A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability

Similar documents
Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Problem Set 4 Answers

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level

Portfolio Choice and Permanent Income

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Characterization of the Optimum

EIEF/LUISS, Graduate Program. Asset Pricing

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720

EIEF, Graduate Program Theoretical Asset Pricing

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

+1 = + +1 = X 1 1 ( ) 1 =( ) = state variable. ( + + ) +

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Foundations of Asset Pricing

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Closure in CGE Models

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Lucas s Investment Tax Credit Example

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Rational Expectations and Consumption

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

The Cagan Model. Lecture 15 by John Kennes March 25

Math 1314 Week 6 Session Notes

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

1 The continuous time limit

Intermediary Balance Sheets Tobias Adrian and Nina Boyarchenko, NY Fed Discussant: Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, UC Berkeley

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot.

Lifetime Portfolio Selection: A Simple Derivation

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Lecture 3, Part 1 (Bubbles, Portfolio Balance Models)

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Final Exam YOUR NAME:. Your mail folder location (Economics, Booth PhD/MBA mailfolders, elsewhere)

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach Assume uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), which is implied by perfect capital substitutability 1.

Long-Run Mean-Variance Analysis in a Diffusion Environment

Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

1 The Solow Growth Model

MONETARY AND FINANCIAL MACRO BUDGET CONSTRAINTS

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution.

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Lecture 11. Fixing the C-CAPM

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Introduction to the Gains from Trade 1

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Inflation. David Andolfatto

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

1 Dynamic programming

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Transcription:

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability John H. Cochrane June 14, 2012 Abstract I solve a continuous-time asset pricing economy with quadratic utility and complex temporal nonseparabilities. University of Chicago Booth School of Business and NBER. 5807 S. Woodlawn, Chicago IL 60637, john.cochrane@chicagobooth.edu; http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/. I thank George Constantinides for helpful comments. I acknowledge research support from CRSP. 1

1 Introduction I solve a linear-quadratic economy and find asset prices in continuous time. I then extend the model to include a habit/durability process. This problem is much easier in continuous time and using the Hansen-Sargent (1991) prediction formulas. This problem applies the tools reviewed in Cochrane (2012). Those tools derive from Hansen and Sargent (1991), who extend the Hansen-Sargent (1980, 1981) methodology to continuous time. Heaton (1993) uses the same tools to solve the quantity dynamics of the models I present here. 2 Time-separable model The warmup problem is the standard quadratic utility permanent income model, with an AR(1) income stream, max 1 ( + ) 2 s.t. 0 2 (1) ( + ) (2) + One of the conveniences of continuous time is apparent: you don t have to worry about timing, whether investment made at joins the capital stock at and generates a return at +1, (finance timing) or whether investment made at sits a period before contributing to capital stock at + 1 (macroeconoimc timing). I find the equilibrium consumption process in level and differenced form, + + + Then, I find the price of the consumption stream, The result is or equivalently + 1 2 ( + ) 2 + + 1 2 ( + ) 2 The first term is the risk neutral term, as emphasized by its expansion in the last equality. The second term is a risk adjustment. The higher the variance of income, the lower the price. As approaches the quadratic utility investor gets more risk averse. At he s at bliss and doesn t want more consumption, so you can t induce him to take risk by giving him more consumption. So as rises to the price discount rises. 2

The price of the endowment stream has an identical risk correction, + + 1 2 ( + ) 2 + + 1 2 ( + ) 2 2.0.1 Model solution First, I show that the flow constraint (2) (together with limits on how fast capital can grow) imply the present value constraint + + + (3) R Quotes on present value because 0 consumption stream! 0 0 + is not the present value (price) of the risky To show this equivalence, write the flow budget constraint (2) as writing it out, ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) Applying to both sides, we obtain (3). 0 + 0 + Second, since the rate of return equals the discount rate, the basic asset pricing first order condition gives 0 0 + and hence ( + ) ( + ) ( )0. Thus, we know that 0 +(), with the latter loading depending on the resource constraint. Next, we substitute first order conditions + and the income forecast + into the resource constraint (3) to find the actual consumption process, + + + 3

