A SECOND-BEST POLLUTION SOLUTION WITH SEPARATE TAXATION OF COMMODITIES AND EMISSIONS

Similar documents
Environmental taxation and the double dividend

Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 (19,5210(17$//(9,(6$1'',67257,21$5<7$;$7,21 3,*287$;$7,21$1'32//87,21 *LOEHUW(0HW DOI :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ

Environmental Policy in the Presence of an. Informal Sector

Principle of targeting in environmental taxation

Environmental Taxes and the Double-Dividend Hypothesis: Did You Really Expect Something for Nothing?

Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Vol. 19, No. 4. (Autumn, 2000), pp

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TWO GENERALIZATIONS OF A DEPOSIT-REFUND SYSTEM. Don Fullerton Ann Wolverton

Health effects and optimal environmental taxes

Subsidizing Non-Polluting Goods vs. Taxing Polluting Goods for Pollution Reduction

Environmental Taxes and the Double-Dividend Hypothesis: Did You Really Expect Something for Nothing

Are Green Taxes a Good Way to Help Solve State Budget Deficits?

First, Do No Harm: Welfare Gains and Welfare Losses from Environmental Taxation. Charles L. Ballard* Michigan State University

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Fiscal Interactions and Climate Change Policy

Gasoline Taxes and Externalities

Environmental Policy in the Presence. of an Informal Sector a

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Environmental Policy in the Presence. of an Informal Sector a

Appendix: Numerical Model

The Double Dividend: Fact or Fallacy?

Environmental Policy in the Presence. of an Informal Sector

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

A note on Cost Benefit Analysis, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and the Marginal Excess Burden of Taxes

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Environmental Controls, Scarcity Rents, and Pre-Existing Distortions

Chapter 8. Revenue recycling and environmental policy

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

Arindam Das Gupta Independent. Abstract

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Green tax reform in Belgium: Combining regional general equilibrium and microsimulation

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

"The General Equilibrium Incidence of Environmental Taxes" (with Don Fullerton), Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 91, No. 3-4 (April 2007),

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency

Application: The Costs of Taxation

AAEC 6524: Environmental Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Environmental Policy with Pre-existing Distortions Part B. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2017

Money in an RBC framework

DIPLOMARBEIT. Titel der Diplomarbeit. Pollution Taxation and Environmental Quality. Verfasser. Sebastian Reis. angestrebter akademischer Grad

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Factors that Affect Fiscal Externalities in an Economic Union

The Substantial Bias from Ignoring General Equilibrium Effects in Estimating Excess Burden, and a Practical Solution

Don Fullerton, University of Illinois Garth Heutel, UNC-Greensboro

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Bankruptcy risk and the performance of tradable permit markets. Abstract

ECON Micro Foundations

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

International Trade in Resource Goods and Returns to Labor in the Non-Resource Sectors

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Perfect competition and intra-industry trade

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

ON UNANIMITY AND MONOPOLY POWER

Do high interest rates stem capital outflows?

Carbon Taxes, Inequality and Engel's Law - The Double Dividend of Redistribution

Accrual vs Realization in Capital Gains Taxation

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

The Private Provision of International Impure Public Goods: the Case of Climate Policy

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

SOPAAN April-Sept. :2014. Green Tax in India

Problem Set # Public Economics

Optimal Taxation of Intermediate Goods in the Presence of Externalities: A Survey Towards the Transport Sector

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Econ 131 Spring 2017 Emmanuel Saez. Problem Set 2. DUE DATE: March 8. Student Name: Student ID: GSI Name:

Intermediate public economics 5 Externalities Hiroaki Sakamoto

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Module 10. Lecture 37

Public Good Provision Rules and Income Distribution: Some General Equilibrium Calculations

EC330 Study Guide II Spring 2010 R. Congleton Public Finance GMU

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Environmental Tax Reform: Efficiency and Political Feasibility

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Tax Reform and the Environment in Developing Economies: Is a Double Dividend Possible?

