Drawdowns Preceding Rallies in the Brownian Motion Model

Similar documents
Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

PDE Methods for the Maximum Drawdown

Drawdowns and Rallies in a Finite Time-horizon

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Insurance against Market Crashes

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Drawdowns, Drawups, their joint distributions, detection and financial risk management

The stochastic calculus

The Black-Scholes Model

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

The Black-Scholes Model

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

The value of foresight

An upper bound for ex-post Sharpe ratio with application in. performance measurement

Risk Measure. An Analysis of the Maximum Drawdown

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Probability in Options Pricing

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Deterministic Income under a Stochastic Interest Rate

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

Option Pricing Models for European Options

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Limited liability, or how to prevent slavery in contract theory

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

1 The continuous time limit

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

BEHAVIOUR OF PASSAGE TIME FOR A QUEUEING NETWORK MODEL WITH FEEDBACK: A SIMULATION STUDY

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

A Note about the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model under Time-Varying Conditions Yi-rong YING and Meng-meng BAI

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Monte Carlo Simulations

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Non-semimartingales in finance

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

"Pricing Exotic Options using Strong Convergence Properties

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Results for option pricing

Hedging under Arbitrage

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics

Dynamic Fund Protection. Elias S. W. Shiu The University of Iowa Iowa City U.S.A.

Interest rate models in continuous time

Lévy models in finance

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

An Analysis of the Maximum Drawdown Risk Measure

Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications

Continuous-Time Pension-Fund Modelling

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Optimal Selling Strategy With Piecewise Linear Drift Function

Transcription:

Drawdowns receding Rallies in the Brownian Motion Model Olympia Hadjiliadis rinceton University Department of Electrical Engineering. Jan Večeř Columbia University Department of Statistics. This version: April 19 006 Abstract We study drawdowns and rallies of Brownian motion. A rally is defined as the difference of the present value of the Brownian motion and its historical minimum while the drawdown is defined as the difference of the historical maximum and its present value. This paper determines the probability that a drawdown of a units precedes a rally of b units. We apply this result to examine stock market crashes and rallies in the geometric Brownian motion model. 1 Introduction In this paper we determine the probability that a drawdown precedes a rally in the Brownian motion model. The probabilities are computed by means of the distribution function of the random variables y + T 1 a and y T b where y+ T 1 a represents the value of the upward rally when the drawdown process reaches the level a for the first time and y T b represents the value of the drawdown when the upward rally process reaches the level b for the first time. Using the results of Taylor [1] and Lehoczky [5] concerning the distribution of a stopped drifted Brownian motion at the first time of the downfall of level a we are able to show that the probability density functions of y + T 1 a and y T b are exponential but with a discrete mass at 0. The paper concludes with a solution to the problem of computing the probability that a drop of 100 α% from the running maximum of a stock price occurs before a rally of 100 β% from its running minimum given that the stock price follows a geometric Brownian motion. Risk management of drawdowns and portfolio optimization with drawdown constraints is becoming increasingly important among the practitioners. Chekhlov et. al. [3] studied drawdown measures in porfolio optimization. Magdon-Ismail et. al. [6] determined the distribution of the maximum drawdown of Brownian motion. Our results are connected to a recent paper by Meilijson [7] where the results of Taylor [1] and Lehoczky [5] are used to derive the expected time to a given drawdown of Brownian motion as well as the stationary distribution of the drawdown process. An alternative derivation of the above expected value based on the expected delay of the CUSUM stopping time appears in Hadjiliadis & Moustakides [4]. The CUSUM stopping time was first proposed by age [9] and was used subsequently as a means of detecting a regime change in the Brownian motion model see Shiryaev [10] Beibel [] and Moustakides [8]. In the next section we first outline the main results of the paper. We then proceed to give an example of an application of these results in the examination of stock market crashes and rallies. We finally give some concluding remarks. 1

