ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION, CREDIT RATIONING AND THE STIGLITZ AND WEISS MODEL

Similar documents
Reservation Rate, Risk and Equilibrium Credit Rationing

Chapter 2 Theoretical Views on Money Creation and Credit Rationing

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction

Rural Financial Intermediaries

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

How Do Banks Pick Safer Ventures? A Theory Relating the Importance of Risk Aversion and Collateral to Interest Margins and Credit Rationing

How to Measure Herd Behavior on the Credit Market?

Chapter 22: Division of Profit. Rate of Interest. Natural Rate of Interest

Development Economics 855 Lecture Notes 7

The role of asymmetric information on investments in emerging markets

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Moral Hazard and Risk Management. in Agri-Environmental Policy

Credit Lecture 23. November 20, 2012

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 12. Default Risk, Collateral and Credit Rationing

TIME VALUE OF MONEY AND DISCOUNTING IN ISLAMIC PERSPECTIVE. Islamic Research and Training Institute Islamic Development Bank, Jeddah.

International Journal of Advance Engineering and Research Development ACCESS TO RURAL CREDIT IN INDIA:

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov

DETERMINANTS OF AGRICULTURAL CREDIT SUPPLY TO FARMERS IN THE NIGER DELTA AREA OF NIGERIA

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Credit II Lecture 25

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending?

Research Note SEGMENTATION AND INTEREST RATE IN RURAL CREDIT MARKETS: SOME EVIDENCE FROM EASTERN UTTAR PRADESH, INDIA

The role of asymmetric information

EXAMPLE OF FAILURE OF EQUILIBRIUM Akerlof's market for lemons (P-R pp )

Investment 3.1 INTRODUCTION. Fixed investment

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission. Konstantinos Drakos, MacroFinance, Monetary Policy Transmission 1

Asymmetric Information and the Role of Financial intermediaries

Arindam Das Gupta Independent. Abstract

Discussion of A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector

research paper series

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Value-at-Risk Based Portfolio Management in Electric Power Sector

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT

Measuring the Benefits from Futures Markets: Conceptual Issues

Education Finance and Imperfections in Information

THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIARIES ON RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH. Philip Lowe. Research Discussion Paper 9213.

CHAPTER III RISK MANAGEMENT

Fiscal stimulus : A loanable funds critique. Author. Published. Journal Title. Copyright Statement. Downloaded from. Link to published version

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Suppose you plan to purchase

Investment and Financing Policies of Nepalese Enterprises

Financial Market Structure and SME s Financing Constraints in China

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

CONVENTIONAL FINANCE, PROSPECT THEORY, AND MARKET EFFICIENCY

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Economics and Finance,

Lecture Note 23 Adverse Selection, Risk Aversion and Insurance Markets

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Bank Credits and Agricultural Development: Does it Promote Entrepreneurship Performance?

Fuel-Switching Capability

Microeconomics (Uncertainty & Behavioural Economics, Ch 05)

UTI LlTY FUNCTIONS WITH JUMP DlSCONTlNUlTl ES: SOME EVIDENCE AND IMPLICATIONS FROM PEASANT AGRICULTURE

CEMARE Research Paper 167. Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE

Political Economy of Directed Credit

* CONTACT AUTHOR: (T) , (F) , -

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Stochastic Modelling: The power behind effective financial planning. Better Outcomes For All. Good for the consumer. Good for the Industry.

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

Loan Market Competition and Bank Risk-Taking

Monetary policy under uncertainty

INVESTORS PREFERENCES FOR INVESTMENT IN MUTUAL FUNDS IN INDIA

ASSET-PRICE BUBBLES AND MONETARY POLICY

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

The Effects of Information Asymmetry in the Performance of the Banking Industry: A Case Study of Banks in Mombasa County.

Financial markets in developing countries (rough notes, use only as guidance; more details provided in lecture) The role of the financial system

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

ON UNANIMITY AND MONOPOLY POWER

Business fluctuations in an evolving network economy

Liquidity. Why do people choose to hold fiat money despite its lower rate of return?

