Basic Assumptions (1)

Similar documents
(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Teoria das organizações e contratos

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

Where do securities come from

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending?

Economics and Finance,

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Homework 3: Asymmetric Information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Instructor: Songzi Du

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Discussion of Calomiris Kahn. Economics 542 Spring 2012

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Shih En Lu. Simon Fraser University (with thanks to Anke Kessler)

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Chapter 7 Moral Hazard: Hidden Actions

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector

Econ 234C Corporate Finance. Lecture 13: Initial Public Offerings (IPOs), Corporate Governance

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Problem Set 2: Sketch of Solutions

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Debt Contracts. Ram Singh. April 1, Department of Economics. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Debt Contracts April 1, / 14

MORAL HAZARD PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Optimal Debt Contracts

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types

Costly State Verification and Debt Contracts

Homework Nonlinear Pricing with Three Types. 2. Downward Sloping Demand I. November 15, 2010

Produced with a Trial Version of PDF Annotator -

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting

Homework 3. Due: Mon 9th December

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT

Delegated Monitoring and Legal Protection. Douglas W. Diamond University of Chicago, GSB. June 2005, revised October 2006.

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Financial Contracting with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard

Moral Hazard. Two Performance Outcomes Output is denoted by q {0, 1}. Costly effort by the agent makes high output more likely.

CONSUMPTION AND INVESTMENT DECISION: AN ANALYSIS OF AGGREGATE AND TIME-ADDITIVE MODELS

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

The Dynamics of the Wealth Distribution and the Interest Rate March with17, Credit 2017Rationing

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real Sector

Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations. Bernanke and Gertler (1989, AER)

Online Appendix to Managerial Beliefs and Corporate Financial Policies

M. R. Grasselli. February, McMaster University. ABM and banking networks. Lecture 3: Some motivating economics models. M. R.

Income Disparity, Uneven Economic Opportunities, and Verifiability. Masayuki Otaki (Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo)

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting

PhD Qualifier Examination

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Asymmetric Information and Global Sourcing

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification

Principal-agent examples

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Risk Neutral Agent. Class 4

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

market opportunity line fair odds line Example 6.6, p. 120.

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Course topic: the firm. The firm has relationships with o Investors o Creditors o Suppliers o Employees (managers) o [customers, government, ]

Backward Integration and Risk Sharing in a Bilateral Monopoly

On the Optimal Use of Ex Ante Regulation and Ex Post Liability

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting

Credit, Bankruptcy Law and Bank Market Structure

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

ECON 4335 The economics of banking Lecture 7, 6/3-2013: Deposit Insurance, Bank Regulation, Solvency Arrangements

Asymmetric Information and the Role of Financial intermediaries

DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY. 1st set of transparencies. Tunis, May Jean TIROLE

Why is CEO compensation excessive and unrelated to their performance? Franklin Allen, Archishman Chakraborty and Bhagwan Chowdhry

Lecture 5 Crisis: Sustainable Debt, Public Debt Crisis, and Bank Runs

Parkes Auction Theory 1. Auction Theory. Jacomo Corbo. School of Engineering and Applied Science, Harvard University

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Optimal Compensation with Earnings Manipulation: Managerial Ownership and Retention

1 The principal-agent problems

Monitoring the Monitor: An Incentive Structure for a Financial Intermediary*

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland

Disputes, Debt and Equity

Transcription:

Basic Assumptions (1) An entrepreneur (borrower). An investment project requiring fixed investment I. The entrepreneur has cash on hand (or liquid securities) A < I. To implement the project the entrepreneur needs (borrows) I A.

Basic Assumptions (2) If undertaken the project either succeeds: verifiable income R > 0. Or the project fails: yields zero income. Let p denote the probability of success. The project is subject to moral hazard.

Basic Assumptions(3) The entrepreneur can exert high effort (work, take no private benefit), or zero effort (shirk, take a private benefit). Equivalently, the entrepreneur chooses between project with high or low probability of success. High effort yields p = p H ; low effort yields p = p L, with p L < p H. Denote p = p H p L. Low effort yields a private benefit B > 0 to the entrepreneur. (B can be interpreted as a disutility of effort).

Basic Assumptions (4) Borrower and lenders (investors) are risk-neutral. For simplicity, there is no time preference: investors require an interest rate equal to 0 (at least). The entrepreneur is protected by limited liability (income cannot be negative). Competition among lenders drive interest and profit to zero.

