The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Similar documents
Money in an RBC framework

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Advanced Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics and finance

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Admissible Functional Forms in Monetary Economics

Problem set Fall 2012.

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Winter 2009 Solutions to Problem Set 2.

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

The Market Price of Risk and the Equity Premium: A Legacy of the Great Depression? by Cogley and Sargent

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Slides III - Complete Markets

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

MONETARY AND FINANCIAL MACRO BUDGET CONSTRAINTS

The Information Content of the Yield Curve

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Over the latter half of the 1990s, the U.S. economy experienced both

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

1 Dynamic programming

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Urban Real Estate Prices and Fair Value: The Case for U.S. Metropolitan Areas

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Money Demand. ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle

MONEY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: SOME INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE. Abstract

Inflation and Stock Market Returns in US: An Empirical Study

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION. Chapter 25

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Inflation & Welfare 1

The Real Business Cycle Model

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Monetary Economics. Money in Utility. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. February Sharif University of Technology

IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND AUSTRALIAN EQUITY RETURNS

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Economics 826 International Finance. Final Exam: April 2007

The Term Structure of Expected Inflation Rates

14.02 Solutions Quiz III Spring 03

Money Growth and Inflation, Nominal and Real Interest Rates The ISLM Model

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Volume 29, Issue 4. A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level: Some Empirical Evidence

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

1. Money in the utility function (start)

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Online Appendix A to chapter 16

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis. (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. September 21, 2015

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Monetary Theory and Policy. Fourth Edition. Carl E. Walsh. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Pseudo-Wealth Fluctuations and Aggregate Demand Effects

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

Pattern-Based Inflation Expectations and the U.S. Real Rate of Interest

Transcription:

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth A B S T R A C T Although the Fisher equation applies for the case of no output growth, I show that it requires an adjustment to account for non-zero output growth. I demonstrate this using a standard model with constant relative risk aversion utility containing money, nominal bonds and output growth in a risk-free setting. Failing to incorporate a growth term in regressions will lead to biased estimation results. 30 November 2004 Neil Arnwine Lecturer Bilkent University I would like to thank Ivan Pastine and Kevin Hasker for their comments. All remaining errors are my own.

I. Introduction The Fisher equation is a well-accepted theoretical construct in macroeconomics and finance. It can be expressed as: E( π) r i = + (1) where i is the nominal interest rate, E( π) is the expected inflation rate and r is the real interest rate. In this paper I show that when there is growth in the level of consumption over time the Fisher equation becomes: ( π) + ρ + α E( y& ) i = E (2) where ρ represents the consumer s real rate of time preference, E ( y& ) represents the expected rate of output (or consumption) growth, and α is the degree of relative risk aversion. The logic is simple: output growth reduces the marginal utility of real income over time increasing the real interest rate: ( y& ) r = ρ + α E. (3) In equation 2 expected output growth increases the nominal interest rate as the consumer tries to smooth consumption by saving less. Conversely, a decrease in expected output reduces the nominal interest rate. When no output growth is expected equation 2 is identical to equation 1. This modification of the Fisher equation to account for growth does not alter Fisher s original view that real and monetary factors are separable in their effect upon the economy. Expected inflation still effects output on a one-to-one basis, ceteris paribus, and has no effect upon the real rate of time preference of the consumer. Fisher (1896) introduces the Fisher equation, see Dimand (1999), and Fisher (1930) contained an extensive discussion of the relation. After more than 100, years Fisher s 1

relation is still a work horse. In the two years 2003-2004 alone there were more than a dozen studies on the Fisher equation, mostly featured in empirical journals. Fisher s contribution here was to observe that real and nominal factors can be separated when analyzing their effects upon the economy. This is a precursor to the theory of the neutrality of money. His discussion of the equation demonstrated an understanding of rational expectations decades before the term was coined. The Fisher equation has various interpretations. At one extreme we can view r as a fixed constant expressing the consumer s rate of time preference so that expected inflation passes through on a one-to-one basis into nominal interest rates. Even if this view is correct, since the researcher cannot observe the consumer s ex-ante inflation expectation there will still be a stochastic element to empirical studies. Alternatively, we can view the real rate as potentially time-varying. Then, while there will be a one-to-one long run relationship between inflation and nominal interest rates it may not be exact in the short run. Mundell (1963) and Tobin (1965) provide a theoretical explanation for a time-varying real interest rate. For Mundell (1963) higher inflation reduces wealth by reducing the desired level of real money balances. This stimulates saving, which reduces the real interest rate. Tobin (1965) sees inflation as driving saving away from nominal assets to real assets, reducing the real interest rate by lowering the marginal product of capital. Evans and Lewis (1995) considers the case in which inflation follows a Markov-switching process so that expost observed the real interest rate features a non-zero expectation and is serially correlated. In empirical studies Mishkin (1984) and Pelaez (1995) reject the hypothesis that the real interest rate is constant for the OECD and U.S., respectively. Fama (1981) concluded that variation in the real interest rate could be explained by real, rather than by nominal, factors. None of these studies necessarily invalidates the Fisher equation as a long run relation. More 2