This is the familiar permanent-income rule. + + To derive the random walk rule, you can just take differences of the last equation, + + ( + ) + + ( + ) + + + + ( + ) + and hence + + Z + (4) Both of these operations are prettier as instances of the Hansen-Sargent prediction formulas of course. The price of the consumption stream is + + I ll compute these by brute force, though one can also apply the Hansen-Sargent formulas. From (4), 1 + 2 + 2 + ( ) 1 2 + ³ 2 + 1 2 ( + ) 2 Similarly, we can find the price of the income stream, Income follows + + 2 2 0 + Z + + 4

so + Ã! ( + + ) 2 Z Ã! + 2 1 + 1 + + ³ 2 + 1 (1 ) (+) 2 1 ( + ) 1 + 2 1 ( + ) + 1 2 ( + ) 2 1 1 + 3 A model with habits and durability I generalize the linear-quadratic model to include a utility function with a rich temporal nonseparability. The quantity dynamics are solved by Heaton (1993), section 3.1, though I hope the notation here is a bit simpler. I extend Heaton s analysis to find asset prices. The consumer faces a linear capital accumulation technology and an AR(1) income stream as before. The consumer s problem is 2 max { } 2 () ( + ) + We can write the objective in operator form, 1 2 ( [1 + L ()] ) 2 (5) The present-value form of the resource constraint is, as before, + + + + + (6) We normally think of the nonseparability () as generating habit persistence or durability in consumption. If () 0, then past consumption contributes positively to current utility, as past durable goods purchases do. If () 0, then past consumption raises current marginal utility, as habit-forming goods do. 5

We can also use nonseparability for a different purpose: The habit/durability term shifts the bliss point, which controls risk aversion. When current consumption is closer to the composite bliss point, the consumer becomes more risk averse. Thus, temporal nonseparability allows us to control risk aversion and the cyclical behavior of asset prices. Controlling risk aversion is useful to making the linear quadratic model vaguely reasonable. One of its biggest problems with a fixed bliss point is that higher consumption makes the consumer more risk averse, where in reality we think risk aversion is likely independent of wealth in the long run, and rises in consumption relative to the recent past may make people less risk averse, as in the Campbell-Cochrane (1999) model. By moving the bliss point, we can capture both ideas, and thus make the linear-quadratic model a more useful approximation. As an example, I use a sum of two exponentials for the () function, so the problem is is In the operator notation of (5), max 1 { } 2 L () ( ) 2 + + + This formulation allows for both habit and durable effects. For example, consumption can be durable in the short run, but induce habits in the long run, with 0, 0,. Having included two exponentials, the generalization to an arbitrary sum of exponentials is clear. Here are the major results: The consumption process follows [1 + L ()] + [1 + L ()] You can see the natural generalization from the time separable case in which L () 0. Inthe double-exponential case, [ ( )+( )] + 1+ + + + (7) + Without nonseparabilities, consumption follows the familiar random walk. With nonseparabilities, marginal utility is still a random walk, but consumption is not, and adjusts towards ( 0) or away ( 0) from its recent past. The price of the consumption stream is 1 1+ L () L () [1 + L ()] ( ) [1 + L ()] 2 (8) [1 + L ()] + The first term is just the risk-neutral present value of the consumption stream, i.e. + 6

The second term in (8) is a discount for risk. In the double-exponential case the price of the consumption stream is 1 + + + + 1+ + + + ³ 1+ + + + 2 + In either general or special formulas, the first term is now more complex because consumption dynamics are complex, and the first term includes expected increases or decreases in consumption itself. The denominator in the second term is the interesting component. This term is still current marginal utility. This term shows us how risk premiums evolve over time. When is larger holding and constant, we still see risk aversion and the price discount rise. But now risk aversion is determined by relative to the habit or durable stock and,whichalsovary over time. This generalization can allow the model to to produce more realistic time series. The price of the endowment stream { } is similarly, In the double-exponential case, + [1 + L ()] 2 [1 + L ()] ( + ) 2 + h i 1+ + + + [ + + ] 2 ( + ) 2 The first term is again the risk neutral value, Z + + The second term reflects the same time-varying risk aversion as before, due to changing marginal utility at time. 3.0.2 Derivation First order conditions and consumption drift. The consumer s first-order conditions state that marginal utility is a martingale, + () + + () + (9) Taking the limit, marginal utility follows a random walk + () 0 I.e., we know that consumption follows a classic autoregressive process, which we can write either as (0) + 0 () + 7

or () + We don t know what is, which the resource constraint will tell us. In operator notation, marginal utility is so the first order condition is [1 + L ()] { [1 + L ()] } 0 The two autoregressive representations are potentially convenient rewritings of this condition [1 + L ()] [1+L ()] [ + (0) + L 0()] Internal vs. external nonseparabilities This first-order condition is the same whether the nonseparability is internal or external. If external, these are directly the first order conditions, in equilibrium where individual aggregate consumption. If internal, the marginal utility of consumption today includes its effects on future utility, Z () + + () + () The first order condition is now + () + + + () + + + + () + Now you can see that (9) is still a solution. Substitute it in to the last equation, () + + () + + + () () () + + () () + () () And hence () 1+ () + () + 1+ () () Resource constraint and consumption shocks. + () + 8