Basic Assumptions(5) The loan contract specifies how the profit is shared between borrower and lenders. Limited liability implies that both sides receive zero in case of failure. Profit sharing: R = R b + R l, where R b is the the borrower s share, R l is the lender s share. Lender s net payoff is R l (I A) in case of success; (I A) in case of failure. The borrower s payoff is thus R b A in case of success and A in case of failure.

Basic Assumptions (6) The zero-profit constraint for lenders is p H R l = I A. Assuming high effort, the rate of interest is ι, where R l = (1 + ι)(i A) or 1 + ι = 1 p H. The nominal rate of interest ι reflects a default premium. We assume that the project is viable only if effort is high: that is, p H R I > 0 and p L R I + B < 0. No loan giving an incentive to low effort will be granted: either the lender or the borrower would lose money in expectation.

The lender s credit analysis (1) The borrower s tradeoff: obtain private benefit B but reduce probability of success to p L. We have the following incentive compatibility constraint, IC: p H R b p L R b + B or R b B p. The highest income that can be pledged to lenders is R B/ p. In expected terms: p H (R B/ p).

The lender s credit analysis (2) The lender s individual rationality constraint, IR, is therefore ( p H R B ) I A. p Financing can be arranged only if ( A I p H R B ). p We assume that I > p H (R B/ p). Otherwise, a lender with A = 0 could obtain credit. The project s NPV is smaller than the minimum expected rent that must be left to the borrower to satisfy IC.

The lender s credit analysis (3) The borrower must have enough assets A A = I p H (R B/ p) in order to be granted credit. If A < A, the project has positive NPV and yet is not funded. The parties cannot find an agreement that both induces high effort and yield enough benefit to lenders. This is credit rationing. The borrower is ready to give more of the return to the lender but the lender does not want to grant such a loan. If A A, the entrepreneur can secure financing (we have a necessary and sufficient condition for financing).

The lender s credit analysis (4) The entrepreneur offers the minimal claim R l, such that p H R l = I A. The entrepreneur s stake satisfies R b = R R l = R I A p H R I A p H = B p, so that the entrepreneur chooses high effort. One only lends to the rich. If A A, the borrower s utility is U b = p H R b A = p H (R R l ) A = p H R I: the borrower receives the entire social surplus of the investment.

Determinants of credit rationing What are the determinants of credit rationing? A low amount of cash A. A high agency cost (or agency rent) B/ p. Moral hazard is determined by the private benefit B and the likelihood ratio p/p H. The likelihood ratio measures how much the observable result (success or failure) reveals the underlying choice of effort.

Do investors hold debt or equity? Remark that the loan contract can be interpreted as debt here. This is because we have a two-outcome model. Interpretation as debt: the borrower must reimburse R l or else go bankrupt. In the case of reimbursement, the borrower keeps the residual R R l.

Costly State Verification Model This model has been analyzed by Townsend (1979) and Gale and Hellwig (1985). We derive the financial structure of the firm from an optimization problem (and from primitive assumptions). Moral hazard here comes from the fact that the entrepreneur can divert (steal) income. There is no effort variable here. Income is semi-verifiable: the lenders can perfectly observe income, provided that they incur an audit cost K. This cost is borne by lenders.

Costly State Verification Model (2) The entrepreneur invests his(her)money A. Investment cost is I. Investment yields a random income R distributed on [0, + ), with density p(r). The entrepreneur observes R without cost. Timing: 1. Loan agreement, I is sunk. 2. Income R is realized. 3. Entrepreneur reports ˆR. 4. Lender may decide to audit. 5. Reimbursement. We apply the Revelation Principle: there is no loss of generality if we focus on revealing mechanisms, i.e., contracts such that the entrepreneur has an incentive to report the true income ˆR = R.

CSV Model (3): Definition of a Contract A contract is a mapping giving a probability of no audit y( ˆR) [0, 1] for each report ˆR,... and nonnegative rewards: w 0 (R, ˆR) and w 1 (R, ˆR) in the absence or presence of an audit. The lender s return R l depends on ˆR only in the absence of audit: w 0 (R, ˆR) = R R l ( ˆR). Define the entrepreneur s expected reward under truthful reporting w(r) = y(r)w 0 (R, R) + (1 y(r))w 1 (R, R).

