Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence. David Autor, MIT Department of Economics

Similar documents
Lecture Demand Functions

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

PROBLEM SET 3 SOLUTIONS. 1. Question 1

Lecture 4 - Theory of Choice and Individual Demand

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Chapter 4. Our Consumption Choices. What can we buy with this money? UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010

Utility Maximization and Choice

Lecture 2 Consumer theory (continued)

Part I. The consumer problems

Journal of College Teaching & Learning February 2007 Volume 4, Number 2 ABSTRACT

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

Intro to Economic analysis

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

Lecture 5 - The Expenditure Function, with an Application to Gift Giving

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Answer Key Practice Final Exam

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency.

MICROECONOMICS II Gisela Rua 2,5 hours

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 3: Demand Theory Applications

Demand and income. Income and Substitution Effects. How demand rises with income. How demand rises with income. The Shape of the Engel Curve

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

CONSUMER OPTIMISATION

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Intermediate microeconomics. Lecture 1: Introduction and Consumer Theory Varian, chapters 1-5

Economics 101A Spring A Revised Version of the Slutsky Equation Using the Expenditure Function or, the expenditure function is our friend!

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

ECON Micro Foundations

MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell

AAEC 6524: Environmental Economic Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Introduction to Non-Market Valuation Part A. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2017

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

a. (4 points) What is the MRS for the point on Bobby s demand curve when the price of snacks is $0.50? Show your work.

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

Microeconomics. The Theory of Consumer Choice. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich update C H A P T E R

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

EconS 301 Written Assignment #3 - ANSWER KEY

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009

Homework # 2 EconS501 [Due on Sepetember 7th, 2018] Instructor: Ana Espinola-Arredondo

Introduction to economics for PhD Students of The Institute of Physical Chemistry, PAS Lecture 3 Consumer s choice

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 3 Solutions

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

3. Consumer Behavior

Lesson: DECOMPOSITION OF PRICE EFFECT. Lesson Developer: Nehkholen Haokip & Anil Kumar Singh. Department/College: Shyamlal College (Eve)

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Characterization of the Optimum

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

The Theory of Consumer Choice. UAPP693 Economics in the Public & Nonprofit Sectors Steven W. Peuquet, Ph.D.

The objectives of the producer

ECN 2001 MICROECONOMICS I SLUTSKY EQUATION Class Discussion 6 (Ch. 7) - Answer Key TRUE-FALSE

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION AND WELFARE EVALUATION WITH NON-CONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE. DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, LONG BEACH

Principle of Microeconomics

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

14.54 International Trade Lecture 20: Trade Policy (I)

ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring Lecture notes 03 Applications of Revealed Preferences

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

Section 2 Solutions. Econ 50 - Stanford University - Winter Quarter 2015/16. January 22, Solve the following utility maximization problem:

Lecture notes 02 Price and Income Effects

ECONOMICS 100A: MICROECONOMICS

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Introduction. The Theory of Consumer Choice. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 28 February 2008.

Chapter 6 DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Microeconomics (Week 3) Consumer choice and demand decisions (part 1): Budget lines Indifference curves Consumer choice

MIDTERM EXAM ECON 210 PROFESSOR GUSE

Eliminating Substitution Bias. One eliminate substitution bias by continuously updating the market basket of goods purchased.

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices

Lecture 10: Two-Period Model

Transcription:

Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence David Autor, MIT Department of Economics 1

1 Normal, Inferior and Giffen Goods The fact that the substitution effect is always negative but the income effect has an ambiguous sign gives rise to three types of goods: X 1. Normal good: > 0, X I p x U =U0 < 0. For this type of good, a rise in its price and a decline in income have complementary effects less consumption. Although we only observe the movement from C 1 to C 2 measured along the x-axis), we can conceive of this movement as having two parts: the movement from C 1 to S along the x-axis substitution effect) and the movement from S to C 2 along the x-axis income effect). X 2. Inferior good: < 0, X I U=U. p 0 < 0 For this type of good, the income and substitution effects are countervailing. Although both derivatives have the same sign, x they have opposite effects because a rise in price reduces real income thereby increasing consumption through the income effect while reducing consumption through the substitution effect. 2