The Systematic Risk and Leverage Effect in the Corporate Sector of Pakistan

Optimization of a Real Estate Portfolio with Contingent Portfolio Programming

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

Asset specificity and holdups. Benjamin Klein 1

International Financial Markets Prices and Policies. Second Edition Richard M. Levich. Overview. ❿ Measuring Economic Exposure to FX Risk

Joint Liability, Asset Collateralization, and Credit Access

COLLATERAL S IMPORTANCE IN SMES FINANCING: WHAT IS THE BANKS RESPONSE? SOME EVIDENCE FOR ROMANIA

WORKING PAPER SERIES 2011-ECO-05

Determinants of Credit Rationing for Corporate Farms in Russia. Alexander Subbotin

Lecture Policy Ineffectiveness

A Study on Importance of Portfolio - Combination of Risky Assets And Risk Free Assets

Establishing the right price for electricity in South Africa. Brian Kantor with assistance from Andrew Kenny and Graham Barr

Greece and the Euro. Harris Dellas, University of Bern. Abstract

Demand, Segmentation and Rationing in the Rural Credit Markets of Puri RANJULA BALI SWAIN

Bankruptcy risk and the performance of tradable permit markets. Abstract

A Note on Competitive Investment under Uncertainty. Robert S. Pindyck. MIT-CEPR WP August 1991

Transcription:

ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION, CREDIT RATIONING AND THE STIGLITZ AND WEISS MODEL SANTONU BASU SCHOOL OF ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL STUDIES MACQUARIE UNIVERSITY 1992

Abstract The credit rationing literature that followed on from the asymmetric information constraint relies on two central tenets. One is referred to in the case when borrowers borrow with the preconceived notion that their probability to repay their loans is low and is known as the adverse selection effect. The other is based on the presumption that higher interest rates induce firms to switch from lower risk projects to higher risk projects, and is referred to as the incentive effect. They are described as mutually exclusive. It is argued in this paper that they are not mutually exclusive and either of these cases is likely to occur in a large scale, leading to the conclusion that this literature can at best provide an explanation for the special case of credit rationing only. 1

Asymmetric information, credit rationing and the Stiqlitz-Weiss Model By Santonu Basu In the last decade Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) in their classic paper titled "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information" provided a theoretical explanation why bankers ration credit. They argue that the interest rate that banks charge may itself affect the quality of loans, and therefore that the interest rate alone may not be capable of clearing the market. This conclusion they derive from two key effects, namely the adverse selection and incentive effects, both of which were based on the assumption that banks can sort borrowers according to the expected return on their investments but not according to the risk. Since their publication, a number of authors [DeMezza and Webb (1987), Bester (1985), Besanko and Thakor (1987) and Riley (1987)] have investigated the above subject matter within the framework of the asymmetric information constraint. Their findings are either contrary to, or claim less than, those of Stiglitz and Weiss. For example, De Mezza and Webb (1987) find that the presence of asymmetric information may lead to either an overestimation or an underestimation of risk, thereby leading to the possibility of an over or under allocation of credit. These findings are based on the assumption that banks cannot I would like to thank D. Collins for his helpful comments and suggestions. I alone am responsible for the final product. 2

distinguish among projects that can be ranked according to first order stochastic dominance. Bester (1985) assumes that banks decide upon the rate of interest and the collateral of their credit offers simultaneously, rather than separately, and concludes that in equilibrium no-one will be denied credit. On the other hand, Riley finds that even if credit rationing occurs due to the adverse selection effect, in each risk pool, "only in a single marginal pool could rationing ever be observed" (1987, p.224). A similar conclusion is derived by Besanko and Thakor (1987) who tested the model with respect to two types of market structures and found that at best the model can capture a rationing market which is less than the observed level. A contradictory result might have resulted from changes in assumptions. However the paramount question remains that even if the rationing occurs due to the presence of asymmetric information, why do we observe rationing which is less than that which occurs in the real world? It will be argued in this paper that Stiglitz and Weiss address the uncertainty that arises from informational asymmetry. In this case, it refers to the risk that is essentially associated with an individual's preferences and attitudes towards risk which are not known to the banker, with the result that uncertainty emerges. But Stiglitz and Weiss do not address the uncertainty that arises from the time duration that is involved between the borrower's intention and his success. It thereby excludes from the model 3

