The following box outlines the basic steps in economic analysis. The last

Similar documents
7 Analyzing the Results 57

Lao People s Democratic Republic Peace Independence Democracy Unity Prosperity

THE MICRONUTRIENT INITIATIVE

Recommendations of the Panel on Cost- Effectiveness in Health and Medicine

John Hills The distribution of welfare. Book section (Accepted version)

Financial Statements March 31, 2016 (expressed in US dollars)

Feasibility study. Lecture 4. 7/15/2014 Dr. Joshua Onono

A nutrition surveillance case study from Guatemala

WHO GCM on NCDs Working Group Discussion Paper on financing for NCDs Submission by the NCD Alliance, February 2015

Tracking Government Investments for Nutrition at Country Level Patrizia Fracassi, Clara Picanyol, 03 rd July 2014

CURRENT POPULATION SURVEY ANALYSIS OF NSLP PARTICIPATION and INCOME

IMPROVING PUBLIC FINANCING FOR NUTRITION SECTOR IN TANZANIA

Food Prices Vulnerability and Social Protection Responses

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS. A. Short-Term Effects on Income Poverty and Vulnerability

Costing of the SDG Targets for Nutrition. Christiane Rudert Mueni Mutunga Jun Fan UNICEF -EAPRO

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

Green Finance for Green Growth

Presentation made in the Second Consultation on Macro-economics. and Health of WHO, Geneva, October 2003

Booklet C.2: Estimating future financial resource needs

Inclusive Growth Analytics and the Diagnostic Facility for Shared Growth

Public spending on health care: how are different criteria related? a second opinion

Financing Agreement. (Rapid Response Child-Focused Social Cash Transfer and Nutrition Security Project) between REPUBLIC OF SENEGAL.

Review of Implementation of National Nutrition Strategy by LGAs and MDAs

NEW ZEALAND SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES PROFESSIONAL STANDARD NO. 91 ECONOMIC VALUATIONS MANDATORY STATUS EFFECTIVE DATE 1 JULY 2010

Regulation of Fortified Foods to Address Micronutrient Malnutrition: Legislation, Regulations and Enforcement

Scaling Up Nutrition Kenya Country Experience

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

NCF Glossary 1. November 2017

Project Appraisal and Selection

CLIENT VALUE & INDEX INSURANCE

KEY QUESTIONS FOR CONSULTANTS ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PROJECTS. Project Economic Evaluation Division Economics and Development Resource Center

How do the capital markets undermine sustainable development? What can be done to correct this?

Ministry of Health / Ministry of Finance Toolkit

Changing how we think about cost-effectiveness of addressing childhood anemia

EXPERIENCES IN PLANNING FOR NUTRITION AT THE LOCAL GOVERNMENT LEVEL

The Results Measurement (ReM) framework methodology

Tax distortions The third mechanism to be taken into account is related to the economic

PROJECT CYCLE MANAGEMENT & LOGICAL FRAMEWORK MATRIX TRAINING CYPRIOT CIVIL SOCIETY IN ACTION V INNOVATION AND CHANGES IN EDUCATION VI

GUIDELINES FOR CONDUCTING A PROVINCIAL PUBLIC EXPENDITURE REVIEW (PPER) OF THE AGRICULTURE SECTOR

RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS

Benefit-Cost Analysis: Introduction and Overview

Ex post evaluation Georgia

Fiscal Implications of Chronic Diseases. Peter S. Heller SAIS, Johns Hopkins University November 23, 2009

PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE Report No.: AB3313 Project Name. BO-Enhancing Human Capital of Children and Youth Region

BRINGING FINANCE TO RURAL PEOPLE MACEDONIA S CASE

MAKE OR BUY Role of Private Sector in Health. Alaa Hamed MNA Health Policy Forum, November 12,

ECONOMICS PUBLIC SECTOR. of the JOSEPH E. STIGUTZ. Second Edition. W.W.NORTON & COMPANY-New York-London. Princeton University

ASIAN DEVELOPMENT BANK

The Features of Investment Decision-Making

We can. overcome. Undernutrition: Lao PDR. Case Study. International Cooperation and Development

Financial Reporting Consolidation PEMPAL Treasury Community of Practice thematic group on Public Sector Accounting and Reporting

Chapter 5 Poverty, Inequality, and Development

Development Cooperation Development Education Partnership Fair. Writing a successful co financing application

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

Financial Restraints in a Mature Welfare State The Case of Denmark 1

Financing strategies to achieve the MDGs in Latin America and the Caribbean

Personal Income Tax Weakness & Possible Remedies: Outdated and Inequitable Tax Provisions