Here, the substitution effect is the S C 1 and the income effect is C 2 S both along the x-axis). 3. Strongly inferior good Giffen good). X < 0, X 0 I U=U < p 0. Similar to a conventional x inferior good, the income and substitution effects are countervailing. But what s special about a Giffen good is that the income effect dominates the substitution effect in some range): a rise in the price of a Giffen good causes the consumer to buy more of the good so, demand is effectively upward sloping). Even though a price increase reduces demand due to the substitution effect holding utility constant, the consumer is effectively so much poorer due to the income loss that her demand for the inferior good rises. 3

The notion of a Giffen good is interesting because it s a non-obvious in fact, barely plausible) implication of consumer theory; it s hard to imagine a case where when the price of a good rises, demand increases. But theory says such goods could exist. The 2008 Jensen and Miller paper in the American Economic Review represents the first rigorous scientific evidence that such goods do exist at least this is the first evidence for humans; there is lab evidence of Giffen behavior among some other species). This evidence may speak to the relevance and plausibility of the underlying theory. Question: The price of gasoline typically rises during the summer months, as does the gallons of gas consumed per household. Is gas a Giffen good? 1.1 Relationship between Compensated and Uncompensated demand These two demand functions compensated and uncompensated are quite closely related. But they are not identical. Recall from the prior lecture the Expenditure Function Ep x, p y, U), 4

which is the function that gives the minimum expenditure necessary to obtain utility U given prices p x, p y. For any chosen level of utility U, the following identity will hold h x p x, p y, U) = d x p x, p y, Ep x, p y, U)). 1) In other words, for any chosen level of utility, compensated and uncompensated demand must equal to one another. Another way to say this: Fix prices at p x, p y. Fix utility at Ū. Use the expenditure function to determine the income Ī necessary to attain utility ) Ū given p x, p y. It must be the case that h x p x, p y, U) = d x p x, p y, I. Although these demand curves cross by construction) at any chosen point, they do not respond identically to a price change. In particular differentiating equation 1) with respecting to p x yields the following equation: h x = d x p x p x d x + I E. 2) p x Rearranging yields, d x = h x d x E. 3) p x p x I p x In words, the uncompensated demand response to a price change is equal to the compensated demand response h x / p x ) minus another term, d x I E. p x The d x / I term should look familiar. It is the income effect on demand for good X. But what is the term multiplying it, E/ p x? This term deserves closer inspection. Recall the expenditure minimization problem that yields Ep x, p y, U). This problem looks as follows: The Lagrangian for this problem is: min p x X + p y Y s.t.ux, Y ) X,Y U. l = p x X + p y Y + λu UX, Y )). 5

The first order conditions for this problem are: X y λ = p x λu x = 0, = p y λu y = 0, = U UX, Y ). The solutions to this problem will have the following Lagrangian multipliers: p x λ = Ux = py. U y And of course, U = UX, Y ) at the optimal choices of X and Y. But what is E/ p x? In words, holding utility constant, how do optimal expenditures respond to a minute change in the price of one good, X? The answer is: P x ) X X = X + p x λu x + p x p ) x X X = X + p x p x + p x p x = X + 0 + 0 = X. Y Y p y λu y p x p ) x p y Y p x p y Y p x Note that we are using the following identities from above: ) p x = λu x p y = λu y. So, the short answer is that E/ P x = X, and more specifically, E/ P x = h x, where h x is the Hicksian or compensated demand function. This result, called Shephard s Lemma, follows directly from the envelope theorem for constrained problems. Since X and Y are optimally chosen, a minute change in p x or p y will not affect the optimal quantity consumed of either good holding utility constant as is always the case with the expenditure function). But a price increase will change total expenditures because, to hold utility constant, expenditures must rise when prices rise. 6

Since the consumer is already consuming an initial quantity of X 0 units of the good and hence spending P x X 0 on X), a rise in P x to P x = P x + 1 raises total expenditures needed to maintain the same level of utility by P x P x ) X 0 = X 0. Concrete example. If you buy 2 cups of coffee a day and the price of coffee rises by 1 cent per cup, how much do we need to compensate you to hold utility constant? To a first approximation, 2 cents it could never be more, it could actually be less). To hold utility constant given the price change, your expenditures must rise by the price change times the initial level of consumption. Note that this result Shephard s lemma) holds only locally, i.e., for small price changes. For a non-negligible price change, the consumer would re-optimize her bundle to reequate the MRS with the new price ratio. The utility maximization equivalently, cost minimization) problem is locally flat at the chosen values. Infinitesimal changes in the price ratio therefore have only second-order effects on utility and hence do not give rise to first order changes in the consumption bundle. As noted above, the demand function for X obtained from taking the derivative E/ p x is equal to h x, the compensated demand function, not d x, the uncompensated demand. Why? Because the expenditure function holds utility constant. Hence, any demand function that arises from the expenditure function must also hold utility constant and so is a compensated demand function. So, to reiterate: The derivative of the Expenditure function with respect to the price of a good is the Hicksian compensated) demand function for that good. Graphically the relationship between the compensated and uncompensated demand functions can be seen in the following figures. Recall that the compensated demand curve is composed of only substitution effects, because it represents how consumption changes with the price if the consumer were given enough money to stay on the same indifference curve at each price level. The uncompensated demand includes both the income and substitution effects. Therefore, the difference in slope between the two demand functions is determined by sign and magnitude of the income effects. 7