the uncertainty that arises from unpredictable changes in macroeconomic variables and from internal competition among firms, factors which influence the success of the project. Thus their model is not based on an investigation of factors that determine the risk of projects, nor does it investigate whether the changes in the interest rate affect the riskiness of the project. However, given the risk of each respective project, risk differentials between projects play a crucial role in determining the riskiness of the loan. This is expressed through the assumption of the incentive effect, that is, changes in the interest rate introduce the possibility of switching from lower risk to higher risk projects. Thus the non-disclosure of information mainly refers to the case when borrowers do not reveal their intention as to whether or not they will switch between projects in the event of changes in the interest rate. However, when this possibility evaporates due to the involvement of a high switching cost between projects, the importance of adverse selection emerges. This is because a higher interest rate reduces the borrower's net expected rate of return in the event of a successful outcome of the project. This suggests that the demand for loans should fall. However, under this circumstance, if any borrowers ask for a loan, this implies that those borrowers must be borrowing with a preconceived notion that their probability of repaying the loan is low. Thus, the two assumptions are mutually exclusive and this provides an explanation why in the presence of an excess demand for loans, bankers, instead of raising the interest rate, may ration credit. 4

However, it will be shown (or argued) that when the large pool of borrowers cannot switch between projects due to the presence of a high switching cost, they do not fall within the domain of the adverse selection effect. This is because the fundamentals of the adverse selection effect are violated. That is, the proposition that borrowers are less likely to lose in the event of a project failure does not in general apply to those who are already engaged in a project. This excludes a very large pool of borrowers who may have been rationed due to changes in the interest rate, and this cannot be explained within the framework of the asymmetric information constraint model. I Different borrowers have different probability pay-off attributes and these attributes may be personal characteristics, as in Jaffee and Russell (1976), or some parameter of any earning distribution, as in Stiglitz and Weiss (1981). However, lenders know less than borrowers about borrowers' probability of payoff attributes. Thus the presence of informational asymmetry is likely to have an impact on the functioning of the credit market. In the presence of an uncertain outcome, as individuals' attitudes towards risk are largely influenced by their own pecuniary (i.e. financial) situations, it is reasonable to argue that those who have less to lose in the event of an unsuccessful venture will be more willing to undertake risk. It is on the basis of this premise that the central conclusion emerging from Stiglitz and Weiss is that the interest rate that banks charge may itself affect the quality of loans, and that the interest 5

rate alone may not be capable of clearing the market. Therefore a form of credit rationing must occur. This conclusion is derived from the following two key assumptions. The first is that different levels of interest rate attract different types of borrowers with different probabilities of repaying the loan. Thus a combination of borrowers may change adversely in the event of changes in the interest rate. This is based on the presumption that the higher interest rate may attract borrowers who have a preconceived notion that their probability of repaying loans is low. Thus a higher interest rate in general may attract more risky borrowers. This effect is referred to as the adverse selection effect. The second assumption is that the interest rate on loans reduces investors' retainable rate of return on a project that succeeds, so that a higher interest rate may induce firms to undertake projects whose rate of return is high but which have a lower probability of success. This assumes a linear relationship between risk and return, i.e. a risky project offers a higher rate of return with a lower probability of success, thus representing a lower probability of repayment. This is referred to as the incentive effect. Both effects stem directly from the residue of asymmetric information which persists, even after the evaluation of the loan applications. Both effects emerge as a result of the non-coincidental interest between banks and borrowers. This in turn creates difficulties for banks to distinguish between risky and relatively less risky borrowers. 6

Nor do the banks have much control over borrowers' actions. Stiglitz and Weiss argue that as the interest rate itself affects the riskiness of loans (i.e. the quality of loans), it is possible to introduce the interest rate as a screening device through which banks may be able to distinguish between risky and relatively less risky borrowers. That is, as interest rates rise the average riskiness of the loan increases, thereby reducing banks' expected profitability. Consequently, this implies that the supply of loans is a decreasing function of the interest rate. That is, the initial increase in the interest rate may raise the supply of loans as it increases the banks' expected profitability. However they are not represented by a monotonic relationship. Beyond a certain point, as interest rates rise, banks' expected profitability increases at a declining rate, reaches an optimal point and then falls as interest rates rise. The optimal point is where the banks' expected profitability equals the interest rate. This is defined as the equilibrium point, see Figure 1. 7

