Topic 5: Sticky Price Models of Money and Exchange Rate

Similar documents
Updated 10/30/13 Topic 4: Sticky Price Models of Money and Exchange Rate

Topic 6: Optimal Monetary Policy and International Policy Coordination

Topic 2: International Comovement Part1: International Business cycle Facts: Quantities

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Pricing To Market, Staggered Contracts, and Real Exchange Rate Persistence

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Advanced International Macroeconomics Session 5

Kiel Institute for World Economics. On the Welfare Effects of Monetary Policy When Households Try to Keep Up with the Rest of the World

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

International Monetary Policy Coordination and Financial Market Integration

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates

International Macroeconomics - Session II

The science of monetary policy

A Canonical Model of the FX Premium

International Macroeconomics and Finance Session 4-6

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries

Slides III - Complete Markets

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Final Exam Solutions

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Notes on the Monetary Model of Exchange Rates

GRA 6639 Topics in Macroeconomics

1 Unemployment Insurance

Does the Optimal Monetary Policy Matter for the Current Account Dynamics

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States

Chapter 10 Solutions

University of Toronto Department of Economics. How Important is the Currency Denomination of Exports in Open-Economy Models?

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Overshooting Meets Inflation Targeting. José De Gregorio and Eric Parrado. Central Bank of Chile

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Goods Market Frictions and Real Exchange Rate Puzzles

Does the Exchange Rate Belong in Monetary Policy Rules?

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Oil Price Shock and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model of Small Open Oil Exporting Economy - Case of Iran 1

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

The Zero Bound and Fiscal Policy

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Equilibrium exchange rates and supply side performance

Economics 502. Nominal Rigidities. Geoffrey Dunbar. UBC, Fall November 22, 2012

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Nontradable Goods, Market Segmentation, and Exchange Rates

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach Assume uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), which is implied by perfect capital substitutability 1.

1 Mar Review. Consumer s problem is. V (z, K, a; G, q z ) = max. subject to. c+ X q z. w(z, K) = zf 2 (K, H(K)) (4) K 0 = G(z, K) (5)

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

Transcription:

Topic 5: Sticky Price Models of Money and Exchange Rate Part 1: Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995 JPE) - We want to explain how monetary shocks affect real variables. The model here will do so by introducing sticky prices. Resembles the Mundell-Fleming model. - But it has more developed micro foundations, including an intertemporal budget constraint and the internal consistency that comes with this. - It also can evaluate policies in terms of agent welfare (utility). 1

Model Description - Two countries, two currencies, perfect foresight except for initial shock - Money introduced by putting it in the utility function - Only hold own money, not foreign. - Sticky price: need to set it one period ahead of time. - Agents choose price, are price setters rather than take price as given, because have some monopoly power - Have a continuum of differentiated goods 2

Market structure: - A continuum of individual monopolistic producers (producers and consumers: yeoman farmers) indexed by z on interval [0 1], each produce a single good. - Fraction n are at home, 1-n are foreign. 3

Preferences: identical preferences over a consumption index (combine all the consumption goods), real money balances (only own money), and effort expended in production (opposite of leisure). j j j M t 1 Ut logct log y P 2 t j 2 t - Last term represents utility of leisure, disutility of labor supply. Are assuming production is just a function of labor y = square root of labor. 4

- Consumption: is a real CES index, an extension to more goods of the two-good index from before. 1 j 1 j C c ( z) dz 0 1 This implies a price index as an index over the goods consumer, just as we saw in lecture one in the case of traded and nontraded goods: 1 1 1 1 n 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) ( ) *( ) 0 0 n P pz dz pz dz ep z dz Where break up into home and foreign goods, assuming that law of one price holds for each one. 5