recently Rapach (2003) does reject the long run Fisher equation, concluding that interest rates adjust less than one-to-one with inflation in the long run, based upon a VAR study. One empirical observation that appears in the literature is that the inclusion of real variables in an estimation of the Fisher equation yields a significant coefficient; see Levi and Makin (1978), Evans and Makin (1979), VanderHoff (1984), and Dotsey, Lantz and Scholl 2003). This is in seeming contradiction to the Fisher equation s prediction that only inflation explains the nominal interest rate. The argument put forward by Levi and Makin (1978), Evans and Makin (1979), VanderHoff (1984), and others is that the Phillips curve introduces a short run bias. They viewed this bias as disappearing in the long run because the economy reverts to full employment level of output (Levi and Makin 1979, p. 43). II. Model I examine a standard cash-in-advance consumption model with constant relative risk aversion utility function and output growth. The model contains no risk. This assumption is made to simplify notation and so that it is clear that my findings do not depend upon Phillips curve explanations, Mundell-Tobin arguments or on a deviation from the quantity theory of money. There are no frictions in the model. Production is exogenously determined so we can interpret this as a Lucas-type tree economy. The representative household can be thought of as a worker-shopper pair. The worker sells the exogenously arriving output in a competitive market and the shopper collects the couple s income, as cash balances, at the end of the period and proceeds to shop in the next period. I assume a constant output growth rate. Output evolves according to: y. (4) t = γ yt Throughout I will assume a risk-free steady output and monetary growth so these growth rates have no time subscript. 3

Government in this model introduces money at a constant growth rate, sells one-period bonds on a discounted basis, and provides a lump sum transfer payment. The money supply evolves according to M t+1 = M t, where a bar over the variable indicates it is the supply of the variable. The government s finance constraint insures that the revenue from seigniorage plus the net revenue from bond sales and redemptions is equal to the lump sum transfer payment: T t ( ) M t + ( 1+ it ) Bt Bt = + 1 1. (5) I assume that the government does not indefinitely let the size of debt grow faster than output. The representative consumer has a constant relative risk aversion utility function: u () c 1 1 α = c 1 α α 1 u() c = ln c, α = 1, (6) The consumer s budget constraint is: ( + it ) Bt M t + Bt + Pt yt Tt P t ct + M t+ 1 + 1 + 1 + (7) where the right hand side represents the consumer s wealth. This consists of money carried into this period from the previous period, the maturing one-period nominal bond, output sold in a competitive market, and the lump sum government transfer payment. The left hand side of equation 6 shows how the consumer allocates his wealth. There is a single consumption good. Saving takes the form of nominal money balances and discounted government bonds. Money demand is motivated by a cash-in-advance constraint placed upon the consumption good. This creates a demand for money, even though money is dominated in return by bonds and equities. P c M (8) t t t Money is selected a period in advance of its use. 4

We are only interested in variables in two different time periods, time t and t+1. Therefore I drop the time subscript and use a prime to denote variables evaluated at time t+1. It is necessary to re-pose the problem in a way that is time stationary. I divide equations 6 and 7 by next period's money stock, M, to define these new variables: M P B T m =, p =, b =, tr =. (9) M M M M Here m is the representative consumer s share of money supply. The other variables, p, b, and tr, are the real goods price, bond value, and transfer payment. Basically, the share of the money stock held by the consumer is selected as a numerairé. After making the change of variables, we get stationary representations of the consumer's budget constraints. m + b p c + m + ( 1 + i) b = + p y + tr (10) m p c = (11) Each constraint is satisfied as equality since consumption is valued and there is an opportunity cost to holding money. Let S = { y,b, γ, } define the current state of the world. The level of money supply M has no effect upon the consumer s decision or on the equilibrium, other than determining the absolute value of P. In equilibrium the representative consumer s share of money stock is one, m = m = 1, and all output is consumed c = y. The consumer s problem can be stated as a value function problem: v ( S ) = { u( c) + β v( S ) max c, m, b subject to equations 10 and 11. } (12) 5