Results Consider the process X t with the following dynamics: X t = σw t + γt where γ σ R and W t is a standard Brownian motion process. The quantity X t inf s [0t] X s measures the size of the rally comparing the present value of the process to its historical minimum while the quantity sup X s X t s [0t] measures the size of the drawdown comparing the present value of the process to its historical maximum. The aim of this section is to determine the probability that a drawdown of size a precedes a rally of size b. We introduce the stopping times: and T 1 a = inf{t 0 : sup X s X t = a a R + } s [0t] T b = inf{t 0 : X t inf s [0t] X s = b b R + }. Consider the stopping time T a b = T 1 a T b. The stopping times T 1 a and T b indicate respectively the first time that the drawdown process reaches the critical level a T 1 a and the first time the upward rally process reaches the critical level b T b. In this section we compute the probabilities of the events {T a b = T 1 a} which represents the event that the drawdown of size a occurs before the rally of size b and {T a b = T b} which represents the event that the rally of size b occurs before the drawdown of size a. In order to simplify notation we introduce the following processes: m + t := inf s [0t] X s m t := inf X s = sup X s s [0t] s [0t] y + t := X t m + t y t := X t m t. Using the above notation the stopping times T 1 a and T b become T 1 a = inf{t 0 : y t = a a R + } T b = inf{t 0 : y + t = b b R + } Theorem.1 Let X t = σw t + γt be a standard Brownian motion with drift parameter γ R and variance parameter σ R; T T 1 and T be the stopping times defined above. We distinguish the following two cases:

1. b a > 0 The probability of the drawdown preceding the rally or the rally preceding the drawdown are given respectively by [ ] σ.1 T a b = T 1 a = m A + 1 m A 1 exp b a. where.3 T a b = T b = 1 m A exp e a 1 m A = e a + a 1. e a + e a e a 1 b a. a b > 0 The probability of the drawdown preceding the rally or the rally preceding the drawdown are given respectively by σ.4 T a b = T 1 a = 1 m B exp a b b.5 where.6 T a b = T b = m B + 1 m B m B = e b b 1 1 e σ [ 1 exp e b + e b The proof of the theorem uses the following proposition:. 1 e σ ] a b b roposition. The probability distribution functions of the random variables y + T 1 a and y T b are given by: 1..7.8 y + T 1 a = 0 = m A y + T 1 a dr = 1 m A [ e a 1 exp e a 1 ] r dr r > 0 where m A is given by equation.3...9.10 y T b = 0 = m B y T b dr = 1 m B where m B is given by equation.6. [ exp 1 e b 3 1 e ] r dr r > 0 b

Before we proceed to the proof of the two above results let us notice that all of equations.1..4.5.3.6 as well as the distributions of the random variables y + T 1 a and y T b as they appears in roposition. depend on the ratio. This ratio is called the adjustment coefficient and appears in the insurance risk literature see Asmussen [1]. To illustrate the probabilities that appear in Theorem.1 we include a graph of the densities of the random variables y + T 1 a and y T b see Figure 1. a b Figure 1: art a depicts the distribution of the random variable y + T 1 a and the gray area marks the T a b = T 1a in the case that b a. art b depicts the distribution of the random variable y and the gray area marks the T b T a b = T b in the case that a b. In order to prove roposition. and Theorem.1 we will need the following two lemmas. Lemma.3 For a b R + we have:.11.1 E [T 1 a] = e a a 1 E [T b] = e b + b 1. roof. Let gx = e x + x 1. By applying Itô s rule to the process gy + t we get.13 dgy + t = σg y + t dw t + γg y + t dt g y + t dm+ t + 1 σ g y + t dt. We notice that the third term in the right hand side of the above equality disappears because dm + t 0 only when y + t = 0 and g 0 = 0. We also notice that the function g satisfies the second order differential equation.14 Solving equation.13 we get:.15 γg x + 1 σ g x =. t gy t + g0 = σg y s + dw s + 0 4 t 0 γg y +t + 1 g y +t ds

Let S n = inf{t 0; t n}. Let T nb = T b S n. Obviously T nb is a.s. finite. On the event {T nb t} we have {y+ t Consequently [ ] T n b E g y s + ds g b.16 n <. 0 b}. Evaluating.15 at T n b and taking expectations while using equations.14 and.16 we get ] E [gy +T n b = E [T n b]. But.17 ] gb E [gy +T n b. Hence we have that gb E [T n b] [ ] E 1 {T n = }. Letting n and using the bounded convergence theorem we deduce that T b is finite a.s. as well. Evaluating both sides of equation.15 at T b and taking expectations of both sides while using equation.14 and the fact that the quadratic variation of the stochastic integral T b 0 g y + t dw t is finite this follows from equation.16 and the a.s. finiteness of T b we get.18 Consequently.19 gb = E [T b]. E [T b] = gb..0 Similarly we can show that This concludes the proof of the lemma. E [T 1 a] = g a. Lemma.4 We have y + t + y t = max{sup s t y s + sup ys }. s t roof. Observe that.1 y + t + y t = m + t m t. We notice that the process y + t +y t can only increase when either X t = m + t or X t = m t both of which cannot happen at the same time since that would imply that y + t + y t is 0. Therefore y + t + y t is a constant as a function of time unless either y + t = 0 or y t = 0 at which instant t we simultaneously have: 5

