of Birmingham

Impact of Dividends on Share Prices of Select It Firms

Overall Excess Burden Minimization from a Mathematical Perspective Kong JUN 1,a,*

Valuing Levered Projects

Corporate Finance, Module 3: Common Stock Valuation. Illustrative Test Questions and Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Examining RADR as a Valuation Method in Capital Budgeting

Two Equivalent Conditions

A Note on Capital Budgeting: Treating a Replacement Project as Two Mutually Exclusive Projects

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Corporate Finance in Central Europe. Povinně volitelný (B): EKMBP FF, EKMBP FF (English)

THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW SOUTH WALES

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

A Two-Dimensional Dual Presentation of Bond Market: A Geometric Analysis

Chapter 4. Discounted Cash Flow Valuation

FIN CORPORATE FINANCE Spring Office: CBA 6.246, Phone: ,

Mechanism of formation of the company optimal capital structure, different from suggested by trade off theory

Inconsistencies In Textbook Presentation Of Capital Budgeting Criteria Frank Elston, ( Concordia College

M&M Propositions and the BPM

Copyright 2017 AN Valuations BV. All Rights Reserved. Learning outcome statements (LOS) are copyrighted by CFA Institute and have been reproduced and

2/22/2016. Compound Interest, Annuities, Perpetuities and Geometric Series. Windows User

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management. Course Syllabus for A&B

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Chapter 3 Financial Statements Analysis

BACHELOR IN ECONOMICS SECOND YEAR

Does Capitalized Net Product Equal Discounted Optimal Consumption in Discrete Time? by W.E. Diewert and P. Schreyer. 1 February 27, 2006.

Transcription:

WACC is not the correct discount rate for general asset cash flows Jing Chen School of Business University of Northern British Columbia Prince George, BC Canada V2N 4Z9 Phone: 1-250-960-6480 Email: chenj@unbc.ca Web: http://web.unbc.ca/~chenj/ First draft: January 2017 This draft: November 2017 Abstract We show that the theoretical proofs of Modigliani and Miller propositions, which were formulated on specific assumptions of cash flows of investment projects, cannot be extended to more general patterns of cash flows. In general, total cash flows from an investment project discounted by WACC (Weighted Average of Cost of Capital) will not yield correct value of the project as the sum of debt and equity. As the Modigliani and Miller propositions and WACC have been applied to many corporate finance problems, fundamental issues in corporate finance need to be reexamined. This paper is revised from an earlier working paper, On the Non-equivalence of Two Definitions of Asset Values. I thank Leroy Carr, Michael Ehrhardt for helpful comments, which greatly improve the quality of this paper. 0

More than half century ago, Modigliani and Miller (1958) published some propositions on asset valuation and capital structures. These propositions have since become the foundation of the theory of corporate finance. Some important concepts, such as weighted average cost of capital (WACC), have sprouted from the Modigliani and Miller propositions. WACC has played a ubiquitous role in determining values and capital structures of assets with general cash flow patterns. Yet the Modigliani and Miller propositions were formulated on assets with constant expected cash flows into perpetuity. Will WACC provide correct discount rate for assets with general cash flow patterns? In this paper, we will discuss a specific type of assets that will provide constant debt payment and changing expected dividend payment over time. We prove that when the expected growth rate of dividend payout from an asset is positive (negative), discounting by WACC will overvalue (undervalue) the asset. In general, total cash flows from an investment project discounted by WACC will not yield correct value of the project as the sum of debt and equity. The theoretical propositions of Modigliani and Miller (1958) are no longer controversial and have been aepted into standard economic theory (Miller, 1988; Myers, 2001). Today, discussion on capital structure focus on empirical issues. Our finding shows that the theoretical propositions of Modigliani and Miller (1958), which were proved under very restrictive assumptions, cannot be extended to general cases. 1

A Brief Review of Modigliani and Miller Propositions We will concern ourselves with Propositions I and II in Modigliani and Miller s 1958 paper. We will preserve Modigliani and Miller s original words as much as possible in stating their propositions. Proposition I: Let XX stand for the expected return per year on the assets by the company. Denote by D the market value of the debts of the company; by S the market value of its common shares; by VV SS + DD the market value of all its securities or, as we shall say, the market value of the firm; and by ρρ the expected rate of return appropriate to its risk. Then our Proposition I asserts that we must have in equilibrium: VV SS + DD = XX ρρ (1) The market value of any firm is independent of its capital structure and is given by capitalizing its expected return at the rate ρρ appropriate to its risk. XX is the expected cash flow of the firm that is available for distribution to shareholders and debtholders. With zero growth (which means no need to a new assets) and zero taxes, then XX is sales minus costs minus depreciation. With no need to finance asset growth, XX is also equal to coupon payments plus dividend payments. 2