This comes from the same sort of exercise used before in this course for a Cobb-Douglas consumption index. What is the minimum cost of one unit of the consumption index. 1 P min Z p( z) c( z) dzd 0 1 1 1 st.. c( z) dz 1 0 where Z is total nominal expenditure on consumption. Note that we can do same for the foreign price index, P*: 1 1 1 1 n 1 1 1 1 pz ( ) 1 e 0 0 n P* p*( z) dz dz p*( z) dz 6

Note that as long as both countries have the same consumption index over goods, we will have PPP satisfied: P = e P*. 7

Budget constraint: - Assume only asset traded is a riskless real bond (like models earlier) with real return r. - Household budget constraint: PB j M j P(1 r) B j M j p ( j) y ( j) PC j P t t1 t t t t t1 t t t t t where P is aggregate price index, p(j) is price of the good this household produces and sells. - Tau is tax with government, how it injects money into the economy: M t M t1 t P t 8

Demand curves: - Consider the intratemporal choice between the various goods. - Maximize index over consumption goods subject to budget constraint that total expenditure not exceed some limit gives an intratemporal allocation rule: pz ( ') cz ( ) cz ( ') p( z) Integrate over goods: j pz ( ) j c ( z) C P 9

- This says that given the total consumption level, household will allocate it among the various goods depending on their relative price, relative to the overall price index. - Take weighted sum of home and foreign households to get total world demand as share of total world consumption: d pz ( ) W y ( z) C P W where C nc(1 n) C* This is a demand curve, where the constant elasticity of demand is theta. 10

b) First order conditions: - Now consider the full intertemporal problem: choosing consumption, bond holdings, money demand, and either quantity of output (labor supply) or price -- subject to constraints: budget constraint, and demand they face for their product. - If prices flexible: choose quantity of production, - but if prices need to be fixed ahead of time, then choose price, let market determine demand and then we assume the agent must satisfy that demand when the time comes, supplying whatever labor supply is necessary. 11

Get first order conditions: 1) Basic intertemporal consumption Euler: want to smooth consumption C (1 r ) C t1 t1 t 2) Money demand: agents must be indifferent between consuming a unit of consumption good on date t or using the same funds to raise cash balances, enjoying the transactions utility in period t and then converting the extra cash balances back to consumption in period t+1. M P t t 1 i t1 Ct it 1 where i is nominal interest rate 12

3) Labor supply: marginal utility cost of producing extra unit of output (lost leisure) equals marginal utility from consumption of the added revenue that an extra unit of output brings. y t 1 1 1 W 1 C t C t - Takes into consideration fact that if increase production, this will lower the price can sell good at, depending on size of market. - Since we assume agents are price-setters rather than quantity setters, use the equation above along with the goods demand condition (demand as a function of goods price) to solve for the optimal price set for the good. 13

- Further, we assume that the agent must set this price one period ahead of time (price rigidity), so he sets price as a function of the expected value of the variables above. 14

Market-clearing conditions - Money supply must equal money demand in each country. (implicit here because use M for supply and demand) - Bond clearing condition: sum over home and foreign bond holdings equals 0. - Can get a world goods market clearing condition, written in terms of consumption index, saying total world consumption equals total world production. 15

c) Solution: Define equilibrium: 16 variables: C, y, M, b, P, tau, price of representative good p(h) and foreign counterparts for these, as well as the exchange rate and interest rate. 16 equilibrium conditions: - FOCs for consumption, money demand, labor supply (price setting) with foreign counterparts (6) - Household budget constraints (2) - Government budget constraints (2) - Definition of price indexes (2) (involves nominal exchange rate) - Demand curves for representative national good (2) 16

- Goods market clearing condition (in terms of consumption index) (1) - Bond market clearing (1) Can t get full analytical solution, but can get some equilibrium relationships that help with intuition. Solution strategy: 1) find a steady state, as a function of relative wealths. 2) Linearize equilibrium conditions around steady state. 3) Find the differences between national variables 4) Find world aggregates. Put this together with national differences to conclude regarding individual national variables. 17

d) Initial Steady state: - Derive consumption functions in steady state, using consumption Euler and intertemporal budget constraint): p( h) C rb y P - If want a closed form solution, consider a case of complete symmetry where the net foreign asset position is zero (Bbar = 0) In this case we have: C C* y y* in the initial steady state. 0 0 0 0 Note that with monopolists, the level of production in steady state will be too low. Because they know that if 18

increase production, this will lower the price. So they restrict production below efficient level. - Plug these into the labor supply decision: 1 12 y0 y* 0 - Notice first that money does not matter for the steady state. 19