However at Z an excess demand for loans may persist, 1 leading to a further rise in interest rates. Consequently interest rates exceed the expected profitability of bankers. Thus banks refuse to lend beyond this equilibrium point, as banks' expected profitability falls, as shown in the above figure. Thus beyond a certain point, even if the interest rate increases, or even if there is an excess demand for loans in the market, banks will refuse to lend. This is because as explained, the interest rate itself affects the nature of the loan transaction (i.e. the quality of loans) and consequently price may not clear the market, as banks attempt to minimise the difference between their anticipated and actual rates of return. II A careful examination of the above two assumptions will suggest that the interest rate can only be useful as a screening device to distinguish between risky and less risky borrowers, when borrowers' behaviour is the only factor that determines the riskiness of loans. In all other cases a difficulty remains in deploying the interest rate as a screening device, even though it may affect the quality of loans. This raises questions in relation to the applicability and the validity of these two assumptions, which are now examined. Firstly, the assumptions presume that those who are willing to borrow at a higher interest rate do so because they have a pre- conceived 1 The excess demand for loans may persist either due to businessmen's higher expected rate of return or due to a higher demand for. working capital in order to prevent the collapse of businesses. 8

notion that their probability to repay the loan is low. This raises the issue that if individuals borrow with this preconceived notion that their probability to repay the loan is low, why will they be concerned with the level of interest rates? This may suggest that changes in the interest rate in either direction should not affect the total number of risky borrowers. Rather it should only affect the number of less risky borrowers, that is, a higher interest rate will induce less risky borrowers to leave the loan market, whilst a lower interest rate will attract relatively less risky borrowers. Thus, although changes in the interest rate affect the combination of borrowers, they do not affect the total number of risky borrowers. The total number of risky borrowers remains unaltered in any pool of borrowers, irrespective of the level of interest rates. This indicates that when interest rates affect the combination of borrowers adversely, the total number of borrowers falls too. This may be directly attributed to the inverse relationship between interest rates and the demand for loans. The above argument is similar to the conclusion reached by Freimer and Gordon i.e. offering higher interest rates would not generate much demand,...while it may encourage borrowers to negotiate loans within this limit at a lower interest rate (1965, p.416). Alternatively we can say that this leaves only the most risky borrowers remaining in the pool of loan applicants and it is only they who are left to be rationed, since it is only they who have an excess demand. Consequently, this allows Riley to conclude that...the extent of rationing implied by S-W model is not likely to be very important empirically (1987 p.226). 9 9

This leaves us with the incentive effect. Stiglitz and Weiss argue that a higher interest rate induces firms to undertake projects whose expected return is high with a lower probability of success. This argument is similar to Allias's paradox. Allias argues that decision makers show a strong preference for the risk aversion principle when choosing between the proximity of certainty and an uncertain outcome. However, preferences change when decision makers are confronted with two projects which both offer uncertain outcomes. Decision makers in general show a strong preference for more risky ventures. This is especially in the case when risk differentials between two projects are marginal, but return differentials are great in the event of success. This principle implies that when the interest rate increases, this reduces borrowers' expected net return, and all things being equal, this will change the balance of the risk/return relationship. That is, a reduction in the expected net return will change the relative position of the risk. Thus when a project is relatively risky in relation to the net return it offers, this may induce the person to switch to a higher risk project where the net return is high in the event of success. From the above analysis, it follows that the selection of a project varies with the level of interest rates. This is possible for those who are considering a number of projects but have not committed themselves to any particular one. However this may not be applicable for those who are already committed to a particular project, because it is necessary for them to take into consideration the selection and switching costs of the project. The issue of the switching cost arises mainly as a 10

result of the fact that investment expenditures are largely irreversible. That is, they are mostly sunk costs and therefore cannot be recovered. Thus if a firm wishes to switch from a low return to a high return project, (which means switching from one industry to another industry), it must take into consideration the net loss that would accrue due to the sunk cost from the old project. This is because a firm's capital (i.e. plant and equipment), marketing techniques and advertising techniques are all specific to that industry. They will therefore have little or no use in other industries, and so in their present form they are sunk costs. In principle a firm should be able to sell its plant and equipment to any other firm which is involved in that specific industry. However, as the value of plant and equipment will be about the same for all firms within that industry, it is unlikely that one firm will gain much if anything at all from selling it. Furthermore, in the event of changes in the interest rate, if a firm considers that its current project's net rate of return is not sufficiently high due to high interest rates, then this view should be shared by all firms within that industry. Therefore all firms from that industry would have the same inducement effect, that is they all would like to switch from low return to high return projects. In these circumstances, firms will either have no buyers for their plant and equipment, or will be forced to sell well below its current market value in order to induce other firms to buy it. In either case it suggests that a switch between projects involves substantial loss to a firm, due to the 11