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Environmental taxation in a federal system of government with equalization payments

Discounting the Benefits of Climate Change Policies Using Uncertain Rates

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

= = = = = = = = = = = = LEADING IN THOUGHT AND ACTION

A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy, and Practice. Daniel J. Phaneuf and Till Requate

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

THE OPTIMUM QUANTITY OF MONEY RULE IN THE THEORY OF PUBLIC FINANCE. Kent P. KIMBROUGH*

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

output and employment, and as,+n for fiscal, tit

International Trade in Emission Permits

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1

Transcription:

A SECOND-BEST POLLUTION SOLUTION WITH SEPARATE TAXATION OF COMMODITIES AND EMISSIONS by Basharat A.K. Pitafi and James Roumasset Working Paper No. 02-8 August 2002

A Second-best Pollution Solution with Separate Taxation of Commodities and Emissions Basharat A. K. Pitafi and James A. Roumasset University of Hawaii at Manoa ϒ July 26, 2002 JEL Classification: D62, H21, H23 Keywords: Second-best environmental taxation, Pigouvian taxation, tax normalization, Revenue recycling, Tax interaction Abstract: Several authors have argued that the second-best environmental tax on a dirty good is less than marginal emission damage associated with its consumption. These studies limit their analysis to cases in which emissions can only be reduced by a reduction of the dirty good. With a more general specification that allows abatement through input substitution, we show that the direct emissions tax cannot be less than marginal emission damage, regardless of the normalization. ϒ 542 SSB, 2424 Maile Way, Honolulu, HI 96822. Fax: (808) 956-4347. basharat@hawaii.edu. Authors gratefully acknowledge comments from Kwong Soo Cheong, Gerard Russo, Katerina Sherstyuk, and the participants of the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Monterey, CA, June 24-27, 2002.

1. Introduction Recent interest in global warming and carbon taxes has spawned a vigorous discussion regarding the size of the optimal environmental tax in relation to marginal environmental damage. Early contributions stressed the additional benefits (denoted as the revenuerecycling effect by Parry, 1995) of using environmental tax revenue to reduce the excess burden of pre-existing taxes [Nichols 1984, Terkla 1984, Lee and Misiolek 1986, Pearce 1991, Repetto et. al. 1992] 1. Nordhaus (1993), for example, using the DICE framework, empirically derived large carbon taxes when such revenue recycling was allowed, and much smaller taxes when it was not allowed. While these studies ignored the tax interaction between environmental and other taxes, Bovenberg and de Mooij (1994) 2 showed that such friction is not negligible. When other taxes are present in the system, environmental taxes may exacerbate pre-existing distortions and this unfavorable tax-interaction effect may outweigh the favorable revenue-recycling effect, such that a second-best emissions tax is smaller than the marginal emissions damage (MED). This did not quite settle the issue, however, and soon Fullerton 3 (1997) and Schöb (1997) showed that the second-best environmental taxes can be greater or smaller than MED depending on the choice of tax instruments. Further confusion was created in the literature by subsuming the size-of-emission-tax argument 1 Tullock (1967) is often credited with pioneering the idea. 2 Also see Bovenberg and de Mooij (1997), and Bovenberg and Goulder (1996). 3 Fullerton s treatment also clarifies how the results of Boveberg and de Mooij (1994) depend on the complementarity between dirty good and labor. Fuest and Huber (1999) show that when there is gross substitutability between the dirty good and the other tax base (labor/clean good), the optimal tax on the dirty good always exceeds the Pigovian tax.

into the "double dividend" debate without a consensus on the definition of double dividend. The purpose of all these analyses was to determine how the size of the environmental tax is affected by the presence of other taxes. At first blush, the problem seems straightforward. One needs only to specify the nature of emissions in a fairly general way and then extend the theory of optimal commodity taxation to include emission taxes. Generality can be achieved by treating emissions as an input (e.g., Oates and Strassman 1984, and Fullerton and Metcalf 2001 4 ). Here we encounter a difficulty, however, because the conventional method of solving for an optimal system of commodity taxes is not directly applicable in the presence of a non-market good (environment). In the absence of an emissions price, the elasticities involving the emissions price, which would make a major component of a conventional tax solution, cannot be computed. Sandmo (1975) and others using similar models (e.g., Bovenberg and de Mooij 1994, Fullerton 1997) avoid this difficulty by making emissions a function of a commodity called the dirty good and taxing the dirty good in order to tax emissions. While this approach renders the model tractable, it severely restricts pollution avoidance possibilities. For instance, in this polar case, imposition of a labor tax does not result in the substitution of emissions for labor in production that would have increased the demand for emissions input. This is the reason behind the Bovenberg and de Mooij result (emissions tax less than MED) and the Fullerton result (the tax-med comparison 4 Fullerton and Metcalf use this technology in comparing the rent-generating and rent-capturing emissions control policies. Oates and Strassmann use it to compare the efficiency of effluent fees under different noncompetitive market structures. 2