} 1. max{y t + y t {{sup } = max s t y s + sup s t ys }. sup s t y + s + y s = y + t + y t. This completes the proof of the lemma. As a consequence of this lemma we have..3 y + T 1 a = max t T 1 a y+ t a 0 y T b = max t T b y t b 0. Finally in order to proceed to the proof of roposition. and Theorem.1 we will use the results of Taylor in [1] and Lehoczky in [5]. Taylor computes the bivariate Laplace transform of X T1 a and T 1 a where T 1 is defined as above. Lehoczky pointed out that the random variable X T1 a + a = sup t T1 a X t has the exponential distribution:.4 X T1 a + a σ Exp e a 1 Note that the exponential parameter becomes equal to 1 a in the case when γ = 0. Now we can proceed to the proof of roposition. and then to the proof of Theorem.1. roof of roposition.. We will only compute the probability density function of the random variable y + T 1 a since the computation of the probability density function of the random variable y T b is done in a similar way. From equation. it follows that.5 y +T1a = 0. = max t T 1 a y+ t < a while.6 y +T1a dr = max t T 1 a y+ t a y + T 1 a dr = y +T1a > 0 max a y +T1a dr y+t1a > 0 r > 0. t T 1 a y+ t In the next discussion we first demonstrate.7 L y +T1a y+t1a > 0 = L X T1 a + a. To see this let.8 R 1 = sup{t T 1 a; y + t = 0}. 6

Fix r > 0. Then y +T1a dr y+t1a > 0 = = X T1 a inf s T1 a X s dr max t T1a y +t a = X T1 a X R1 +X R1 inf s T1 a X s dr R 1 <T 1 a R 1 <T 1 a max t T1 ax t X R1 +X R1 inf s t X s a R 1 <T 1 a R 1 <T 1 a X T1 a X R1 +X R1 inf s R1 X s dr R 1 <T 1 a max t T1 ax t X R1 +X R1 inf s R1 X s a R 1 <T 1 a = X T1 a X R1 dr R 1 <T 1 a = max R1 t T 1 a X t X R1 a R 1 <T 1 a = X T1 a X R1 dr R 1 <T 1 a max t T1 a X t X R1 a R 1 <T 1 a X T1 a dr max t T1 a X t a = λe λr e λa dr e λa = λe λr dr = X T1 a + a dr where λ =.9 1 e σ a. Therefore we get y +T1a dr y+t1a > 0 σ Exp r > 0. e a 1 From equation. it follows that.30 y + T 1 a T = 0 = 1 a < T a. To compute T 1 a < T a we first notice that.31.3 T 1 a = T a b + T 1 a T a b T b = T a b + T b T a b Taking expectations we get [.33 E [T 1 a] = E [T a b] + E T 1 a T a b [.34 E [T b] = E [T a b] + E T b T a b 1 {T ab=t b} 1 {T ab=t1 a}. 1 {T ab=t b} 1 {T ab=t1 a} With a = b and equation. it follows that.35 E [T 1 a] = E [T a a] + E [T 1 a] T a < T 1 a.36 E [T a] = E [T a a] + E [T a] T 1 a < T a. ] ]. Using T 1 a < T a + T a < T 1 a = 1 7