irreversible cost. It follows that once the incorporation of the switching cost as well as the selection cost is completed, that firm's net expected rate of return may not rise sufficiently to induce them to switch from low return to high return projects, even when the new project offers a higher expected rate of return. 2 This suggests that switching between projects in the event of changes in the interest rate is possible provided it is assumed that capital is malleable, since malleable capital does have properties that eliminate the additional costs involved in switching. However Garegnani (1983) argues that at any given instant available physical capital cannot be fluid, so it cannot take an appropriate form to adjust to the new level of interest rates. The above argument therefore implies that it is unlikely that existing firms who are already committed to projects will be able to switch from projects with low returns to projects with higher returns, without incurring heavy expenses. The risk of default may therefore remain high in the event of high interest rates, irrespective of the choice of project, i.e. whether they choose to remain in the old project or switch to a new one. Furthermore, the higher expected rate of return and the risk are not the only two criteria on the basis of which entrepreneurs select their projects. They are also influenced by their knowledge and familiarity with that project. In most cases, entrepreneurs do not have sufficient information in relation to 2 For further details see Pindyck (1991). 12

all projects available to them, leading them to select the project they know best, and this is to some extent irrespective of the level of interest rates. These two cases suggest that limitations in the selection of a project remain even after changes in the interest rate, due either to unfamiliarity with the other available projects or to the additional cost involved in switching form one project to another. This leaves Stiglitz and Weiss with a relatively small number of firms who are not committed to any projects and therefore able to switch between projects. On the other hand, firms which are already committed to a project are unlikely to fall within the adverse selection model. These firms have invested a considerable amount of their own resources and energy and are unlikely to be in a situation where they have less to lose in the event of the failure of their project. In addition, if the fact is considered that firms in general have to provide collateral or some form of security in order to obtain loans, then the argument of having less to lose disappears. Furthermore, as the loan market operates on the basis of trust and past track records (or the borrower's standing position with the lending authority), those who borrow with a preconceived notion that their probability to repay the loan is low cannot be considered as characteristic of the general borrowing population, since this default would eliminate the possibility of these borrowers obtaining future loans. No matter how we examine the problem of adverse selection, it does not appear to be a realistic assumption. It applies only in 13

special situations, where firms know that without a loan there is certainty that the business will collapse but that with a loan there is a slim possibility of survival. Even under these circumstances, it is unlikely a firm will borrow with such a preconceived notion, as it would be better to sell the business to minimize the loss, thereby preserving the individual's track record as a sensible businessman. This then may suggest that, even if the adverse selection effect or incentive effect occurs due to changes in the interest rate, these effects are likely to occur only among a small proportion of the total borrowing population. Thus the rationing that is generated by Stiglitz and Weiss's model is unlikely to represent the extent of rationing occurring in the real world. III Stiglitz and Weiss's model is based on the asymmetric information constraint. This constraint refers to those problems that arise mainly due to non-disclosure of information. In this case uncertainty for bankers results mainly from the fact that borrowers do not disclose all the necessary information required by banks in the evaluation of the risk involved in each loan. Thus borrowers know more about their probability of loan repayment than do bankers. This provides us with two possible situations where banks can either overestimate or underestimate risk, thereby leading to either an under-or over-allocation of credit. Banks will be mainly concerned about the underestimation of risk. To avoid this underestimation, bankers are required to investigate 14