dependent on normalization or the choice of tax instruments). 5 Moreover, the utility function is typically assumed to exhibit weak separability between emissions and other goods. This further restricts the applicability of the results from these models. Accordingly, we proceed with a different solution strategy. We maintain the generality afforded by regarding emission as an input to production and solve the non-market problem by treating emissions analogously to the other input, labor. Just as the consumer is endowed with units of labor that can be sold or consumed, she is also endowed with emission rights that can be sold to polluters or retained (thereby reducing pollution). We derive the Ramsey price of emissions and then exploit institutional equivalency under zero transaction costs to replace the pollution market with an equivalent pollution tax. We also relax the assumption of weak separability. Using this framework, we show that, when the revenue requirement warrants distortionary taxation, the second-best emissions tax exceeds MED, and quantity of emissions is less than in the first-best solution. If the revenue requirement is small enough to be financed by emissions tax alone, then a first-best optimum obtains with the emissions tax equal to MED. These results are independent of tax normalization. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The model and derivation of result are provided in section 2. Section 3 summarizes the results and concludes. 5 The only abatement method allowed is reducing the consumption of the dirty good. It does not allow for abatement by switching to a cleaner process or using end-of-pipe treatment. This implies that consumer cannot choose the amount of emissions independently of the amount of the dirty good, and the two cannot, therefore, be taxed separately. Because the dirty tax changes with normalization, the implied emissions tax also varies. 3

2. The Model Following Oates and Strassmann (1984), emissions are modeled as a virtual input. This allows for all three abatement methods, i.e., a) decreasing output, b) switching to a cleaner process, and c) end-of-pipe treatment. In consonance with, but simultaneously generalizing, the prototypical approach 6, we have two goods, one of which is dirty (good d) in the sense that emissions are necessary for its production, while the other is a clean good (c). The production functions are: ( 1 ) c = c( lc), d = d( ld, e), where l c and l d are labor inputs to sector c and d respectively and e is the emissions input. For convenience, we first assume a market for emissions and then replace the market with an emissions tax. The producers profit-maximizing first-order conditions (FOCs) are now: d d ( 2 ) p c = w, pd = w, pd = pe lc ld e where w is the wage rate, p e is the emissions market price, and p c and p d are the producer prices of the good c and d respectively. The consumer is initially endowed with N pollution rights, 7 sells e rights to the producers in an emissions market and consumes the rest, n, in the same way that she sells part (l) of the total labor endowment (L) and consumes the rest as leisure (v). Thus, l c + l d = l = (L - 6 Henceforth, prototypical or standard model or approach refers to Bovenberg and de Mooij (1994), Fullerton (1997) and similar models. 7 N can be set arbitrarily at some number greater than or equal to the optimal quantity of emissions. To fix ideas, however, we may take it to be the maximum amount of pollution that would obtain if the emissions 4

v) and e = (N - n). The consumer s utility is, therefore, u(c, d, v, n, G), where G is a government good financed through taxes, is weakly separable in the utility function, and is held constant (following the standard models). For the government revenue constraint, G, to be met, the consumer pays ad valorem commodity 8 taxes, t c and t d. The revenue constraint is then: ( 3 ) tc c + td pd d G where p c and p d are the producer prices of the good c and d respectively, and the former is normalized to unity, without loss of generality. The consumer maximizes the utility subject to the budget constraint: ( 4 ) w l + p e = ( 1+ tc) c + (1 + td) pd d e The resulting first-order conditions (FOCs) are: ( 5 ) i) = λ (1 + tc), ii) = λ. pd (1 + td), iii) = λ. w, iv) = λ. pe d v n where λ is the marginal utility of income. Re-writing (5), we get a more intuitive form: ( 5A ) i) (1 + tc) = λ, ii) pd.(1 + td) = λ, iii) w = λ, iv) pe = λ d v n price were zero. 8 Because demand function has the property of being homogeneous of degree zero in consumer prices, i.e., only relative prices matter, one of the goods can be chosen as numeraire (see, e.g., Keller 1980). The numeraire s price can be set to unity without changing the relative prices. Then all the others prices are stated in terms of units of the numeraire good. The same is true of supply function in terms of supplier prices. However, in the presence of taxes, the consumer and supplier prices are differentiated. For convenience and ease of interpretation, we often set the consumer and supplier prices of the same good to unity, causing the tax wedge between the two to disappear, i.e., we perform tax normalization. Since the choice of the numeraire is arbitrary, many alternate normalizations are possible. Here we are normalizing the labor tax to zero. Later we consider other normalizations and show that they yield the same results. 5