Finally, I assume that output does not grow too fast, β γ 1 α < 1. The consumer s first order conditions are as follows: α ( S ) = c p ( λ + µ ) = 0 v c (13) v v m ( S ) = λ + β E[ vm ( S )] = 0 ( S ) ( λ + µ b ( S ) = ( 1+ i) λ + β E[ vb ( S )] = 0 ( S ) v = 1 m ) (14) λ v b = (15) The second term in equations 14 and 15, v m and v b, makes use of the envelope theorem. Combining equations 13-15 together with the constraints, equations 10 and 11, and the two market clearing conditions yields a stationary (in growth rates) equilibrium. In evaluating the envelope condition in equations 14 and 15 it is not necessary to take expectations because there is no uncertainty, however it is important to observe the time superscript of the variables. A priori we know that = and γ = γ. The price level is found from the cash-in-advance constraint, equation 11: p = 1 y (16) Combining equations 13 and 16 I obtain: 1 α λ + µ = y (17) Equation 14 together with equation 17 yields the Lagrange multiplier on wealth: λ = β = β ( λ + µ ) 1 α ( γ y) (18) Finally combining equations 15 and 18 yields the modified Fisher equation: i = β λ λ = β γ 1 α (19) 6

Using equation 9 with the price level in equation 16 yields the inflation rate: P p = P p = γ (20) The modified Fisher equation presented in equation 19 is perhaps more recognizable if I make the following change of variables: ~ i = ln( 1+ i), π = ln ln γ, ρ = ln( β), y& = ln y t ln yt 1 (21) Then the equation becomes: ~ i = π + ρ + α y&. (22) There is a one-to-one relationship between inflation and the nominal interest rate if we control for output growth. Finally, I would like to make a couple of observations concerning the solutions presented in equations 16-20. Firstly, I examine the derivative of the value function with respect to output: γ v y ( S ) = p λ = β ( γ y) α. (23) This is clearing declining over time if output is growing. This is the reason for an output growth term belonging in the Fisher equation. Next, observe that confirming that the transformed budget constraint is indeed time stationary. p y is constant, III. Conclusion The Fisher equation is only correct when there is no output growth. In practice this condition is not likely to hold. I have derived a modification of the Fisher equation that allows us to directly estimate the consumer s degree of relative risk aversion. This observation provides theoretical support to the practice of including real variables in the estimation of the Fisher equation. For example Dotsey, Lantz and Scholl s (2003) finding 7

that the ex-ante real interest rate is positively correlated with output, and high rates are correlated with high output in the next quarter is completely consistent with the modified Fisher equation. References Cooray, Arusha, The Fisher Effect: A Survey. The Singapore Economic Review 48 (2003): 135-150. Crowder, William J. and Hoffman, Dennis L., The Long-Run Relationship between Nominal and Inflation: The Fisher Equation Revisited. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 28 (February 1996): 102-118. Dimand, Robert W., Irving Fisher and the Fisher Relation: Setting the Record Straight. Canadian Journal of Economics, 32 (May 1999): 744-750. Dotsey, Michael, Lantz, Carl, and Scholl, Brian, The Behavior of the Real Interest Rate. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 35 (February 2003): 91-110. Evans, Martin D. D., Real Rates, Expected Inflation, and Inflation Risk Premia. Journal of Finance 53 (February 1998): 187-218. Evans, Martin D. D. and Lewis, Karen K., Do Expected Shifts in Inflation Affect Estimates of the Long-Run Fisher Relation? Journal of Finance 1 (March 1995): 225-253. Fama, Eugene F., Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and Money. American Economic Review 71 (September 1981): 545-565. Fisher, Irving, Appreciation and Interest. Publications of the American Economic Association, 11 (July 1896): 1-98. Fisher, Irving, The Theory of Interest. New York : MacMillan 1930. Levi, Maurice D. and Makin, John H., Anticipated Inflation and Interest Rates: Further Interpretation of Findings on the Fisher Equation. American Economic Review 68 (December 1978): 801-812. Levi, Maurice D. and Makin, John H., Fisher, Phillips, Friedman and the Measured Impact of Inflation on Interest. Journal of Finance 34 (March 1979): 35-52. Mishkin, F. S., Are Real Interest Rates Equal Across Countries? An Empirical Investigation of International Parity Conditions. Journal of Finance 39 (1984): 1345-1357. Mundell, Robert, Inflation and Real Interest. Journal of Political Economy 71 (June 1963): 280-283. Pelaez, R.F., The Fisher Effect: Reprise. Journal of Macroeconomics 17 (1995): 333-346. Rapach, David E., International Evidence on the Long-Run Empact of Inflation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 35 (February 2003): 23-48. Tobin, James, Money and Economic Growth. Econometrica 33 (October 1965): 671-684. VarderHoff, James, Evidence on the Varying Effect of Expected Inflation on Interest Rates. Review of Economics and Statistics 66 (August 1984): 477-481. 8