Marche Region. Ex Ante Evaluation report. Executive summary. Roma, June 2015

Securing Sustainable Financing: A Priority for Health Programs in Namibia

CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION. decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of household

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623

Assessing Development Strategies to Achieve the MDGs in the Arab Region

Questions and Answers: Value Added Tax (VAT)

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Session 1.2 Scope of Project Economic Analysis. Introductory Course on Economic Analysis of Investment Projects 29 June 2009

PART V INSTITUTE OF NUTRITION OF CENTRAL AMERICA AND PANAMA

MDGs Example from Latin America

Introduction ( 1 ) The German Landesbanken cases a brief review CHIEF ECONOMIST SECTION

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

RESERVE BANK OF MALAWI

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

INTERNATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF INSURANCE SUPERVISORS

Economics Concepts Overview

Franklin European Dividend Fund

The theory of taxation/3 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.15 Rosen) Desirable characteristics of tax systems (optimal taxation)

Optimal Progressivity

Al-Amal Microfinance Bank

October 10, Teresa Rodriguez Arias International Organization of Securities Commission (IOSCO) Calle Oquendo Madrid

ITIL Practitioner Course 06 - Use Metrics & Measurement

Subsidies in the fiscal system would be considerably understated if one

MONTENEGRO. Name the source when using the data

Country Report of Yemen for the regional MDG project

DANISH ECONOMY SPRING 2018 SUMMARY AND RECOMMENDATIONS

E Distribution: GENERAL. Executive Board First Regular Session. Rome, 9 11 February January 2009 ORIGINAL: ENGLISH

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Environmental Funds. Main Categories and Characteristics of Environmental Funds

Article from: Pension Section News. September 2013 Issue 81

Chapter 9. Development

Understanding goal-based investing

Financing Strategies: A missing link to translate NDCs into action

Principles: Subsidy Design for Private Sector Mini-grids. Subodh Mathur. and

Prioritisation of Initiatives and Program Development [F5]

HOW FAR SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT GO IN PROVIDING A MINIMUM LEVEL OF NUTRITION?

Subject CP1 Actuarial Practice Core Practices Syllabus

2 USES OF CONSUMER PRICE INDICES

Chapter 8: Lifecycle Planning

Module 10. Lecture 37

214 Massachusetts Ave. N.E Washington D.C (202) TESTIMONY. Medicaid Expansion

Rwanda. UNICEF/Till Muellenmeister. Health Budget Brief

Boston Chapter AGA 2018 Regional Professional Development Conference. Brandeis University Professor Erich Schumann May 2018

Transcription:

4 The Groundwork for Economic Analysis 11 The following box outlines the basic steps in economic analysis. The last three are often given most attention in how to guidelines and this is understandable given their greater technical complexity. But the earlier stage is no less important. In fact, the appropriateness and efficiency of the analysis itself depends crucially on getting these first steps right. The basic steps: Specify the problem and define the objectives of the project in relation to that problem Identify all plausible options for achieving those objectives Decide what level of analysis is worthwhile Describe in detail the options being considered Estimate the costs of each option Estimate the benefits or effectiveness of each option, based on the projected demand Analyze the relationship between costs and benefits (or effectiveness) for each of the options being considered. Problem and objective definition The principal objective largely determines the analytical approach used. The objective is expressed in terms of some specified reduction in a defined problem. This might be a nutrition problem (e.g. vitamin A deficiency is high, malnutrition in children has increased), or a technical or administrative one (e.g. iodine levels in fortified salt appear to be too low, the supplementation

12 program is not working as well as hoped, there is insufficient nutrition expertise available). It may be a broader health or welfare concern (e.g. mortality rates are high). The more precisely defined the objective, in terms of population and geographic targets and timetable (e.g. to reduce by 50% the level of vitamin A deficiency in young children in rural areas of Guatemala by the year 2000"), the easier the subsequent steps in an economic appraisal will be. Built into the declaration of the objective of a project is a judgement that that objective is worth meeting. Sector level economic analysis should have determined this before the project appraisal stage, but it may be appropriate to question that assumption, open up the issue and redefine the problem. If support for that judgement is not solid, there may be good grounds for recommending that project resources be invested in further analysis or research to provide more convincing evidence to guide future decisions and help mid-course corrections to project implementation. Identification of alternatives While disease and inadequate dietary intake both contribute to malnutrition, nutrition projects traditionally focus on rectifying the problem of inadequate or inappropriate intake (e.g. premature feeding of liquids to young infants). In general terms, there are three important broad routes through which dietary intake can be improved changing tastes (preferences, habits, values), changing the price to consumers of foods or food inputs to consumers (fortified foods, food supplements, materials for home gardening etc.) and changing the resources (income) available to procure appropriate food in adequate amounts. Governments can influence the first directly through information, education and communication for the targeted population. This can be done indirectly by training those outside government service or regulating their educational activities. The second can be accomplished by fully funding, subsidizing, or requiring through legislation and regulations that someone else provide those foods or food inputs (e.g. food fortification regulations). The third can