borrowers' current rates of return, or the total volume of their yearly sales and their size of operation. However, in the absence of any indirect avenue to obtain such information, bankers may have to rely upon borrowers' honesty. In fact borrowers may provide misleading information, distorting and diffusing the bankers' process of risk evaluation, leading to deceptive information in relation to the probability of loans repayment. Bankers are left with only one option and that is to investigate individuals' attitudes toward risk, and whether their attitudes toward risk change when the interest rate increases. Thus the importance of adverse selection and incentive effects come into play. However, the problem is that this overlooks the other factors that also contribute to the determination of the individuals' total risk and thereby leaves out an important vehicle through which one can in general distinguish between relatively less risky and riskier borrowers. For example, as every firm in a industry competes with its rivals in order to increase its own market share, competition among firms may bring about a unforeseen risk of failure for any firm. Given the market demand, if an individual firm is able to increase its own share, it would mean some other firm may not be able to increase its own share as originally anticipated. As a matter of fact some firms may even lose their share. If all firms have equal shares or equal size of operations, then each individual firm will have an equal chance of increasing or losing its own share. Thus risk could be equally distributed, and project risk and firm 15

risk may become identical. Consequently firms' risk could be represented by project risk only. If firms within an industry do not have equal shares, the probability of each individual firm losing or increasing its own share in the market will differ between firms, so that risk could not be distributed equally. That is, some firms may present a greater risk than others within the industry. Thus the risk that is generated by internal competition, whether it will be equally distributed or unequally distributed among firms within the industry, will be determined by the specific market structure. As modern industry is mostly represented by some form or another of oligopolistic phenomena, it is not viable to ignore the risk that emerges from specific competitive market structures. The existence of differential scales of operation within the industry introduces the possibility for firms of unequal size to obtain heterogeneous rates of return and to have different probabilities of obtaining these rates. Thus, given that the estimated mean value of unequally sized firms represents different values of variance associated with their earnings, unequally sized firms would represent different levels of risk. This implies that the mean value of a project is an average value of all firms within the industry, thus hiding a significant variation within the estimated mean value, and also the probability of obtaining such a value. It follows that an individual's size of operation, in relation both to his competitors and to the total size of the market, has an important bearing upon determining the degree of his risk in relation to 16

the project risk, that is, whether the individual is above or below the mean value of the project risk. This suggests that an individual's risk cannot be represented purely by considering the mean value of the project risk. In fact the size of operation appears to be an important criterion for banks to use in order to decide to whom to lend, and how much to lend, as is evidenced by the fact that smaller sized firms always have less access to the loan market. Furthermore, when the interest rate increases it is normally the smaller sized firms whose access to the loan market is reduced. This was observed in the United States between 1955-57, when both the demand for loans and the interest rate remained high, and banks refused to lend to small business [Grey and Brockie (1959), Basu (1989)]. 3 Grey and Brockie noted that during the period from 1955-57 when the interest rate was generally rising, it rose less for smaller-sized firms while, at the same time, the volume of borrowing by smaller-sized firms did not increase to the same extent as that by larger enterprises (1959, p.340). One may tend to conclude that perhaps the smaller firms are more interest elastic than larger firms. However, evidence suggests that the credit-worthiness of the borrower may remain as the primary importance in credit allocation. This was based on the observation which suggests that the young firm has a greater 3 See also Japelli (1990), where the author found that individuals' access to loans is largely determined by their income. Thus a general rise in interest rates, while income is held constant, will naturally reduce access to the loan market for those who receive a lower income. 17

demand for. funds than the older firm because it is expanding more rapidly in size and the young firm is generally a small firm. (Grey and Brockie, 1959 pp. 339-40). It is difficult to conclude from the above observation whether or not the higher interest rate affected the aggregate supply of loans, but there is no evidential difficulty in concluding that the higher interest rate at least affected the distribution of loans. The distribution of loans is largely affected by the expected adverse impact on the smaller borrower which is caused by a higher interest rate. This is because banks believe that smaller and some medium size borrowers' average future profit may not be sufficient to cover the interest rate. This course of action by banks follows from two probable beliefs. The first is that smaller or medium sized firms will be unable to capture a sufficient share of the growing market. This is due to the presence either of large firms or of too many small firms with easy entry which prevents smaller and medium sized firms from enhancing their income enough to pay the higher interest rate. The second belief is that the higher demand for products leading to a higher price in general is also accompanied by a higher input price, so that if the share of the market does not increase sufficiently to offer the advantage of economies of scale in the use of inputs, then the expected profit from these businesses may not rise sufficiently to cover the interest bill. Neither of the above cases suggests that banks' denial of loans to smaller and medium size business arises from the adverse selection effect and incentive effect. Rather it occurs due to 18