To find the response to shocks, I use the Hansen-Sargent prediction formulas. Hansen and Sargent (1991) show that if we express a process in moving-average form, () L () then we can find the moving average representation of the expected discounted value by L () L () + (10) The impact multiplier of the expected discounted value how it responds to a shock is lim L () L () L () (11) (See Cochrane (2012) for an accessible derivation.) Now, using the Hansen-Sargent response-to-shock formula (11), and the representation [1 + L ()] we have + () + 1 1 1+L () Differentiating the resource constraint (6), we obtain + + + + Comparing the two expressions, the impact multiplier satisfies 1 1+L () + + + + Therefore, + (1 + L ()) In sum, then, consumption follows the process (0) + 0 () + 1+ () + or, () + 1+ () + or, in operator notation, [ + L ()] + [1 + L()] We can write the same result by characterizing the marginal utility process, + () + 9 1+ () (12)

[1 + L ()] Consumption process, exponential case + [1 + L ()] (13) Expressing the state in terms of and is useful. Directly, (12) (13) are ( + + ) + [1 + L ()] (14) If we want to study consumption growth, we can substitute from (13) 1+ + + + 1 + + + 1 + + 1+ + + + Then, rewriting this in terms of the state variables and, [ ( )+( )] + Price of the consumption stream + + 1+ + + 1+ + + + (15) + The price of the consumption stream is [ + + R () + ] [ + R () + ] The formula simplifies if we recognize that marginal utility follows a random walk. Then + + () + + () + Z + (1 + L ()) + Substituting this result in the pricing formula, we have + + [1 + L Z ()] Z + + (16) [1 + L ()] Let s work on the first term. Using the Hansen-Sargent prediction formula and the operator expression for the consumption process, [ + L ()] + (1 + L ()) we have + (1+L ()) [1+L ()] (1+L ()) [1+L ()] + [1 + L ()] [1 + L ()] + ( ) [1 + L ()] [1 + L ()] [1 + L ()] 1 [1 + L ()] ( )[1+L ()] 10 1+ L () L () ( )

I can t get further in general, so using the double-exponential functional form, ³ ³ 1 + h i 1+ + + + + + + 1+ + + ( ) + " 1 2 h i 1+ + + 1+ ( + )( + ) + 2 # ( + )( + ) + + (+) + (+) 1+ + + 1 + Now for the second part. Start with the hard-looking part, Z + Actually, this is easy, and the risk adjustment term is quite general. Start with any consumption process, + Z + + Z + Z 1 L () () () Z () () 1 () Using our consumption process, h i [1 + L ()] + [1 + L ()] 1+ + + + h i + 1+ + + + we have h i + + 1+ + + + h i + 1+ + + 1 + + Now, adding back the other terms of (16), + [1 + L Z ()] Z + + [1 + L ()] + [1 + L ()] 1 [1 + L ()] + [1 + L ()] 2 [1 + L ()] + 11

Price of the endowment stream The price of the endowment stream is [ + + R () + ] [ + R () + ] Working analogously, we have + + () + + () + + (1 + L ()) + + [1 + L ()] [1 + L ()] + [1 + L ()] [1 + L ()] Z Z Z + 2 + + [1 + L Z ()] Z [1 + L ()] In the double-exponential case, 2 + + [1 + L ()] 1 1 [1 + L ()] 1 + + [1 + L ()] 2 [1 + L ()] ( + ) 2 + h i 1+ + + + [ + + ] 2 ( + ) 2 + + + 4 References Cochrane, John H., 2012, Continuous-Time Linear Models, Manuscript, University of Chicago, http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/papers/continuous time linear models.pdf Hansen, Lars Peter, and Thomas J. Sargent, 1991, Prediction Formulas for Continuous-Time Linear Rational Expectations Models Chapter 8 of Rational Expectations Econometrics, https://files.nyu.edu/ts43/public/books/tomchpt.8.pdf Hansen, Lars Peter, and Thomas.J. Sargent, 1980, Formulating and Estimating Dynamic Linear Rational-Expectations Models, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2, 7-46. Hansen, Lars Peter, and Thomas J. Sargent, 1981, A Note On Wiener-Kolmogorov Prediction Formulas for Rational Expectations Models, Economics Letters 8,: 255-260, Heaton, John, 1993, The Interaction Between Time-Nonseparable Preferences and Time Aggregation, Econometrica 61 353-385 http://www.jstor.org/stable/2951555 12