From (5)(i), the marginal utility of income, λ, is ( 6 ) λ = ( 1+ tc) Note the relationship of λ to the tax on the clean good. Now, we are ready to compare the emissions price with the marginal emissions damage. Plugging (6) in (5)(iv) gives: ( 7 ) p (1 e = + tc) n (1 + tc) p e = e Q n = N e where the R.H.S. is just the marginal emissions damage (MED). Re-arranging (7), we get: ( 8 ) pe = ( 1+ tc) = ( MED) (1 + tc) e > MED pe ( 9 ) = MED when when t > 0 c t = 0 c Thus, when there are no commodity taxes, the emissions price and MED are equal. Positive commodity taxation (warranted by a revenue requirement in excess of emissions tax revenue) must increase the efficiency price of emissions above MED. This is because the taxes on commodities raise consumer prices and encourage the consumer to substitute leisure and environment for consumption of commodities. This reduces the supply of emissions permits and raises the emissions price to the producers. When the emissions price is implemented as an emissions tax on producers, the emissions tax exceeds MED. 6

For purposes of illustration, consider a downward sloping demand for permits (value of marginal product of emissions) curve and an upward sloping supply of permits (marginal cost of damage from emissions) curve, as shown in Figure 1. Imposing the commodity tax, shifts the permits supply curve to the left, representing a substitution toward the consumption of untaxed environmental amenities and away from the consumption of the taxed commodity. Figure 1: Second-best Emissions Price/Tax (induced by commodity taxation) e.( 1 + tc) e d p d. ed In contrast, consider the case where G = 0. In the absence of distortionary tax, t c, the permit supply equals permit demand at the emissions level e 1 and price p 1. Since the government expenditures are zero, the tax revenue, p 1.e 1, is simply disbursed to the consumer in lump-sum fashion. Even as G increases, we remain at the first-best equilibrium so long as G = p 1.e 1. 7

Once the revenue constraint becomes binding, i.e., G = p 1.e 1, then distortionary taxes become necessary to raise any more revenue. As shown in Figure 1, this shifts the permit supply curve to the left, raises the emissions price to p 2, and reduces the emissions quantity to e 2. The value of MED at the new emissions level is MED 2. 9 The emissions price, p 2, is larger than this MED level. Since this emissions price is implemented as a tax on producers, the resulting emissions tax is larger than MED. The emissions tax is also larger than the first-best MED level, i.e., p 1. 2.1. The Normalization Problem The conventional method of normalization in tax models is to use the same good as numeraire for both consumer and producer prices. As a result, without loss of generality, one of the taxes is zero. When we set the labor tax to zero, commodity taxes are used to meet any excess revenue requirement. We have shown above that, in this case, the emissions tax is greater than MED. This is because leisure and environmental amenities are substituted for other consumption and the emissions supply schedule shifts leftward. Similarly, when we use the labor tax to raise revenue and set the clean good tax to zero, again we get the result that the emissions tax is greater than MED. This is because labor tax reduces the consumer s income and induces the consumer to substitute leisure and environmental amenities for other consumption, which, in turn, reduces the supply of emissions, as in Fig. 1. Any combination of the clean good tax and labor tax also yields the same results because they both affect emissions supply in the same way. 10 Therefore, 9 In the comparison between emissions tax and MED commonly used in the literature (e.g., Bovenberg and de Mooij 1994, Fullerton 1997), MED is implicitly defined as its value at the second-best optimum. 10 The consumer budget constraint with two commodity and one labor taxes is: c.( 1+ tc) + d. pd.(1 + td) = l. w.(1 tl) + e. p e 8