the fact that this sector has a history of high failure rates, so that banks in general have less interest in lending to them. Furthermore, during the high interest rate period, banks become more concerned about the difficulties of small firms in meeting the interest cost. Stiglitz and Weiss have ignored this issue. This may be because of the fact that it is not possible to address the risk that emerges from the size of operation or from the specific competitive market structure within the asymmetric information framework. Thus it remains that these authors analyse credit rationing by considering the mean value of the project risk as representative of the individual's risk. Consequently, the possibility of switching from lower risk to higher risk projects remains the only plausible reason for bankers to ration credit when the interest rate changes. However, when the switching possibility disappears due to the irreversible cost, Stiglitz and Weiss's model cannot explain why bankers ration credit when the interest rate increases. Besanko and Thakor (1987) have investigated credit rationing by incorporating the market structure, with reference to the lender's monopoly and a perfectly competitive market structure, but were unable to generate much rationing. This is because they also assume that the project risk and borrowers' risk are identical. That is, if we assume that the borrower is a monopoly firm the firm's risk will be represented by the project risk. On the other hand if we assume that borrowers operate under a perfectly competitive market, then by assumption, any variation 19

in the size of operation is eliminated. Again, project risk can be used as representative of the firms' risk. It is no wonder that Besanko and Thakor too found that the extent of rationing that is generated by their model or by Stiglitz and Weiss's model is less than that observed in the real world. At the beginning of this paper it was mentioned that asymmetric information does not address the risk and uncertainty that arise due to the time between the borrower's intention and his success. Intention is generally influenced by past and current experience, and in this case, the decision to invest in any particular I project is determined by the past and current outcome of the project and by the investor's familiarity with such a project. Thus, the project risk is calculated on the basis of objective information available at that time. However, once the decision is taken to invest in such a project or in another project, objective information alone is no longer valid for the purpose of estimating future risk. This is because we do not have factual information concerning the future values of those variables whose movements will ultimately determine the project outcome. Calculation of risk for a project's future outcome involves projecting forward in time, not moving backward in time. Risk that is past can be calculated with objective information, but in the case of future risk we do not have factual information, and consequently risk calculation is essentially based on subjective evaluation. It is because of this factor that even after the evaluation of a loan application or a project evaluation one cannot determine the precise magnitude of the risk involved in such a project. 20

Asymmetric information attempts to address the risks that are associated with the past, that is, the information is there but uncertainty emerges because borrowers do not reveal the total information in relation to the project's past and current performance as well as their true intention. For example, suppose a farmer is borrowing for a seed plantation. The farmer knows that he should not plant a high yielding variety in nonirrigated land nor should he plant drought resistance seeds in irrigated land. He also knows which seed should be planted in which season. Planting seeds in unsuitable land and in an unsuitable season will influence the outcome of his output, thereby affecting the riskiness of the loan. This information is known to the farmer from his past experience but he does not reveal it to the lender, when he provides a general outline of the project. Thus, the way the farmer will implement his project is not known to the lender nor can the lender monitor it. According to Stiglitz and Weiss's model it could be argued that changes in the interest rate that reduce the farmer's net return may provide an incentive for farmers to switch from one seed to another, which has a higher probability of failure but which in the event of success will produce a greater yield. Thus, a higher interest rate introduces the possibility of the emergence of the adverse selection and incentive effects. It is doubtful whether the actual farmer would behave in this way. However, we can give good reasons why farmers in general would not behave in this manner even when the interest cost increases. 21

The farmer's net rate of return may be reduced due to higher interest costs, but there is still some return and this allows the farmers to enjoy ownership of their own land. Switching to a more risky seed exposes them to the possibility of losing their land, since they have to mortgage part of it to obtain the loan. Observation reveals that farmers in general by nature prefer to avoid risk just like businessmen. It took quite a significant time for the government of India to convince farmers that the high yielding variety programme would benefit them. Similarly, Australian farmers during the mid-1980s when they knew farming did not have a good future in Australia, did not sell their property and invest in the money market nor in government bonds that would earn more income than they derived from their current occupation. They held on to their land because farming was what they knew best. Thus, it is extremely unlikely a farmer will undertake more risky projects in the event of changes in the interest rate. Most businessmen as well as farmers prefer techniques and projects that they know best. Consequently, technological diffusion or new product introduction take longer periods to introduce and bankers also show their reluctance to lend for the adoption of a new technique or a new product. This then may explain why a banker does not take much interest in how a farmer or a businessman will implement a project, or in f monitoring the business. In addition, monitoring a business requires specific knowledge about that business which most bankers lack. 22