Comparison of Compensated h x ) and Uncompensated d x ) Demand Curves for a Normal Good Comparison of Compensated h x ) and Uncompensated d x ) Demand Curves for an Inferior Good 8

1.2 Longer Demonstration of Shephard s Lemma [optional] Recall the dual of the consumer s problem: minimizing expenditures subject to a utility constraint. min p x x + p y y s.t.ux, y) v l = p x x + p y y + λ Ux, y) U ), which gives E = p x x + p y y for Ux, y ) = v. Bear in mind the following first order conditions: p x λ = Ux = py. U y Now, calculate ) ) x x y y = x + p x λu x + p y λu x. p x p x p x p x p x Substitute in for λ x = x + p x p ) x x U x + p x p x U x p x p y y p x p y ) y U y = x. U y p x Hence, = E = x. p x p x Note that this x is actually h x p x, p y, U ) since utility is held constant. 1.3 Applying Shephard s lemma Returning to equation 3), we can substitute back in using Shephard s Lemma to obtain: d x = h x d x X p x p x I. This identity is called the Slutsky equation. It says that the difference between the uncompensated demand response to a price change the left-hand side, d x / p x ) is equal to the compensated demand response 9

h x / p x ) minus the income effect scaled by the effective change in income due to the price change recalling that X = E/ p x ). Notice also the economic content of the final term, dx I X. The size of the income effect on total demand for good X in response to a change in p x depends on the amount of X that the consumer is already purchasing. If the consumer is buying large quantities of X, an increase in p x has a large income effect. If the consumer is consuming zero of good X initially, the income effect of a change in p x is zero. Applying the Slutsky equation to the three types of goods, it s easy to see that: For a normal good dx > 0), the income and substitution effects are complementary. I For an inferior good dx < 0), the income and substitution effects are countervailing. I For a Giffen good, the income effect dominates: d x X > I hx p x note that they are both negative.) Effect of rise of p x in two good economy X, Y ). Consumption of X Consumption of Y Uncompensated Demand Marshallian) Substitution: Compensated Demand Hicksian) Substitution: Income: +/ Income: 0 Substitution: + Substitution: + Income: +/ Income: 0 Consumer Utility 0 1.4 Closing the loop: Uncompensated demand and the indirect utility function. One more piece of consumer theory that might come in handy: We concluded directly above that the compensated demand function can be derived just by differentiating the expenditure function. Is there a similar trick for deriving the uncompensated demand function? Glad you asked! 10

Recall the Lagrangian for the indirect utility function: V = maxux, Y ) s.t. Xp x + Y p y I, x,y l = UX, Y ) + λi Xp x Y p y ), X = U x λp x = Y = U y λp y = = I Xp x Y p y = 0. λ Now, by the envelope theorem for constrained problems: I = V I = U y = Ux = λ. 4) p y p x The shadow value of additional income is equal to the marginal utility of consumption of either good divided by the cost of the good. And by a similar envelope theorem argument: V = X X Y Y = λx + U x λp x + U y λp y 5) p x p x p x p x p x p ) ) x X X Y Y = λx + U x λp x + U y λp y 6) p x p x p x p ) x ) X X Y Y = λx + λp x λp x + λp y λp y 7) p x p x p x p x = λx 8) Notice the logic of this expression. The utility cost of a one unit price increase in is equal to the additional monetary cost which is simply equal to X, the amount you are already consuming, times one) multiplied by the shadow value of additional income. Returning to the coffee example, a 1 cent price rise costs you 2 cents if you were planning to buy 2 cups. And the value of 2 cents in foregone utility is simply λ times 2 cents. Putting together 4 and 9, we get the following expression: V P, I)/ P V P, I)/ I = λx = X = d x 9) λ which is called Roy s identity. Notice that we have substituted d x for X here because we have recovered the Marshallian uncompensated) demand function. That is, this is the demand for X holding income and other prices constant, not the demand for X holding utility and other prices constant. 11