under any normalization, the emissions tax is equal to or greater than MED at the second-best optimum. Our results are the same under any choice of tax instruments. They agree with those of the prototypical model in case of a commodity tax but differ in case of a labor tax. The intuition behind this difference is explained next. 2.2 Comparison with the Standard Model Why do we get the result that the emissions tax is equal to or larger than MED (under any choice of tax instruments), in contrast with the standard result that the dirty good tax is less than MED (at least in the presence of a labor tax)? As suggested in section 1, the answer lies in the input substitutability between emissions and labor. In the standard model (e.g., Bovenberg and de Mooij 1994, and Fullerton 1997) does not allow substitution between emissions and labor as inputs in the production of a dirty good. By assuming that emissions are a fixed function of the dirty good, the elasticity of input substitution is implicitly assumed zero. This implies that the consumer cannot choose the amounts of environmental amenities to consume (or emissions to tolerate) independently of the amount of dirty good consumed. Therefore, taxing emissions or taxing dirty good is equivalent. More importantly, when a labor tax is imposed, producers cannot respond by substituting emissions for labor. If they could, the demand for emissions would Multiplying through by a constant, Q, the consumer FOCs now become: i) = λ.(1 + tc). Q ii) = λ. pd.(1 + td). Q, iii) = λ. w.(1 tl). Q, iv) = d v n, λ Q = 1 (1 t ) Note that we can set Q = 1 (1 + tc) to eliminate the clean good tax or l to eliminate the labor tax. Dividing (iv) by (i) gives: pe. Q = = MED p e =.( 1+ tc) = ( MED).(1 + tc) (1 + tc). Q n n pe MED when t c [0,1]. pe. Q 9

increase, as would the emissions price/tax, as in our model discussed above. 3. Conclusions We examine the optimal emissions tax in a model that allows for multiple means of abatement. When there is no distortionary taxation to meet the revenue requirement, the emissions tax equals MED. When there is distortionary taxation, the emissions tax exceeds MED evaluated at the second-best optimum, and the emissions quantity is less than in the first-best solution. The second-best emissions tax also exceeds MED at the first-best optimum. The assumption of no input substitution is the underlying reason for the results of the prototypical model. Without this restriction, our model provides the result that emissions tax is larger than MED and remains larger under any normalization. Thus, modeling the production function to allow for input substitution, and the resulting abatement possibilities, avoids the troublesome normalization problem that has plagued the double dividend debate. When the elasticity of input substitution is positive, the emissions tax is greater than or equal to MED. 10

References Bovenberg, A. L. and R. A. de Mooij, 1994, Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation, American Economic Review 84, 1085-1089. Bovenberg, A. L. and R. A. de Mooij, 1997, Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Reply, American Economic Review 87, 252-253. Bovenberg, A. L. and L. H. Goulder, 1996, Optimal Taxation in the presence of Other Taxes: General Equilibrium Analyses, American Economic Review 4, 985-1000. Fuest, C. and B. Huber, 1999, Second-Best Pollution Taxes: An Analytical Framework and some New results, Bulletin of Economic Research 51, 31-38. Fullerton, D., 1997, Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Comment, American Economic Review 1, 245-251. Fullerton, D., G. E. Metcalf, 2001, Environmental controls, scarcity rents, and preexisting distortions, Journal of Public Economics 80, 249 267. Keller, W. J., 1980, Tax Incidence: A General Equilibrium Approach (North-Holland, New York). Lee, D. R. and W. S. Misiolek, 1986, Substituting Pollution Taxation for General Taxation: Some Implications for Efficiency in Pollution Taxation, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 13, 338-347. Nordhaus, W., 1993, Optimal Greenhouse-Gas Reduction and Tax Policy in the DICE Model, American Economic Review 83, 313-317.

Oates, W. E. and D. L. Strassmann, 1984, Effluent Fees and Market Structure, Journal of Public Economics 24, 29-46. Parry, I. W. H., 1995, Pollution Taxes and Revenue Recycling, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29, S64-77. Pearce, D., 1991, The Role of Carbon Taxes in Adjusting to Global Warming, Economic Journal 101, 938-948. Repetto, R., R. C. Dower, R. Jenkins, and J. Geoghegan, 1992, Green Fees: How a Tax Shift Can Work for the Environment and the Economy, Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. Schöb, R., 1997, Environmental Taxes and Pre-Existing Distortions: The Normalization Trap, International Tax and Public Finance 4, 167-176. Terkla, D., 1984, The Efficiency Value of Effluent Tax Revenues, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 11, 107-123. Tullock, G., 1967. Excess Benefit. Water Resources Research 3, 643 644. 2