- Notice next that this level of output is less than what a social planner would choose, based on the real part of the agent s utility function: 1 2 max log y y 2 1 optimal y 1 This is important to the welfare conclusions later. 1 2 20

- Next log linearize all equations around the symmetric steady state. I skip most steps. - Use lower case letters to represent percent deviations from initial steady state. 21

e) Short run effects - permanent rise in money. MM-curve - Combine (as differences across countries) the consumption Eulers and money demands, and PPP: * * e m m t c c t t t - This says: if we increase home money supply, this will increase money supply relative to money demand, and this causes the exchange rate to depreciate. t - Graph it as e versus relative consumption: downsloping to show a rise in consumption raises money demand and causes e to appreciate. A rise in m would shift curve to right: e depreciates for a given relative consumption. 22

GG curve - Combine the linearized versions of the goods demand equations (where prices are fixed), along with the linearized versions of the labor supply conditions (to change outputs into consumption levels, you get: e t r ( * 2 t ct 1 ) 2 ( c r( 1) ) - Graphs this as an upsloping curve because it says an e depreciation will shift demand toward home goods because prices fixed and are cheaper relative to foreign, production increases, so income increases, so consumption rises 23

M1 e M2 G c-c* G M2 M1 24

- A rise in home money supply shifts the MM curve right. This has the effects: 1) e rises (home currency depreciation) 2) (c-c*) rises: a rise in home consumption relative to foreign. - It is also possible to write these in terms of output differences, given that the two national demand conditions when linearized imply that (y-y*) = e. - So we also conclude that: 3) (y-y*) rises: a rise in home relative to foreign output. 25

Now Find world aggregates: - Doing more manipulations not shown here, we find that: 1 w rt mt 1 So if either country increases its money supply, this will make the common world real interest rate fall. - And find that: w ct 1 rt So a fall in the interest rate will raise world consumption. In fact: w w w ct mt yt w w w - Summarizing: mt r ct yt - This shows that this is not a zero sum game. 26

- Before the monetary shock, output was sub-optimally low, held down by the monopolists to maximize their profits. - But a surprise rise in money supply lowers the real interest rate and raises demand; the monopolists must accommodate this demand by increasing production. 27

- Put the information together to conclude about individual country variables. - Know (c-c*) rises and (c+c*) rises, so know c rises home. Regarding the foreign variable, we can t tell from here what happens to c*, but can use other equations to show it rises as well. - Know (y-y*) rises and (y+y*) rises, so know y rises at home. Regarding the foreign variable, we can t tell what happens to y*, and the effect is in general ambiguous. 28

- This ambiguity in foreign output comes about because there are two effects: 1) The rise in money lowers the real interest rate, which would tend to raise foreign demand and hence output. 2) but it also makes the nominal exchange rate rise, so foreign goods are more expensive. This shifts demand toward home goods and away from foreign goods, and this fall in demand would lower foreign production. - As long as the elasticity of intratemporal substitution (theta) is greater than the intertemporal elasticity (which is unity because of the log utility specification), the change in the relative price will dominate the effect of the change in interest rate. 29

- Note that this would be an example of the beggar thy neighbor policy emphasized in the Mundell-Fleming model: a home monetary expansion raises home output at the expense of lowering output abroad. 30

f) Welfare effects: - But we should not judge the impact of the policy in terms of output levels, but instead in terms of agent welfare, using the utility function on which the model was based. - If substitute equilibrium variables into utility function, most of terms cancel out and you get: w w ct mt du 31