13 be influenced through income transfers (e.g. food stamps). There may be interactions among these (e.g. income transfers may influence prices and/or tastes ). Also, less direct ways may be used, such as through education and agricultural policies. In considering the alternative ways to ameliorate the defined nutrition problem, it pays to be creative and cast a wide net in the first instance. Involve technical specialists to canvas the options as broadly as possible. Consider the different routes through which change could be effected and whether the problem is best tackled through interventions in the health, agriculture or education sectors; which mix of inputs (more food or education, training or quality assurance techniques) is key; whether or how much targeting to undertake (by age, income or location); what technologies or delivery systems to use; and the optimal scale of operation. Consider the possible instruments for affecting that change (direct provision, subsidies, regulation) and alternative providers and implementing agencies including those in the private as well as the public sector. Labor is often the largest cost component, and exploring alternative ways to use this resource more efficiently is a relevant cost-effectiveness issue for most nutrition programs. In practice, the choices within some of these dimensions will be quite limited for some interventions, and certain issues will emerge as more important for a given intervention. Some choices will be clearly less efficient than others on the basis of a rough assessment of likely cost and effectiveness. Others might fail to satisfy some absolute constraints (e.g. financial, technical, legal, cultural or ethical). These options should be recorded and the reasons for not considering them further noted. It is important not to eliminate from the list any alternatives which have powerful political support. Three micronutrient problems illustrate the kinds of differences in issues and choices that are likely to emerge. The problem of vitamin A deficiency, for example, can be tackled in three very different ways: fortification of food vehicles, periodic distribution of high dose capsules (supplements) or education to encourage the consumption of vitamin A-rich foods. The demand

14 for existing supply of each of these will vary and will form a basis for the analyses. Which strategy, or mix of strategies, is preferable will not be immediately obvious in most cases and can usefully be subjected to costeffectiveness analysis (see Case Study 1). Iron deficiency in pregnant women, on the other hand, can only be addressed through supplements the iron needs of pregnant women exceed any safe level of population-wide food fortification and naturally rich food sources of iron do not provide enough. Cost-effectiveness analysis can, however, be used to explore the alternative ways in which supplementation can be implemented. Important issues, for example, include the role of screening and the magnitude of public sector subsidies for social marketing and supplements (see Case Study 2). Among options for iodine deficiency control, there is usually no viable alternative to iodizing salt; injections are more costly and complex and are used as a stop-gap emergency measure only. Within the broad strategy of salt iodization, a number of alternative approaches are possible. One is how to encourage small salt producers to produce iodizable quality salt, whether through subsidies or through penalties against un-iodized salt, which would drive some salt producers out of the market. Another is the appropriate balance of investment in demand generation through public education, and in a regulatory and monitoring system. Where the question being posed is should we continue this nutrition project as it is or in some modified form analysis of the existing project is likely to be an important source of ideas about suitable alternatives. Case Study 2 illustrates this approach as applied to an iron supplementation program in Jamaica. Public/private question One of the key sets of alternatives that must be considered concerns the nature and extent of public sector involvement. Governments can play a

15 variety of roles. They may act as providers of goods or services which can be financed through taxation or user fees. Alternatively, governments may contract out services to the private sector or provide other incentives to modify private provider behavior through regulations or pricing policies or by directly subsidizing some inputs such as information or training. Cost-benefit or cost-effectiveness analysis will not answer the question of whether government involvement is appropriate or not. An attractive economic return does not necessarily justify public involvement. Indeed, if the net financial returns are also positive it suggests that the project be left entirely or largely to the private market (Devarajan, et al, 1996). Government involvement can generally be justified where there are identifiable failures in the market, which arise in the case of public goods, externalities and imperfect information, or where income redistribution is considered desirable. Where government involvement is justified, the Bank has favored government finance (as opposed to government provision of goods and services). One reason for this is that public sector institutions have often been found to operate less efficiently than those in the private sector, and attempts to improve their performance have generally been unsatisfactory. Undertaking a detailed analysis of all the private/public alternatives is not necessary. Some will be clearly inappropriate. The best procedure is to start by identifying the rationale for public involvement and explore what this might mean for an appropriate government role. In nutrition, there are few examples of pure public goods or of market failure arising from externalities or indivisibilities. Many of the benefits from improved nutrition are private benefits, captured by the individual and her/his family (Levin, 1985). Much of the rationale for public involvement in nutrition will revolve around market failure resulting from imperfect information (Behrman, 1995) and the desire to redistribute income to poorer members of society. If information failure is the rationale, it may be worth investing in education, communications and research (including basic research to improve understanding of intervention benefits, as well as monitoring epidemiological trends in deficiencies) rather