and equations.35 and.36 we conclude that.37 T 1 a < T a = E [T a] E [T a] + E [T 1 a]. The result now follows by substituting.9.30.37 into equations.6 and.5 while using Lemma.3. This completes the proof of roposition.. roof of Theorem.1. We will prove the theorem in the case that b a since the proof is similar in the case a b. Suppose that b a. From Lemma.4 and equation. it follows that on the event {T 1 a < T b} we have.38 y + T 1 a = { 0 if maxs T1 a y + s < a max s T1 a y + s a if a max s T1 a y + s < b. Therefore.39 T 1 a < T b = y + T 1 a = 0 + b a 0 + y + T 1 a dr and the result is obtained from roposition.. This completes the proof of Theorem.1. Corollary.5 Let X t = W t be a standard Brownian motion and let T T 1 and T be stopping times defined as above. We distinguish the following two cases: 1. b a > 0 The probability of the drawdown preceding the rally or the rally preceding the drawdown are given respectively by.40.41 T a b = T 1 a T a b = T b = 1 + 1 [ 1 e 1 b a] a = 1 e 1 a b a.. a b > 0 The probability of the drawdown preceding the rally or the rally preceding the drawdown are given respectively by.4.43 T a b = T 1 a T a b = T b = 1 e 1 b a b = 1 + 1 [ 1 e 1 a b] b. roof. It is a simple consequence of Theorem.1 by taking the limit as γ 0. Corollary.6 Let X t = W t be a standard Brownian motion. The probability distribution function of the random variables y + T 1 a and y T b are given by 8

1..44.45 y + T 1 a = 0 = 1 y + T 1 a dr = 1 [ ] 1 a e 1 a r dr r > 0...46.47 y T b = 0 = 1 y T b dr = 1 [ ] 1 b e 1 b r dr r > 0. roof. The above corollary is a consequence of roposition. by letting γ 0. A graph of the distribution of each of the random variables y + T 1 a and y T b appears in Figure below. a b Figure : art a depicts the distribution of the random variable y + T 1 a for γ = 0 and the gray area marks the T a b = T 1 a in the case that b a. art b depicts the distribution of the random variable y for γ = 0 and T b the gray area marks the T a b = T b in the case that a b. Example: Stock Market Crashes and Rallies. Suppose that we have a stock S t whose dynamics follow a geometric Brownian motion:.48 ds t = µs t dt + σs t dw t. What is the probability that this stock would drop by 100 α% before it incurs a rally of 100 β%? We can solve this problem by using Theorem.1. First observe that.49 S t = S 0 exp µ 1 σ t + σw t = S0 expσx t where X t = W t + µ σ t. Let U 1α be the first time the stock drops by 100 α% from its running maximum and U β be the first time the stock rallies by 100 β% from its running minimum. Let M t = sup S s 0 s t 9

and Notice that N t = inf S s. 0 s t.50 U 1 α = inf{t 0 : S t 1 αm t } and.51 U β = inf{t 0 : S t 1 + βn t } Thus = inf{t 0 : sup X s X t 1 σ log1 α} = T 1 1 σ log1 α 0 s t = inf{t 0 : X t inf X s 1 0 s t σ log1 + β} = T 1 σ log1 + β..5 U 1 α < U β = T 1 1 σ log1 α < T 1 σ log1 + β and we can apply Theorem.1 with the following parameters: a = 1 σ log1 α b = 1 σ log1 + β γ = µ σ. The resulting probability is given by:.53 U 1 α < U β = 1+β [ when α β 1+β and.54 U 1 α < U β = 1 1 α [ when α µ 1 ] + log1+β 1 µ 1 1+β [ µ 1 ] +1+β [ µ 1 ] µ 1 ] + log1 α 1 µ 1 1 α [ µ 1 ] +1 α [ µ 1 ] [1 α1 + β] [1 α1 + β] β 1+β. In the case when µ = 1 σ the above formulae simplify to.55 U 1 α < U β = 1 [1 α1 + β] 1 log1+β when α β 1+β and.56 U 1 α < U β = 1 1 [1 α1 + β] 1 log1 α when α β 1+β. µ 1 1 1+β [ µ 1 ] µ 1 1 1 α [ µ 1 ] 3 Concluding remarks In this paper we are able to compute the probability that a drawdown of size a occurs before an upward rally of size b in the drifted Brownian motion model and use this result to compute the probability that a drop of a given percentage α from the running maximum of a stock occurs before a rise of a given percentage β from the running minimum of a stock. 10