This proposition can be stated in an equivalent way in terms of the firm s average cost of capital, XX VV, which is the ratio of its expected return to the market value of all its securities. Our proposition then is XX XX = ρρ (2) SS+DD VV Proposition II. From Proposition I we can derive the following proposition concerning the rate of return on common stock in a company whose capital structure includes some debt: the expected rate of return or yield, rr ss, on the stock of the company is a linear function of leverage as follows: rr ss = ρρ + (ρρ rr DD ) DD SS (3) Where rr DD is the yield of the debt of the company. The above are Propositions I and II in MM s paper. We can rearrange equation (3) to obtain ρρ = DD DD + SS rr DD + SS DD + SS rr ss = DD VV rr DD + SS VV rr ss (4) This means that the company s average cost of capital is the weighted average of the costs of its debt and its equity. Propositions I and II are proved under the assumption that the expected return from the asset is constant over time and there are no taxes. However, formula (4) of WACC has since been used in literature and taught in textbooks as a general formula of cost of capital of firms. Some of the assumptions in the original MM 1958 paper had been relaxed (Stiglitz, 1969). Can formula (3) 3

and (4) be extended to value assets with general cash flows? We will examine this issue in the next section. Valuation of Asset Cash Flows with WACC The value of an asset is the sum of the values of its debt and equity. In corporate finance literature, asset value is also defined as cash flows discounted by weighted average cost of capital (WACC) (Ross, Westerfield, Jordan and Roberts, 2013). Modigliani and Miller (1958) proved that when the expected return of an asset is constant over time, two definitions give the same result. We shall prove, by providing a counter example, that in general, two definitions provide different valuations. Suppose an asset is financed by a perpetual bond and an equity issue. The bond pays coupon amount c per unit time. The equity is expected to pay dividend amount d next time period. The amount of dividend is expected to grow at a rate of g. The market value of the bond is D. Then the yield of the bond is rr DD = DD (5) The market value of the equity is S. The discount rate on the dividends is rr ss. Then the yield of equity is rr ss = + gg (6) SS 4

The asset value, V, is the sum of debt and equity. In corporate finance, the value of an asset is also defined as total cash flows discounted by WACC. Let VV represent the asset value calculated from this definition. VV = + + +(1+gg) + +(1+gg)2 + 1+ρρ (1+ρρ) 2 (1+ρρ) 3 = 1+ρρ + (1+ρρ) 2 + (1+ρρ) 3 + + + (1+gg) + (1+gg)2 + 1+ρρ (1+ρρ) 2 (1+ρρ) 3 = ρρ + ρρ gg = DD VV rr DD+ SS VV rr ss + DD VV rr DD+ SS VV rr ss gg = VV + DDrr DD +SSrr ss DDrr DD +SSrr ss VVVV So VV = VV + DDrr DD +SSrr ss DDrr DD +SSrr ss VVVV (7) The difference between VV aaaaaa VV would be VV VV = VV + DDrr DD +SSrr ss DDrr DD +SSrr ss VVVV 1 From (5) and (6), the above formula can be simplified into, = VV( + ++SSSS ++SSSS VVVV 1) = VV + ++SSSS + DDDD 1 5

= VV (+ DDDD)+(++SSSS) (++SSSS)(+ DDDD) (++SSSS)(+ DDDD) = VV ++SSSSgg2 (++SSSS)(+ DDDD) gggggg = VV DD + SS + gg ( + + SSSS)( + DDDD) = VV gggggg(rr ss rr DD ) (++SSSS)(+ DDDD) (8) When g = 0, term (8) is equal to zero. VV = VV In the special case when the expected growth rate of dividend payout is zero, WACC does provide correct valuation for asset cash flows, as proved by Modigliani and Miller (1958). From (8), when the growth rate is positive, g > 0, VV > VV discounting by WACC will overvalue the asset. When the growth rate is negative, g < 0, VV < VV discounting by WACC will undervalue the asset. In general, asset values calculated from cash flows discounted by WACC are not equal to the sum of values of debt and equity. Debt and equities can be traded in the markets and their values are observable quantities. Valuations by WACC, in contrast, are not observable quantities. Since valuation with WACC differs from the 6

sum of debt and equity values, the theoretical method of Modigliani and Miller cannot be extended to value assets with general cash flows. In practice, people usually choose a discount rate that equalizes two definitions of asset values and call it WACC (Brigham, Ehrhardt, Gessaroli and Nason, 2017, P. 655). This is to solve for r in the equation CCCCCChffffffffff ii (1 + rr) ii = DD + SS (9) ii=1 and call r WACC. However, this r in general is not equal to the weighted average of costs of debt and equity, DD DD + SS rr DD + SS DD + SS rr ss It should not be called WACC. The following numerical example will provide a more concrete illustration of the issue. Suppose a company is financed with a perpetual bond and common stock. The market value of bond is 100 million dollars and the market value of the equity is 100 million dollars as well. The asset value of the company, as the sum of debt and equity, is 100+100 = 200 million dollars. 7