Interpret: - Welfare rises the same in both countries regardless of who undertakes the monetary expansion, because consumption rises in both countries. - This is a first-order effect. The monetary expansion forces a rise in the world level of production and overall consumption above the monopolistic level. - This shows the importance of using optimizing models rather than ISLM/ Mundell-Fleming models. In the latter you can t do welfare analysis. 32

g) Kollman (JIE 2001): compare model to data - See if OR-type model can generate stylized facts saw in data. Augments model for data comparison. Model Description (how different from OR) - Has uncertainty. - Small open economy rather than two-country. - Consider sticky prices and wages also - Consider stickiness of varying durations: 2 quarter, 4 quarter, and gradual adjustment. - Multiple shocks: money supply, labor productivity, price level in rest of world, and world interest rate. - Nominal bonds, in either domestic currency with rate r or foreign currency at r*. - More general utility function and production function 33

Sticky-Price specification: Version one: price set k=periods ahead of time. So at period t choose Pt+k that expect to satisfy optimality conditions, based on info available at period t. Version 2: Calvo adjustment mechanism: - Firms only allowed to change price if receive a random price-change signal with probability (1-delta). - So each period fraction (1-delta) of firms change their price and fraction delta will not. - Firms solve for the optimal price given this expectation. - Under certain conditions the prices can be aggregated to imply the aggregate price is a weighted average of previous period s aggregate price and the optimal reset price. - This has the convenient implication that the aggregate price will gradually adjust to a shock. 34

Impulse responses: - Figure 1: four-period fixed price and wage. Monetary shock lowers domestic nominal interest rate, and raises domestic output, nominal and real depreciation of country s currency. - Figure 5: Calvo adjustment: same, but smoother, more gradual adjustment. - Note: overshooting 35

36

37

Moments from simulation Recall exchange rate facts to match: - real and nominal exchange rates move together, - volatility 4X that of output - persistent (with serial corr of about 0.8). 38

39

40

4-period stickiness: - corr(e,rer) = 0.81 compared to 0.97 in data. - Vol(e) = 3.64 compared to 4.75 in data - Autocorr(rer) = 0.64 compared to about 0.8 on average Calvo stickiness: - Calibrate with 8% of firms adjust each quarter. - Suspiciously high degree of stickiness means that on average price reset only every 3 years - corr(e,rer) = 0.99 compared to 0.97 in data. - Vol(e) = 5.45 compared to 4.75 in data - Autocorr(rer) = 0.68 compared to about 0.8 on average 41

Questions for Discussion 1) What role does PPP and the law of one price play in the Obstfeld-Rogoff model? 2) List 3 specific ways in which this model differs from the Mundell-Fleming model you have studied previously? 3) Might these differences lead to different implications for policy analysis? 4) Compare the usefulness of this model for monetary versus fiscal policy analysis. 42

Part 2) Sticky Price Models and Exchange Rate Puzzles 1) Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (RES 2002) - The model is similar to Kollmann (2001 JIE), in that it is an RBC model augmented with money and sticky prices. - It is different in that it assumes prices are set in staggered overlapping Taylor contracts (Taylor 1980, JPE). 43

Core of the model is a standard RBC model. - Two countries: home and foreign - Each country produces a continuum of intermediate goods indexed by i over [0 1]. - Producers are monopolistically competitive, with market power. Can choose different prices in the two countries. - These intermediate goods are combined to make final goods, specific to each country, used for consumption, investment and government consumption. Aggregator: 44

- Production of intermediate uses capital (k) and labor (l): - Capital accumulation subject to adjustment costs (x is investment) - Complete asset markets: complete set of nominal statecontingent bonds, where o s t is history of events up to period t. o B is holding of state-contingent bond o Q(s t ) is price of one unit of home currency in state s t. o Q(s t+1,s t ) = Q(s t+1 )/Q(s t ) is price of bond bought in s t and that pays off in s t+1, 45