In the case of a more general model such as for example a general Markovian or non-markovian model there are some useful formulas that do result from renewal considerations but we might not be able to obtain closed form expressions as they appear in Theorem.1. To be more specific let us assume that we are in the case that b > a. Then the following equation holds regardless of the underlying model dynamics: 3.1 T b < T 1 a = T a < T 1 a T b < T 1 a T a < T 1 a where T a < T 1 a can be readily computed using equation.37. This equation in turn is computed using equations.35.36 both of which follow by a renewal type of argument and hold regardless of the underlying model. However the term T b < T 1 a T a < T 1 a will very clearly depend on the underlying model. This represents is the probability that the rally process y t + will reach level b before the drawdown process yt reaches level a given that y t + reached level a before yt did. That is the same as the probability that the underlying process travels an extra upward distance of b a before it drops below its running maximum by a units. We can hope for a closed form formula of this probability only in the case that the underlying process has independent increments. Notice that in case of independent increments both the drawdown process and the rally process are Markovian. However if the assumption of independent increments does not hold the above conditional probability will be path dependent in even in a Markovian model resulting in potentially complicated computations. Similarly it is important to notice that.7 is true regardless of the underlying model the proof of this result is also based on renewal type of arguments and appears in the long equation before.9. However the exact distribution of the X T1 a+a = sup t T1 a X t will heavily depend on the assumption of the underlying model. Our results can be applied in a straightforward way for diffusion models for which the distribution of sup t T1 a X t is explicitly known which is a fairly large class of diffusions see for instance Lehoczky [5]. As a consequence of the fact that our results address diffusion models that satisfy the conditions that appear in Lehoczky [5] important financial models of a mean-reverting character or drift-varying character with a constant adjustment coefficient are included. For instance the Cox- Ingersoll-Ross model for interest rates falls into this setting. From that perspective our results might be used quite universally. Moreover even in more general type of jump-models that result in fat-tailed distributions equations 3.1.37 as well as.7 all hold true and could be used as starting points in the estimation of the probabilities of the events in Theorem.1. Finally it is worth pointing out that using these results one can compute the expected time of the minimum of the stopping times T 1 a and T b. This is of great interest for detecting a regime change in the case of two-sided alternatives. Stopping times such as the minimum of T 1 a and T b resemble the -CUSUM stopping rule that has traditionally been used in the detection of regime changes in the presence of two-sided alternatives see for example Hadjiliadis & Moustakides [4] Tartakovsky [11]. 4 Acknowledgements Authors would like to thank Mark Brown Chris Heyde and Steven Shreve for helpful comments on this manuscript. We are also thankful to the publishing editor David Burgoyne and the two anonymous referees for the suggested improvements of this paper. The work of Jan Vecer was supported in part by the National Science Foundation grant DMS 0418457. 11

References [1] S. Asmussen. Ruin robabilities. Singapore; River Edge NJ: World Scientific 000. [] M. Beibel. A note on Ritov s Bayes approach to the minimax property of the CUSUM procedure. Annals of Statistics 44:1804 181 1996. [3] A. Chekhlov S. Uryasev and M. Zabarankin. Drawdown measure in portfolio optimization. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance 81:13 58 005. [4] O. Hadjiliadis and G. V. Moustakides. Optimal and asymptotically optimal CUSUM rules for change point detection in the Brownian motion model with multiple alternatives. Theory of robability and its applications Teoriya Veroyatnostei i ee rimeneniya 501:131 144 005. [5] J.. Lehoczky. Formulas for stopped diffusion processes with stopping times based on the maximum. Annals of robability 54:601 607 1977. [6] M. Magdon-Ismail A. F. Atiya A. ratap and Y. S. Abu-Mostafa. On the Maximum drawdown of a Brownian motion. Journal of Applied robability 411:147 161 004. [7] I. Meijilson. The time to a given drawdown in Brownian motion volume XXXVII of Seminaire de robabilites pages 94 108. Springer Verlag 003. [8] G. V. Moustakides. Optimality of the CUSUM procedure in continuous time. Annals of Statistics 31:30 315 004. [9] E. S. age. Continuous inspection schemes. Biometrika 41:100 115 1954. [10] A. N. Shiryaev. Minimax optimality of the method of cumulative sums CUSUM in the case of continuous time. Russian Mathematical Surveys 51:750 751 1996. [11] A. G. Tartakovsky. Asymptotically minimax multi-alternative sequential rule for disorder detection. Statistics and Control of Random rocesses: roceedings of the Steklov Institute of Mathematics 04:9 36 1994. American Mathematical Society rovidence Rhode Island. [1] H. M. Taylor. A stopped Brownian motion formula. Annals of robability 3:34 46 1975. 1