The company is expected to distribute coupon amount to 3 million dollar and dividend amount to 3 million dollars next year. So the yield of the perpetual bond is 3% and the dividend ratio is 3%. Assume the growth rate of the dividend is 4% per year. The cost of equity is Dividend yield + growth rate = 3%+4%=7% and WWWWWWWW = DD rr DD+SS DD + SS rr DD+SS ss = 100 100+100 100 3% + 7% = 5% 100+100 The sum of cash flows discounted by WACC is 3+3(1+4%)ii 1 ii=1 (1+5%) ii 3 = ii=1 + 3(1+4%)ii 1 ii=1 (1+5%) ii = 3 + 3 = 60 + 300 = 360 mmmmmmmmmmmmmm 5% 5% 4% (1+5%) ii This is the asset value calculated from discounting by WACC. Compared with the asset value as the sum of debt and equity, which is 200 million, the asset value calculated from discounting by WACC is much higher. In the example above, the correct discount rate for total cash flows can be obtained by solving (9). As 3 + 3 = 50 + 150 = 200, 6% 6% 4% the discount rate is 6%. But this rate is not a weighted average of costs of debt and equity. 8

Empirical tests often find firms are underleveraged. This is often attributed to various types of market imperfection. However, further investigations often show that it is the designs or methodologies of these tests that are flawed (Molina, 2005; Chen, 2006). Our finding suggests some supposed underleveraging could also come from miscalculation caused by discounting with WACC. Concluding Remarks We prove that WACC is not the correct discount rate for general cash flows. The intuition behind the proof is very simple. Discount rate is not a linear factor. We shouldn t expect WACC, a linear combination of two discount rates, will provide correct measure of discounting for combined cash flows in general cases. Since discounting by WACC does not provide correct measurement of asset values in general, we recommend no more using WACC in valuing assets. Instead, we can calculate equity value and debt value separately with their corresponding discount rates. This will provide more aurate measurement of asset values as the sum of debt and equity values. The goal of financial management, as stated at the beginning of most textbooks, is to maximize shareholder value. After the introduction of the concept of WACC in the mile of the textbooks, the goal of financial management usually changes into the maximization of firm value, which is 9

the sum of equity value and debt value. The goal of maximizing shareholder value and maximizing frim value are not always consistent with each other. By calculating equity value and debt value separately, we can maintain a consistent approach of maximizing shareholder value throughout the whole teaching process. We can also determine the optimal capital structure from the process of maximizing shareholder value. The Modigliani and Miller propositions and WACC have been applied to many corporate finance problems. For example, the optimal capital structure, which is supposed to maximize firm value, is often defined as the debt equity ratio where WACC reaches its minimum. As the WACC discounting method does not provide correct measure of asset value, fundamental issues in corporate finance need to be reexamined. This finding will have deep implications to research, teaching and practice in corporate finance. 10

References Brigham, E. F., Ehrhardt, M. C., Gessaroli, J. and Nason, R.R. (2017). Financial management: Theory & practice. Third Canadian Edition, Nelson. Chen, J. (2006). Imperfect market or imperfect theory: a unified analytical theory of production and capital structure of firms. Miller, M. H. (1988). The Modigliani-Miller propositions after thirty years. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(4), 99-120. Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. "The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment." The American economic review 48.3 (1958): 261-297. Molina, C. A. (2005). Are firms underleveraged? An examination of the effect of leverage on default probabilities. The Journal of Finance, 60(3), 1427-1459. Myers, S. C. (2001). Capital structure. The journal of economic perspectives, 15(2), 81-102. 11

Ross SA, Westerfield R, Jordan BD. Roberts, G, Fundamentals of corporate finance. Eighth Canadian Edition, McGraw-Hill Education; 2013. Stiglitz, J. E. (1969). A re-examination of the Modigliani-Miller theorem. The American Economic Review, 784-793. Villamil, A. P. (2008). The Modigliani-Miller Theorem. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, 6. 12