- Price setting: - Index home firms i (0,1) and divide into N groups. - In period t fraction 1/N of the home firms, i (0,1/N), set their price p(i) for N periods. - Next period, firms indexed i (1/N, 2/N) set their prices, and so on. - The logic is that when a firm has the opportunity to reset its price, it will do so only partly, because it knows some of its competitors have not reset their prices yet. - Calibration will imply contracts last one year. 46

Price setting problem: and optimality conditions: Where: = We will consider a simpler problem to aid interpretation 47

Aside: Simple version price-setting problem: To deepen understanding, consider a simpler version of price setting problem: (single-period predetermined price, abstract from investment and state notation) Suppose monopolistically competitive firm i faces demands: pht i cht i cht pht at home and * * p Ht i * cht i c * Ht p Ht abroad, where firms takes overall demand c * and c Ht as given. * And production function: y i c ic i AL i Where labor is paid at wage rate W t. Ht Ht Ht Ht t t 48

Maximization problem: max * 1 Ht p i, p i Ht t E Uct t i * * Ht Ht E Uct pht i cht i et p i c i WL t t i t1 where profits over various periods and states are valued using marginal utility of households, U ct. Substitute in production and then demand functions: W t * W t * max Et 1 Uct pht i cht i etp Ht i c Ht i At At * W pht i Ht t W p t i max E t 1 U ct pht i cht etp Ht i c * At pht At p Ht * * Ht 49

FOC for foreign price, * p Ht i : * 1 * * p Ht i 1 * p Ht t i W * Et 1 U ct etp Ht i c * * Ht ec * t Ht At p Ht p Ht p Ht 0 Impose symmetry (and the unit interval of goods): * * W t 1 Et 1 Uctc Ht etp Ht i e 0 * t At p Ht p i p * * Ht Ht 50

* 1 W t * E t1 Uctc Ht et 0 * E U Ht t 1 ctc et p Ht A t 1 W t 1 0 t1 * p t1 Ht A t W E U c p * * E U ctc Htet E Uctc Ht * t ct Ht * A t1 t Ht * 1 E U Ht t 1 ctc e t Interpret: price as a markup over marginal cost, augmented by expectations about demand, marginal utility, and exchange rate. 51

If take a linear approximation of this condition around a deterministic steady state, as done in RBC literature: p E W E A E e * Ht t 1 t t 1 t t 1 t The repeated terms drop out, and it becomes simpler. Note: To represent this conditional in a stochastic linear system, need to define expectation terms, which will involve a non-invertible matrix. This rules out solving the system by the method of Blanchard-Kahn. Need an alternative not requiring matrix inversion, such as QZ decomposition. 52

Back to interpreting price setting conditions from paper: Q: like the marginal utility used for discounting above P v: nominal marginal costs, like W/A above Sum over states: expected value :uncertain demand. Sum over periods: price is average over optimal price for each of period during the contract. 53

Households: - Infinitely lived, choosing consumption, labor, and money demand, to maximize discounted sum of utilities U, subject to budget constraint: - Preferences: separable in consumption and leisure: 54

- Usual first order conditions for labor supply, money demand, and risk sharing: - Note that iterating on the risk sharing condition implies the following relationship between the real exchange rate (q) and marginal utilities: (A) 55

- Government: assume a constant money growth process, injected by transfers: With money distributed by transfers 56

Calibrate one country to U.S., other to European aggregate. 57

Findings: - Run stochastic simulations, under shocks to monetary aggregate. HP filter, and report moments of simulated data. - Benchmark case: good on volatility, not so good on persistence. (See table 5 below.) 58

59

Intuition for volatility: equation (A) above implies: Lesson: With sticky price models of this type you generally can generate as much real exchange rate volatility as you want, by adjusting the risk aversion parameter. 60