16 than free provision of subsidies for goods and services. If equity is the rationale for public financing, then income incidence of benefits needs to be looked at very closely. Since full cost recovery will rarely be a desirable goal for those nutrition projects which do have a convincing public sector rationale, it is important that appraisals include the cost of distortions created by financing projects through taxation. The marginal cost of public funds is an additional and substantial cost incurred by the project. For every dollar in additional taxation that is required, distortionary costs have been estimated to lie in the range of 20 cents to one dollar, depending in part on the tax instrument employed (Devarajan, et al, 1996). Level of analysis Economic appraisal is not an all or nothing exercise. It can be done more or less thoroughly and comprehensively and should itself be subjected to some level of economic assessment. It is important not to fall into the trap of holding modest decisions hostage to elaborate manipulations of data (Field, 1987). On the other hand, failure to devote adequate attention to assessing the options and their implications can have costly consequences. For example, failure to adequately assess the expected costs, benefits and demand for routine hemoglobin testing in Jamaica has resulted in an unnecessary drain on scarce health resources (see Case Study 2). In deciding how much time and money to invest in the analysis, the following should be considered: the possible losses from making a wrong choice the nature of the available data and the likely costs of different levels of complexity of the analysis

17 the amount of influence the analysis is likely to have (both for this decision and others) the type, level of detail and presentation of data that is suitable for the study s audience The general principle is to do the minimum necessary to answer the question being posed. The analysis only need be as precise and sophisticated as is necessary to decide to accept or reject a project. Clearly identifying what is known about cost, or effectiveness or their component parts, and what can be used as is with minimal adaptation, and what data will need to be specially collected, is key to being efficient in the appraisal process. Another strategy is to focus data collection and analysis on those elements that are likely to contribute most to costs or benefits, such as the cost of fortificant in the vitamin A fortification program in Case Study 1. Description of the alternatives An important step before embarking on the estimation of costs and benefits or effectiveness is to delineate as precisely as possible exactly what it is that is being appraised. Part of the reason for doing this is to make sure that the cost and effectiveness estimates match, that what is being costed is really the intervention whose effectiveness is being estimated. Size, time horizon and perspective are important dimensions to define. A societal perspective is generally appropriate for donors such as the Bank and is the perspective adopted in most of this document. It implies being comprehensive in the measurement of costs and benefits. Different parties involved, for example, government ministries and consumers will have different viewpoints. It is often useful to also calculate the costs and benefits they will experience, in order to understand the nature of the incentives or disincentives to their participation. This is particularly true of the potential

18 beneficiaries of the project. The costs and benefits they perceive will determine the level of their demand for the project outputs and hence project effectiveness. If the intervention is a discrete, time-limited one, the analysis should be on the whole of the project, over its lifetime. If the intervention is long-term, indefinite and relatively stable, a more manageable short-cut might be to define the intervention in terms of one year and estimate the effectiveness of resources employed in that typical year. Immediate project outputs are often the pivot around which estimates are derived. For example, in a food distribution program, the cost exercise might involve estimating the cost per kilogram of food delivered per beneficiary per year, while the effectiveness calculations will involve estimating how a kilogram of food per beneficiary per year will translate into a reduction in mortality. It is important to ensure that the link is secure. It would not be appropriate for the costs to refer to food delivered for example, while effectiveness is based on food consumed. Consistency in approach between interventions is also an important principle. For example, if a typical year is being used, the approach should be comparable for different interventions. It would not be legitimate, for example, to study an early start-up year, probably with high costs and poorer effects, for one project and a year when the program is well-established for another (see Case Study 4). Consistent assumptions regarding key economic and epidemiological variables, such as discount rates, exchange rates and mortality rates, should be employed across the interventions. The perspective adopted should be the same for each intervention.