Roy s identity is analogous to Shephard s lemma above; both recover demand functions by differentiating solutions to the consumer s problems with respect to prices. The difference is that by differentiating the expenditure function, Shephard s lemma gives the compensated demand function, whereas by differentiating the indirect utility function, Roy s identity gives the uncompensated demand function. We are now ready to put these tools to work. 2 Giffen goods in China: The Jensen and Miller 2008) Experiment 2.1 Context In China in 2005, about 10% of the population survived on less than one dollar per day. Given China s rapid growth, the contemporaneous number is surely much lower.) For this experiment, the sample included 650 households each in Hunan and Gansu provinces 1,300 households and 3,661 individuals). Households were selected from the list of urban poor. Thus, this sample is meant to be representative of the poor population, not the full population. Urban poor households by this definition have incomes averaging $0.41 to $0.82 per person per day. About 90 million Chinese households met this definition at the time of the study. The diet among the poor is very simple, consisting mostly of rice and noodles, plus some pork and other meat. Most consumers in the sample obtained 70% of total calories from rice or noodles alone. Importantly for the study, regional preferences for rice versus noodles vary considerably Table 1). In the South Hunan), rice is the staple. In the North Gansu), noodles are the staple. Meat is generally preferred to rice or noodles, but it is considerably more expensive. Meat typically provides only one-third the calories or protein per Yuan as rice or noodles Table 2). 12

2.2 The experiment Within each group Hunan, Gansu), households were randomly assigned to either a control group or one of three treatment groups. HH s in the treatment group were given printed vouchers entitling them to prices reductions of 0.10, 0.20 or 0.30 yuan off the price of each 500g 1 jin) of the staple good rice or noodles). Each treated household received vouchers for 5 months, with the vouchers distributed at the beginning of each month. The vouchers were for large quantities, amounting to 750g per person per day for each month of treatment. In practice, this means that households would be very unlikely to use their full quotas. That s important because it means that as far as the household is concerned, the voucher is equivalent to a price reduction in the staple good with no quantity constraint. Because the households in this study were extremely poor, they generally only consume the lowest quality variety of the staple good. Thus, substitution to higher qualities that is, spending more for smaller quantities of higher quality rice) is unlikely to create confounding measurement issues. An important subtlety is that Giffen behavior is unlikely to be relevant for households that are either too poor or too rich. Households that are so poor that they are barely meeting their caloric needs are unlikely to be in the range where an increase in effective income due to a decline in the staple price would cause them to buy less of the staple and more of the fancy good. The marginal dollar will still go towards the staple Households that are wealthy enough that they are easily meeting their caloric needs are unlikely to exhibit Giffen behavior because a fall in the price of the staple good does not substantially increase their wealth, and so even if the staple is an inferior good, the income effect will not dominate the substitution effect and so they will tend to buy more of the staple. Households that are poor enough that they are approximately at the subsistence constraint but not substantially above it may exhibit Giffen behavior. For them, a decline in the price of the staple increases effective income so that they may be able to meet their nutritional needs and consume some of the fancy good e.g., 13

pork). Thus, a reduction in the staple price may cause them to consume less of the staple and more of the preferred good. 2.3 Data analysis One interesting thing about this experiment as implemented in the paper is that each household provides its own pre-post comparison over multiple time periods. But there is also a control group. So this is a difference-in-difference design applied to a randomized control trial, which makes the study especially compelling. I will let you develop the notation for analyzing this experiment. 2.4 What they find The key results for Hunan are found in Table 3 with additional robustness tests in Table 4). Be sure also to study Figure 2. Notice that the percentage change in consumption of the staple is non-monotone in the initial staple calorie share. It s negative for the wealthier and poorer households in the sample those that have low and high staple consumption shares) and positive for those with high 60 to 80 percent) but non-corner-solution consumption shares. The results for Gansu province are less clear cut. Jensen and Miller discuss at length why that might be. What are the major threats to validity in this experiment? Are there any alternative interpretations? Do these results have any relevance to policy? Hint: Autor thinks that they do.) 14

MIT OpenCourseWare https://ocw.mit.edu 14.03 / 14.003 Microeconomic Theory and Public Policy Fall 2016 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: https://ocw.mit.edu/terms.