Lesson: But this trick does not help generate persistence. 61

- Table further shows that many model extensions have little effect (incomplete asset markets, sticky wages). - Note that if the preferences are specified as nonseparable, this can raise persistence. But this comes at the cost of losing all volatility. - With nonseparable utility, the risk sharing condition is affected also by leisure, not just sigma and consumption, so the mechanism above is no longer at work. 62

- An additional problem with main result above: it implies a high correlation between consumption and real exchange rate (also called the Backus-Smith puzzle : JIE 1993) - The model implies a perfect correlation, as seen from the risk sharing condition above: - But in the data the correlation is varied and negative on average. 63

- Neither incomplete asset markets nor habits in preferences can break the counterfactual high correlation. 64

2) Johri and Lahiri (2008 JIE) Questions for class discussion: 1) What two new features does this paper add to the model of Chari et al.? 2) Have we seen one of these before? How different? 3) Why should these two model features help explain real exchange rate persistence? 4) How is home bias important to this result? 5) How is the intertemporal elasticity important here? 6) Do you think this model can explain the Backus-Smith puzzle also? 65

3) Exchange Rate Pass-through Another aspect of the international price puzzles is in terms of exchange rate pass through to import prices Where: - PM is import price index - PF*E is the average foreign price level (CPI) expressed in dollar terms using the nominal effective exchange rate - PCOM controls for commodity prices is the pass-through coefficient: what fraction of a change in the nominal exchange rate is passed on to changes in the price of goods imported from that country. 66

Also possible to estimate separate s for PF and E in this regression. Can also estimate as a long-run pas-through using error correction form for the regression. 67

Estimated in Gust, Leduc and Viggusson (JME 2010): - Using monthly data 1981-1990, = 0.65: a 10% dollar depreciation raising dollar value of foreign prices would lead to a 6.5 percent increase in U.S. import prices. - Note: if use more recent data 1994-2003: = 0.12. - Figure shows gradual fall in pass-through over time. 68

69

Conclusions: - Pass-through to U.S. import prices rather low, especially in recent data. - This implies that exporters to U.S. are not changing their prices when exchange rate fluctuations raise the dollar value of their costs. - This affects their markups of price over cost and profits. - Also has implications for the efficacy of exchange rate policies, which rely upon currency depreciations to switch expenditure away from foreign goods toward domestic. 70

Translog preferences: - One way to explain reluctance to raise export prices after domestic currency appreciation is fear that setting higher prices than competitors will erode market share. - This concern is not reflected in price setting under CES preferences derived last time in class: recall that desired price is a constant markup over expected marginal costs. p W E U c * t ct Ht * A t1 t Ht * 1 E U Ht t 1 ctc e t - Or as linear approximation in class: 71

p E W E A E e * Ht t1 t t1 t t1 t - If a 1% exchange rate change is anticipated, there is 1% rise in price: complete pass through. - If unanticipated, the pass through is zero in the initial period. But in next period (or in long run) exchange rate is complete: a 1% rise in e raises price by 1%. - The level of the constant markup is a function of the constant elasticity in the CES. - To allow for a time-varying markup, need a time-varying elasticity. 72

Translog preferences cont. (from Bergin-Feenstra JIE 2001): Rather than start with a consumption index, posit an expenditure function: where P it is the set of home-currency price of good i, N is set of potential goods in market. Home-country demand for each good is: Where it is the expenditure share, derived by differentiating the expenditure function: 73

The demand function implies an elasticity that can vary over time: As good i s price rises relative to the market average and i s market share ( it) falls, the demand elasticity rises (lowering market share at an increasing rate) 74

Price-setting for export under translog (2-period contract) where: - p i * is foreign currency price of home export - mc is marginal cost, - e is nominal exchange rate Note: now firm cares about price of competitors (p j *) as well as own marginal cost. And weight on exchange rate is reduce to around 0.5: A 1% permanent depreciation will reduce price charged in foreign market by 0.5% (all else constant). = 0.5 75

4) Rodriguez Lopez (Review of Economic Studies 2010) Student presentation 76