CSV Model (4): Standard Debt Contract A standard debt contract specifies a debt level D. There is no audit if debt D is repaid; an audit and no reward if D is not repaid. Formally, y(r) = 1 if R D and y(r) = 0 if R < D. w(r) = max{r D, 0}.

CSV Model (5): Optimal Contract We maximize the expected income Maximize + 0 w(r)p(r)dr, with respect to {y(.), w 0 (.,.), w 1 (.,.)}, subject to the entrepreneur s incentive constraint IC, i.e., w(r) = max{y( ˆR)w 0 (R, ˆR) + (1 y( ˆR))w 1 (R, ˆR)} ˆR and the lender s participation constraint, IR, that is, + 0 [R w(r) (1 y(r))k ]p(r)dr I A. and limited liability constraints w 0 (R, R) 0, w 1 (R, R) 0.

CSV Model (5b): Optimal Contract Since IR will be binding at the optimum, we can susbsitute IR in the objective function (the borrower s expected profit) and we find, + 0 w(r)p(r)dr = K + 0 (1 y(r))p(r)dr (I A)+E(R). The objective is equivalent to minimizing the expected audit cost.

Analysis of the Optimal Contract (1) Assume that audits are deterministic: y(r) = 0 or 1 for all R. Feasible values of R are divided into to regions: the no-audit region Q 0 and audit region Q 1 (A partition of [0, + )). Reimbursement R w(r) must be constant over the no audit region Q 0. Proof. If reimbursement is higher for R than for R with R, R Q 0 then, for R entrepreneur would prefer to report R. Conclusion: Reimbursement must be constant, say D, if R Q 0, and Q 0 [D, + ).

Analysis of the Optimal Contract (2) The reimbursement for R in Q 1 cannot exceed D, for if it did then R w(r) > D and the entrepreneur would prefer to report an income in Q 0 to pay only D. Important Result: for any contract satisfying IC and IR, there exists a standard debt contract that does at least as well for the entrepreneur. Prove this in 2 steps. Step 1. For any contract C, there exists a standard debt contract C that pays out more to lenders at a smaller audit cost. Step 2. There exists a second standard debt contract C that satisfies IR (lenders break even) and involving an even smaller expected audit cost.

Analysis of the Optimal Contract (3) Proof of Step 1. Consider an arbitrary contract C satisfying IC and IR, with regions Q 0 (no audit) and Q 1 (audit). Let D be the repayment in Q 0. Construct a standard debt contract in which repayment is D = D. Define new regions Q 0 = [D, + ) and = [0, D). Q 1 The entrepreneur receives 0 in Q 1. Since Q 0 Q 0, the expected audit cost is weakly smaller (since Pr(Q 0 ) Pr(Q 0 )). Expected repayment to lenders is weakly larger under C : for Q Q 0, repayment is the same, equal to D; for R Q 0 Q 0 repayment is at most D under C and equal to D under C ; for R Q 1 Q 1 the lender s payoff is R K under C and cannot be larger under C.

Analysis of the Optimal Contract (4) Proof of Step 2. Suppose that the standard debt contract C leaves a strictly positive expected profit to lenders. Then, by the intermediate value theorem, there exists D < D such that the lenders payoff is just 0, D [1 P(D )]D + Rp(R)dR P(D )K = I A, 0 where P(D ) = Pr(R D ) is the cdf of p. Contract C has a lower expected audit cost since D < D = D, implying P(D )K < P(D )K and leaves no surplus to lenders (IR is an equality). We conclude that contract C is preferred by the borrower to the initial contract C.

Figure 1: Borrower s reward o~ ~ _

Figure 2: Lender s reward ~C) 1 ~~~~----------~----~~, ~ D - "'" ~ ~ ~ ~ 1 ~I -- ~ ~ f\)

CSV Model: Interpretation The audit region Q 1 is interpreted as bankruptcy region. When R < D, the entrepreneur fails to reimburse the debt and is declared bankrupt. The entrepreneur can withdraw nothing from the "cash register" before the audit, but can fully withdraw the residual income if there is no audit. Interpretation: the borrower can in fact steal the income but cannot consume it and must refund it if an audit takes place. Alternative interpretation: the entrepreneur can, over time, transform hidden income into perks. Perks can be enjoyed if the firm is not shut down. During the bankruptcy process, the lenders recoup the value of the assets in the firm.