What are the factors that introduce risk and uncertainty in relation to a project's outcome? The main risk and uncertainty for farmers, for example, emerges from the unpredictable nature of the weather affecting output and the future output price. Future price is not only determined by the price of production (i.e. cost of production plus mark-up, where mark-up includes interest cost as well), but also by the demand conditions prevailing at that time. These are known neither to the farmer nor to the banker. These uncertainties mainly emerge due to the time duration between the planting of seeds and the harvest, within which time many conditions may change thereby either affecting the output or the price. Even if the farmer revealed all his information to the bankers, neither the farmer nor the banker would be able to determine the precise magnitude of the risk involved in each loan. It is this fact that will influence the design of contracts, rather than the adverse selection and incentive effects. Accordingly, bankers ask for collateral or security against loans. Thus, access to the loan market is not only determined by the borrowers' willingness to pay the interest rate, but whether they can provide the required collateral and their standing position with the banking authority. This then may suggest that in addressing the issue of why bankers ration credit, it may be necessary to ask why the interest rate alone can determine the distribution of loans rather than why stickiness is observed in the interest rate. It is the analysis which may allow development of a theory that may explain the extent of rationing that exists in the loan market. 23

References Allias, M. (1987) - "Allias Paradox" in New Palcrrave A Dictionary of Economics, Vol 1, ed. by J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman, MacMillan. Andrews P.W.S. (1951) - "A further Inquiry into the effects of Rates of Interest" in Oxford Studies in the Price Mechanism, ed. by Wison, T. and Andrews P.W.S., Oxford at the Clarendon Press. Basu S. (1989) "Deregulation, Small Business Access to the Capital Market - Theoretical Issues with Special Reference to Australian Bank Finance", Australian Economic Papers Vo1.28, pp.141-159. Besanko D. and Thakor A.V. (1987) "Collateral and Rationing: Sorting Equalibria in Monopolistic and Competitive Credit Markets", International Economic Review, Vol. 28 pp 671-689. Bester H. (1985). "Screening vs Rationing in Credit Market with Imperfect Information", American Economic Review, Vol 75, pp.850-55. Blinder A. and Stiglitz J. (1983), "Money Credit Constraint and Economic Activity", American Economic Review, Vol 73 pp 297-302. De Mezza D. and Webb D.C. (1987), "Too Much investment: A Problem of Asymmetric Information" Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol 102. pp 281-292. 24

Freimer M. and Gordon M. (1965), "Why Bankers Ration Credit" Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 79 pp 397-416. Garegnani P. (1983), "Notes on Consumption Investment and Effective Demand" in Keynes's Economics and the Theory of Value and Distributions ed. by J. Eatwell and M. Milgate, Duckworth. Grey A.L. and Brockie J.M.D. (1959), "The rate of Interest, Marginal Efficiency of Capital and Investment Programming A rejoinder", Economic Journal, Vol 69, pp 333-343. Jaffee D.M. and Russell T. (1976), "Imperfect information, uncertainty and Credit Rationing" Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 90 pp 651-666. Jaffee D.M. and Stiglitz J. (1990) - "Credit Rationing" in Handbooks of Monetary Economics, B Briedman and F. Hahn (eds.), Vol.II, North Holland. Japelli T. (1990), "Who is credit constrained in the U.S. Economy?" Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 105, pp 219-234. Pindyck R.S. (1991) "Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment", Journal of Economic Literature Vol. 29, pp 1110-1148. Riley J. (1987), "Credit Rationing: A further remark", American Economic Review, Vol 77, pp 224-231. 25

Stiglitz J.E. and Weiss A. (1981), "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information", American Economic Review Vol 71, pp.393-410. Stiglitz J.E. and Weiss A. (1987), "Credit Rationing: Reply" American Economic Review, Vo1.77 pp.228-231. 26